Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-p9bg8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T07:08:17.868Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 July 2018

Randall G. Holcombe
Affiliation:
Florida State University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Political Capitalism
How Political Influence Is Made and Maintained
, pp. 279 - 290
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31, no. 4 (December 2003): 620652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerlof, Robert, “‘We Thinking’ and Its Consequences.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 415419.Google Scholar
Adams, George P. Jr., Competitive Economic Systems. New York, NY: Thomas Y. Crowell Company, 1955.Google Scholar
Aidt, Toke S., “Rent Seeking and the Economics of Corruption.” Constitutional Political Economy 27, no. 2 (June 2016): 142157.Google Scholar
Allison, John, The Financial Crisis and the Free Market Cure. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 2013.Google Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, P. J., The Birth of a Transfer Society. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen and Puy, M. Socorro, “Identity Voting,” Public Choice 169, nos. 1/2 (October 2016): 7795.Google Scholar
Applebaum, Elie and Katz, Eliakim, “Seeking Rents by Setting Rents: The Political Economy of Rent Seeking.” Economic Journal 97, Issue 387 (September 1987): 685699.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd edn. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. and Debreu, Gerard, “Existence of an Equilibrium for a Competitive Economy.” Econometrica 27, no. 3 (1954): 265290.Google Scholar
Averch, Harvey and Johnson, Leland L., “Behavior of the Firm Under Regulatory Constraint.” American Economic Review 52, no. 5 (December 1962): 10521069.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry M., Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Bator, Francis M., “The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization.” American Economic Review 47, no. 1 (March 1957): 2259.Google Scholar
Bator, Francis M., “The Anatomy of Market Failure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 72, no. 3 (August 1958): 351379.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J., Entrepreneurship, Management, and the Structure of Payoffs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., “Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 5, Part 1 (October 1990): 893921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J., “Health Care, Education, and the Cost Disease: A Looming Crisis for Public Choice.” Public Choice 77, no. 1 (September 1993): 1728.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis.” American Economic Review 57, no. 3 (June 1967): 415426.Google Scholar
Beard, Charles A., An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1913.Google Scholar
Berggren, Niclas, “The Benefits of Economic Freedom: A Survey.” Independent Review 8, no. 2 (Fall 2003): 193211.Google Scholar
Berle, Adolf and Means, Gardiner, The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 1932.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S., “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98 (1983): 371400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce L., The Enterprise of Law: Justice Without the State. Oakland, CA: Pacific Research Institute for Public Policy, 1990.Google Scholar
Bentley, Arthur F., The Process of Government: A Study of Social Pressures. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1908.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy, Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006.Google Scholar
Black, Dunan, The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1958.Google Scholar
Bloxam, G. A., “Letters Patent for Inventions: Their Use and Misuse.” The Journal of Industrial Economics 5, no. 3 (July 1957): 157179.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter J., Living Economics: Yesterday, Today, and Tomorrow. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute, 2012.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter J., Why Perestroika Failed: The Politics and Economics of Socialist Transition. London: Routledge, 1993.Google Scholar
Boudreaux, Christopher J. and Holcombe, Randall G., “Regulation and Corruption.” Public Choice 164, no. 1 (July 2015): 7585.Google Scholar
Boudreaux, Christopher J., Nikolaev, Boris N., and Holcombe, Randall G., “Corruption and Destructive Entrepreneurship.” Small Business Economics (forthcoming).Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., “The Domain of Constitutional Economics.” Constitutional Political Economy 1, no. 1 (December 1990): 118.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1975.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., “Politics, Policy, and the Pigouvian Margins.” Economics n.s. 29, no. 113 (February 1962): 1728.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., “Public Finance and Public Choice.” National Tax Journal 28, no. 4 (December 1975): 383394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M., “Social Choice, Democracy, and Free Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 62, no. 2 (April 1954): 114123.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D., and Tullock, Gordon, eds., Towards a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press, 1980.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon, The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Wagner, Richard E., Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. New York, NY: Academic Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Buck, Ken, Drain the Swamp: How Washington Corruption Is Worse Than You Think. Washington, DC: Regnery, 2017.Google Scholar
Butler, Eamonn, Public Choice: A Primer. London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 2012.Google Scholar
Caplan, Bryan, The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2007.Google Scholar
Carpenter, Dick M. II, Knepper, Lisa, Erickson, Angela C., and Ross, John K., License to Work: A National Study of the Burdens From Occupational Licensing. Washington, DC: Institute for Justice, 2012.Google Scholar
Carvalho, Jean-Paul, “Identity-Based Organizations.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 410414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Young Back, “Industrial Policy as the Engine of Economic Growth in South Korea: Myth and Reality,” in Boettke, Peter J., ed., The Collapse of Development Planning. New York, NY: New York University Press, 1994: 231255.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H., “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law & Economics, 3 (1960): 144.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S., Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Belknap, 1990.Google Scholar
Commons, John R., Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1934.Google Scholar
Commons, John R., The Legal Foundations of Capitalism. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press, 1924.Google Scholar
Congleton, Roger D., Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Congleton, Roger D. and Hillman, Arye L., eds., Companion to the Political Economy of Rent-Seeking. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2015.Google Scholar
Congleton, Roger D. and Lee, Sanghack, “Efficient Mercantilism? Revenue-Maximizing Monopoly Policies as Ramsey Taxation.” European Journal of Political Economy 25, no. 1 (December 2007): 102114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conover, Pamela J., “The Influence of Group Identifications on Political Perception and Evaluation.” Journal of Politics 46, no. 3 (August 1984): 760785.Google Scholar
Corcoran, William J. and Karels, Gordon V., “Rent-Seeking Behavior in the Long Run.” Public Choice 46, no. 3 (1985): 227246.Google Scholar
Crain, W. Mark, “On the Structure and Stability of Political Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 85, no. 4 (August 1977): 829842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalberg, John E. E. and Acton, Lord, “Acton–Creighton Correspondence” [1887], http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/acton-acton-creighton-correspondence.Google Scholar
Dari-Mattiacci, Guiseppe and Parisi, Francesco, “Returns to Effort in Rent-Seeking Games.” Public Choice 159, nos. 1/2 (April 2014): 99104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Haan, Jakob, Lundstrom, Susanna, and Sturm, Jan-Egbert, “Market-Oriented Institutions and Policies and Economic Growth: A Critical Survey.” Journal of Economic Surveys 20, no. 2 (April 2006): 157191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delsol, Jean-Philippe, Lecaussin, Nicolas, and Martin, Emmanuel, eds., Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21st Century. Washington, DC: Cato Institute, 2017.Google Scholar
de Soto, Hernando, The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York, NY: Basic Books, 2000.Google Scholar
de Soto, Hernando, The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York, NY: Harper & Row, 1989.Google Scholar
Dent, Chris, “Generally Inconvenient: The 1624 Statute of Monopolies as Political Compromise.” Melbourne University Law Review 33, no. 2 (2009): 415453.Google Scholar
Diamond, Jared, The World Until Yesterday: What Can We Learn From Traditional Societies? New York, NY: Viking, 2012.Google Scholar
Do, Quoc-Anh, Nguen, Kieu-Trang, and Tran, Anh N., “One Mandarin Benefits the Whole Clan: Hometown Favoritism in an Authoritarian Regime. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 9, no. 4 (October 2017): 129.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony, An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York, NY: Harper & Row, 1957.Google Scholar
Dreher, Axel and Gassebner, Martin, “Greasing the Wheels? The Impact of Regulations and Corruption on Firm Entry.” Public Choice 155, nos. 3/4 (June 2013): 413432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dugan, William R. and Snyder, James M., “Are Rents Fully Dissipated?Public Choice 77, no. 4 (December 1993): 793813.Google Scholar
Dutta, Nabamita and Sobel, Russell, “Does Corruption Ever Help Entrepreneurship?Small Business Economics 47, no. 1 (June 2016): 179199.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B. and Tollison, Robert D., Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Edelman, Murray, The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Urbana, IL: University of Illinois Press, 1964.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P., “Further Evidence on the Partisan Consequences of Legislative Professionalism.” American Journal of Political Science 43, no. 3 (1989): 974977.Google Scholar
Friedman, David D., The Machinery of Freedom: Guide to Radical Capitalism. Chicago, IL: Open Court Publishing Company, 1973.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1962.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, “Lerner on the Economics of Control,” Journal of Political Economy 55, no. 5 (October 1947): 405416.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis, The End of History and the Last Man. New York, NY: Free Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin, Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin and Page, Benjamin I., “Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens.” Perspectives on Politics 12, no. 3 (September 2014): 564581.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D. and Holcombe, Randall G., “Unions, Economic Freedom, and Growth.” Cato Journal 30, no. 1 (Winter 2010): 122.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Holcombe, Randall G., and Lawson, Robert, “Economic Freedom, Institutional Quality, and Cross-Country Differences in Income and Growth,” Cato Journal 24, no. 3 (Fall 2004): 205233.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Holcombe, Randall G., and Lawson, Robert, “The Scope of Government and the Wealth of Nations,” Cato Journal 18, no. 2 (Fall 1998): 163190.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Lawson, Robert, and Hall, Joshua. Economic Freedom of the World 2014 Annual Report. Vancouver, BC: Fraser Institute, 2014.Google Scholar
Gwartney, James D., Lawson, Robert, and Holcombe, Randall G., “Economic Freedom and the Environment for Economic Growth.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 155, no. 4 (1999): 643663.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. and Pierson, Paul, Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer—And Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster, 2010.Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett, “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science 162, Issue 3859 (December 13, 1968): 12431248.Google Scholar
Hartmann, Eva and Kjaer, Poul F., The Evolution of Intermediary Institutions in Europe: From Corporatism to Governance. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A., Individualism and Economic Order. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1944.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A., The Road to Serfdom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1944.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A., “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Review 35 (1945): 519530.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert L., The Making of Economic Society. Englewood Cliff, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1962.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert L., “The Triumph of Capitalism.” The New Yorker (January 23, 1989): 98109.Google Scholar
Higgins, Richard S., Shughart, William F. II, and Tollison, Robert D., “Free Entry and Efficient Rent-Seeking.” Public Choice 46, no. 3 (1985): 247258.Google Scholar
Higgs, Robert, Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987.Google Scholar
Hitch, Charles J. and McKean, Roland N., The Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M., Conceptualizing Capitalism: Institutions, Evolution, Future. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2015.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., Advanced Introduction to Public Choice. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2016.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Consent or Coercion? A Critical Analysis of the Constitutional Contract,” in Marciano, Alain, edn., Constitutional Mythologies. New York, NY: Springer, 2011: 923.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Crony Capitalism: By-Product of Big Government.” The Independent Review 17, no. 4 (Spring 2013): 541559.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “The Economic Theory of Rights.” Journal of Institutional Economics 10, no. 3 (September 2014): 471491.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., From Liberty to Democracy: The Transformation of American Government. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Government: Unnecessary But Inevitable. Independent Review 8, no. 3 (Winter 2004): 325342.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Liberty and Democracy as Economic Systems.” The Independent Review 6, no. 3 (Winter 2002): 407425.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Make Economics Policy Relevant: Depose the Omniscient Benevolent Dictator.” The Independent Review 17, no. 2 (Fall 2012): 165176.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “A Note on Seniority and Political Competition.” Public Choice 61, no. 3 (June 1989): 285288.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Political Capitalism.” Cato Journal 35, no. 1 (Winter 2015): 4166.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Political Incentives for Rent Creation.” Constitutional Political Economy 28, no. 1 (March 2017): 6278.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Principles and Politics: Like Oil and Water.” Review of Austrian Economics 22, no. 2 (June 2009): 151157.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Privatization of Municipal Wastewater Treatment.” Public Budgeting & Finance 11, no. 3 (Fall 1991): 2842.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “South Korea’s Economic Future: Industrial Policy or Economic Democracy?Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 88 (April 2013): 313.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “What Stiglitz and Stockman Have in Common.” Cato Journal 34, no. 3 (Fall 2014): 569579.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., The Economic Foundations of Government. New York, NY: New York University Press, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., Entrepreneurship and Economic Progress. London: Routledge, 2007.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Political Entrepreneurship and the Democratic Allocation of Economic Resources,” Review of Austrian Economics 15, nos. 2/3 (June 2002): 143159.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., “Why Does Government Produce National Defense?Public Choice 137, nos. 1/2 (October 2008): 1119.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G., Producing Prosperity. London: Routledge, 2013.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Boudreaux, Christopher J., “Regulation and Corruption.” Public Choice 164, nos. 1/2 (July 2015): 7585.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Castillo, Andrea M., Liberalism and Cronyism: Two Rival Political and Economic Systems. Arlington, VA: Mercatus Center, 2013.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Holcombe, Lora P., “The Market for Regulation.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 142, no. 4 (December 1986): 684696.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Parker, Glenn R., “Committees in Legislatures: A Property Rights Perspective.” Public Choice 70, no. 1 (April 1991): 1120.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Powell, Benjamin, eds., Housing America: Building Out of a Crisis. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute, 2009.Google Scholar
Holcombe, Randall G. and Staley, Samuel R., Smarter Growth: Market-Based Strategies for Land-Use Planning in the 21st Century. Westport, CT: Greenwood, 2001.Google Scholar
Ido, Masanobu, Varieties of Capitalism, Types of Democracy, and Globalization. London: Routledge, 2012.Google Scholar
Ikeda, Sanford, Dynamics of the Mixed Economy: Toward a Theory of Interventionism. London: Routledge, 1997.Google Scholar
Isaacson, Walter, Steve Jobs. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster, 2011.Google Scholar
Jain, Arvind K., “Corruption: A Review.” Journal of Economic Surveys 15, no. 1 (2001): 71121.Google Scholar
Jarrell, Gregg A., “The Demand for State Regulation of the Electric Utility Industry.” Journal of Law & Economics 21, no. 2 (October 1978): 269295.Google Scholar
Jindapon, Paan and Whaley, Christopher A., “Risk Lovers and the Rent-Overinvestment Puzzle.” Public Choice 164, nos. 1/2 (July 2015): 87101.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, Daniel, Kraay, Aart, and Mastruzzi, Massimo, “The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 5430 (September 2010).Google Scholar
Kelman, Steven, “Public Choice and the Public Spirit.” Public Interest 87 (Spring 1987): 8094.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York, NY: Harcourt Brace and Company, 1936.Google Scholar
Koford, Kenneth J., “Centralized Vote Trading.” Public Choice 39, no. 2 (1982): 245268.Google Scholar
Kohn, Meir, “Value and Exchange.” Cato Journal 24, no. 3 (Fall 2004): 303339.Google Scholar
Kolko, Gabriel, Railroads and Regulation: 1877–1916. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Kolko, Gabriel, The Triumph of Conservatism: A Reinterpretation of American History, 1900–1916. New York, NY: The Free Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E., “Identity Economics 2016: Where Do Social Norms Come From?American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 405409.Google Scholar
Krueger, Anne O., “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review 64 (June 1974): 291303.Google Scholar
Lake, James and Linask, Maia K., “Costly Distribution and the Non-Equivalence of Tariffs and Quotas.” Public Choice 165, nos. 3/4 (December 2015): 211238.Google Scholar
Landes, David S., The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 1998.Google Scholar
Lee, Hyeonseo, The Girl With Seven Names: Escape From North Korea. London: William Collins, 2015.Google Scholar
Lehmbruch, Gerhard, “Liberal Corporatism and Party Government.” Comparative Politicsl Studies 10, no. 1 (April 1977): 91126.Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar and Taylor, Fred M., On the Economic Theory of Socialism. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota Press, 1938.Google Scholar
Lerner, Abba, The Economics of Control: Principles of Welfare Economics. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1946.Google Scholar
Leonard, Thomas C., Race, Eugenics, and American Economics in the Progressive Era. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2016.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret, Of Rule and Revenue. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Lindsey, Lawrence B., Conspiracies of the Ruling Class: How to Break Their Grip Forever. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster, 2016.Google Scholar
Liebowitz, Stan J., “Anatomy of a Train Wreck: Causes of the Mortgage Meltdown,” Holcombe, Randall G. and Powell, Benjamin, eds., Housing America: Building Out of a Crisis. Oakland, CA: Independent Institute, 2009.Google Scholar
Lingle, Christopher, Singapore’s Authoritarian Capitalism: Asian Values, Free Market Illusions, and Political Dependency. Fairfax, VA: Locke Institute, 1996.Google Scholar
Lingle, Christopher, The Rise and Decline of the Asian Century: False Starts on the Path to the Global Millennium. Barcelona: Editions Sirocco, 1997.Google Scholar
Lipsey, R. G. and Lancaster, Kelvin, “The General Theory of Second Best.” Review of Economic Studies 24, no. 1 (1956): 1132.Google Scholar
Lott, John R. Jr. and Kenny, Lawrence W., “Did Women’s Suffrage Change the Size and Scope of Government?Journal of Political Economy 107, no. 6 (December 1999): 11631198.Google Scholar
Loucks, William N. and Whitney, William G., Comparative Economic Systems, 9th edn. New York, NY: Harper & Row, 1973.Google Scholar
Love, John R., Antiquity and Capitalism: Max Weber and the Sociological Foundations of Roman Civilization. London: Routledge, 1991.Google Scholar
Magness, Phillip W. and Murphy, Robert P.. “Challenging the Empirical Contribution of Thomas Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century.” The Journal of Private Enterprise 30, no. 1 (Spring 2015): 134.Google Scholar
Malthus, Thomas Robert, An Essay on the Principle of Population. London: J. Johnson, 1798.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1920.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl, Capital. Chicago, IL: Charles H. Kerr & Company, 1906.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl and Engels, Friedrich, The Communist Manifesto. New York, NY, International Publishers, 1948.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S., “Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Legal Studies 16, no. 1 (January 1987): 101118.Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred S., Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N., Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2010.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N., Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2016.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N., The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 2006.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N., “The Rhetoric of Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature 21, no. 2 (June 1983): 481517.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N., The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Meckling, William H. and Jensen, Michael, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics 3, no. 4 (1976): 305360.Google Scholar
Meinke, Scott R. and Hasecke, Edward B, “Term Limits, Professionalism, and Partisan Control in U.S. State Legislatures.” Journal of Politics 65, no. 3 (August 2003): 898908.Google Scholar
Meltzer, Alan H. and Richard, Scott F., “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 5 (October 1981): 914927.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart, Principles of Political Economy With Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy. London: Longmans, Green, and Co., 1920 [orig. 1848].Google Scholar
Mills, C. Wright, The Power Elite. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1956.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics, Scholar’s Edition. Auburn, AL: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1998.Google Scholar
Mises, Ludwig, Socialism. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1951.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel, The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Market Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2002.Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel, The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
Murray, Charles, Losing Ground: American Social Policy, 1950–1980. New York, NY: Basic Books, 1984.Google Scholar
Nader, Ralph, Unstoppable: The Emerging Left-Right Alliance to Dismantle the Corporate State. New York, NY: Nation Books, 2014.Google Scholar
Niskenen, William A., Bureaucracy and Representative Government. Chicago, IL: Aldine-Atherton, 1971.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., “Institutions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5, no. 1 (Winter 1991): 97112.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Structure and Change in Economic History. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 1981.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., Wallis, John Joseph, and Weingast, Barry R., Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009.Google Scholar
Nti, Kofi O., “Rent-Seeking With Asymmetric Valuations.” Public Choice 98, nos. 3/4 (March 1999): 415430.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha, Creating Capabilities: The Human Development Approach. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., “Big Bills Left on the Sidewalk: Why Some Nations Are Rich, Others Poor,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, no. 2 (Spring 1996): 324.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., Power and Prosperity: Outgrowing Communist and Capitalist Dictatorships. New York, NY: Basic Books, 2000.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., “A Theory of the Incentives Facing Political Organizations: Neo-Corporatism and the Hegemonic State.” International Political Science Review 7, no. 2 (April 1986): 165189.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, “Political Coase Theorem.” Public Choice 115, nos. 1/2 (April 2003): 136.Google Scholar
Peltzman, Sam, “An Evaluation of Consumer Protection Legislation: The 1962 Drug Amendments.” Journal of Political Economy 81, no. 5 (October 1973): 10491091.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, “Do Political Institutions Shape Economic Policy?Econometrica 70, no. 3 (May 2002): 883905.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido, Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C., The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan, 1920,Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas, Capitalism in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2014.Google Scholar
Polishchuk, Leonid and Syunaev, Georgiy, “Ruling Elites’ Rotation and Asset Ownership: Implications for Property Rights.” Public Choice 162, nos. 1/2 (January 2015): 159182.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A., “Taxation by Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2, no. 1 (Spring 1971): 2250.Google Scholar
Rand, Ayn, Atlas Shrugged. New York, NY: Signet Classics, 1957.Google Scholar
Rand, Ayn, “The Nature of Government,” in The Virtue of Selfishness. New York, NY: Signet Books, 1961.Google Scholar
Ricardo, David, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, 3rd edn. London: John Murray, 1821.Google Scholar
Rodrik, Dani, “When Ideas Trump Interests: Preferences, World Views, and Policy Innovations.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, no. 1 (Winter 2014): 189208.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul M., “Mathiness in the Theory of Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 105, no. 5 (May 2015): 8993.Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean Jacques, The Social Contract, or Principles of Political Right. Translated by Cole, G. D. H.. www.constitution.org/jjr/socon.htm. 1762.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N., Classical Economics: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume II. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 1995.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N., The Ethics of Liberty. Atlantic Highlands, NJ: Humanities Press, 1982.Google Scholar
Rothbard, Murray N., For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1947.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review of Economics and Statistics 36 (November 1954): 387389.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., “A Diagrammatic Exposition of a Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review of Economics and Statistics 37 (November 1955): 350356.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A., Economics, 9th edn. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 1973.Google Scholar
Schleifer, Andrei and Vishny, Robert W., “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, no. 3 (1993): 599617.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 2nd edn. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1947.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A., History of Economic Analysis. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, 1954.Google Scholar
Schweitzer, Arthur, “Big Business and Private Property under the Nazis.” Journal of Business of the Unitersity of Chicago 19, no. 2 (April 1946): 99126.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter, Clinton Cash: The Untold Story of How and Why Foreign Governments and Businesses Helped Make Bill and Hillary Rich. New York, NY: Harper, Broadside Books, 2015.Google Scholar
Schweizer, Peter, Extortion: How Politicians Extract Your Money, Buy Votes, and Line Their Own Pockets. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin, 2013.Google Scholar
Sen, Anartya, Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1985.Google Scholar
Shayo, Moses, “A Model of Social Identity with an Application to Political Economy: Nation, Class, and Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 103, no. 2 (May 2009): 147174.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam, An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. New York, NY: Modern Library, 1937 [orig. 1776].Google Scholar
Snower, Dennis J. and Bosworth, Steven J.. “Identity-Driven Cooperation Versus Competition.” American Economic Review 106, no. 5 (May 2016): 420424.Google Scholar
Starr, Paul, The Social Transformation of American Medicine. New York, NY: Basic Books, 1982.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., The Theory of Price, 3rd edn. New York, NY: Macmillan, 1966.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J., “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2, no. 1 (Spring 1971): 321.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., The Price of Inequality: How Today’s Divided Society Endangers the Future. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 2012.Google Scholar
Stockman, David A., The Great Deformation: The Corruption of Capitalism in America. New York, NY: Public Affairs Press, 2013.Google Scholar
Streit, Manfred E., “The Mirage of Neo-Corporatism.” Kyklos 41, no. 4 (1988): 603624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Temin, Peter, “Soviet and Nazi Economic Planning in the 1930s.” Economic History Review 44, no. 4 (1991): 573593.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Sunstein, Cass R., Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2008.Google Scholar
Tideman, T. Nicolaus and Tullock, Gordon, “A New and Superior Process for Making Social Choices.” Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 6 (December 1976): 11451159.Google Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis, Democracy in America. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 2007 [orig. 1838].Google Scholar
Tomasson, Richard F., Sweden: Prototype of Modern Society. New York, NY: Random House, 1970.Google Scholar
Truman, David B., The Governmental Process: Political Interests and Public Opinion. New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 1951.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, Economics of Income Redistribution, 2nd edn. New York, NY: Springer, 1997.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, “Efficient Rent-Seeking,” in Buchanan, James M., Tollison, Robert D., and Tullock, Gordon, eds., Towards a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press, 1980: 97112.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, Toward a Mathematics of Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, “The Welfare Cost of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal 5 (June 1967): 224232.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, “The Transitional Gains Trap.” Bell Journal of Economics 6 (Autumn 1975): 671678.Google Scholar
Twight, Charlotte, America’s Emerging Fascist Economy. New Rochelle, NY: Arlington House, 1975.Google Scholar
Vahabi, Mehrdad, “A Positive Theory of the Predatory State.” Public Choice 168, nos. 3/4 (September 2016): 153175.Google Scholar
van Bavel, Bas, The Invisible Hand? How Market Economies Have Emerged and Declined Since AD 500. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2016.Google Scholar
Walras, Leon, Elements of Pure Economics: Or the Theory of Social Wealth. Translated by Jaffe, William. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin, 1954 [orig. 1874].Google Scholar
Weber, Max, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, ed. Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich. New York, NY: Benminster Press, 1968.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Johnsen, Christopher, “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 4 (August 1981): 642664.Google Scholar
Westphal, Larry E. and Kim, Kwang Suk, “Industrial Policy and Development in Korea,” in Balassa, Bela, ed., Development Strategies in Semi-Industrial Economies. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982: 212279.Google Scholar
White, Lawrence H., The Clash of Economic Ideas: The Great Policy Debates and Experiments of the Last Hundred Years. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2012.Google Scholar
White, Richard, Railroaded: The Transcontinentals and the Making of Modern America. New York, NY: W. W. Norton, 2011.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., “A Comparison of Alternative Approaches to Economic Methodology.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146, no. 1 (1990): 6171.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A., The Myth of Democratic Failure. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press, 1995.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald A., “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy, 97 (1989): 13951424.Google Scholar
Yandle, Bruce, “Bootleggers and Baptists: The Education of a Regulatory Economist.” Regulation 7, no. 3 (May–June 1983): 1216.Google Scholar
Yeager, Leland B., Ethics as a Social Science: The Moral Philosophy of Social Cooperation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2001.Google Scholar
Yeager, Leland B., “Rights, Contract, and Utility in Policy Espousal.” Cato Journal 5, no. 1 (Summer 1985): 259294.Google Scholar
Yoo, Jungho, “Myth About Korea’s Rapid Growth,” presented at the International Conference on Institutions and National Competitiveness, Seoul, Korea, August 2009.Google Scholar
Zingales, Luigi, A Capitalism for the People: Recapturing the Lost Genius of American Prosperity. New York, NY: Basic Books, 2012.Google Scholar
Zingales, Luigi, “Towards a Political Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31, no. 3 (September 2017): 113130.Google Scholar
Zupan, Mark A., Inside Job: How Government Insiders Subvert the Public Interest. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2017.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×