Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T13:18:23.522Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Reform and Rebellion in Weak States

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 May 2020

Evgeny Finkel
Affiliation:
The Johns Hopkins University, Maryland
Scott Gehlbach
Affiliation:
University of Chicago

Summary

Throughout history, reform has provoked rebellion - not just by the losers from reform, but also among its intended beneficiaries. Finkel and Gehlbach emphasize that, especially in weak states, reform often must be implemented by local actors with a stake in the status quo. In this setting, the promise of reform represents an implicit contract against which subsequent implementation is measured: when implementation falls short of this promise, citizens are aggrieved and more likely to rebel. Finkel and Gehlbach explore this argument in the context of Russia's emancipation of the serfs in 1861 - a fundamental reform of Russian state and society that paradoxically encouraged unrest among the peasants who were its prime beneficiaries. They further examine the empirical reach of their theory through narrative analyses of the Tanzimat reforms of the nineteenth-century Ottoman Empire, land reform in ancient Rome, the abolition of feudalism during the French Revolution, and land reform in contemporary Latin America.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781108855112
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 11 June 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Bibliography

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A. 2000. Why Did the West Expand the Franchise? Growth, Inequality and Democracy in Historical Perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 11671199.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A. 2001. A Theory of Political Transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938963.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2018. Social Mobility and Stability of Democracy: Re-evaluating De Tocqueville. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 133(2), 10411105.Google Scholar
Acharya, Avidit, and Grillo, Edoardo. 2017. A Behavioral Foundation for Audience Costs. Mimeo. http://stanford.edu/~avidit/audiencecosts.pdf.Google Scholar
Ado, Anatolii. 1987. Krest’iane i Velikaia Frantsuzskaiia Revoliutsiia: Krest’ianskoe Dvizhenie v 1789–1794 gg. Moscow: Izdatel’stvo Moskovskogo Universiteta.Google Scholar
Albertus, Michael. 2015. Autocracy and Redistribution. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Albertus, Michael. 2019. Land Reform and Civil Conflict: Theory and Evidence from Peru. American Journal of Political Science. Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albertus, Michael, and Kaplan, Oliver. 2013. Land Reform as a Counterinsurgency Policy: Evidence from Colombia. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 198231.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Passarelli, Francesco. 2015. Loss Aversion in Politics. NBER Working Paper 21077. www.nber.org/papers/w21077.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansell, Ben, and Samuels, David. 2010. Inequality and Democratization: A Contractarian Approach. Comparative Political Studies, 43(12), 15431574.Google Scholar
Aytekın, E. Attıla. 2012. Peasant Protest in the Late Ottoman Empire: Moral Economy, Revolt, and the Tanzimat Reforms. International Review of Social History, 57(2), 191227.Google Scholar
Aytekın, E. Attıla. 2013. Tax Revolts during the Tanzimat Period (1839–1876) and before the Young Turk Revolution (1904–1908): Popular Protest and State Formation in the Late Ottoman Empire. Journal of Policy History, 25(3), 308333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beard, Mary. 2015. SPQR: A History of Ancient Rome. New York: Liveright.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan. 2016. Aspiration-based Models of Politics. In Krosnick, Jon A., Chiang, I-Chant, A., and Stark, Tobias H. (eds.), Political Psychology: New Explorations. Milton Park, Abingdon, UK: Taylor & Francis, pp. 2960.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, and Meirowitz, Adam. 2004. Spatial Models of Delegation. American Political Science Review, 98(2), 293310.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, Diermeier, Daniel, and Ting, Michael. 2003. A Behavioral Model of Turnout. American Political Science Review, 97(2), 261280.Google Scholar
Benson, Brett V., Meirowitz, Adam, and Ramsay, Kristopher W. 2016. Changing Capabilities, Uncertainty, and the Risk of War in Crisis Bargaining. Research & Politics, 3(3), 16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, Alvin H. 1969. The Rural Crisis in Italy and the Lex Agraria of 133 BC. Ph.D. thesis, Cornell University, Ithaca.Google Scholar
Bertrand, Jacques. 2013. Political Change in Southeast Asia. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy. 2016. Aspirations and the Political Economy of Inequality. Oxford Economic Papers, 69(1), 135.Google Scholar
Blattman, Christopher, and Miguel, Edward. 2010. Civil War. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brady, Nyle C., and Weil, Ray R. 2002. The Nature and Property of Soils. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Bragg, John. 2014. Ottoman Notables and Participatory Politics: Tanzimat Reform in Tokat, 1839–1876. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brisku, Adrian. 2017. Political Reform in the Ottoman and Russian Empires: A Comparative Approach. London: Bloomsbury Publishing.Google Scholar
Brown, J. David, Earle, John S., and Gehlbach, Scott. 2009. Helping Hand or Grabbing Hand? State Bureaucracy and Privatization Effectiveness. American Political Science Review, 103(2), 264283.Google Scholar
Bruce, John W, and Knox, Anna. 2009. Structures and Stratagems: Making Decentralization of Authority over Land in Africa Cost-Effective. World Development, 37(8), 13601369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin F., Loewenstein, George, and Rabin, Matthew (eds.). 2004. Advances in Behavioral Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dower, Castañeda, Paul, Finkel, Evgeny, Gehlbach, Scott, and Nafziger, Steven. 2018. Collective Action and Representation in Autocracies: Evidence from Russia’s Great Reforms. American Political Science Review, 112(1), 125147.Google Scholar
Dower, Castañeda, Paul and Markevich, Andrei. 2017. The Stolypin Reform and Agricultural Productivity in Late Imperial Russia. Mimeo. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2361860.Google Scholar
Chong, Dennis. 2014. Collective Action and the Civil Rights Movement. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cleaves, Peter S., and Scurrah, Martin J. 1980. Agriculture, Bureaucracy, and Military Government in Peru. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Cobban, Alfred. 1999. The Social Interpretation of the French Revolution. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Davies, James C. 1962. Toward a Theory of Revolution. American Sociological Review, 27(1), 519.Google Scholar
de Janvry, Alain. 1981. The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville, Alexis. 2002 [1835/40]. Democracy in America. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville, Alexis. 2008 [1856]. The Ancien Régime and the Revolution. New York: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
de Tocqueville, Alexis. 2011 [1856]. The Ancien Régime and the French Revolution. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, Stefano. 2009. Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(2), 315372.Google Scholar
Dennison, Tracy. 2011. The Institutional Framework of Russian Serfdom. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dewatripont, Mathias, and Roland, Gérard. 1992. Economic Reform and Dynamic Political Constraints. Review of Economic Studies, 59(4), 703730.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewatripont, Mathias, and Roland, Gérard. 1995. The Design of Reform Packages under Uncertainty. American Economic Review, 85(5), 12071223.Google Scholar
Dimitrov, Martin. 2013. Why Communism Did Not Collapse: Understanding Authoritarian Regime Resilience in Asia and Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Domar, Evsey D. 1970. The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis. The Journal of Economic History, 30(1), 1832.Google Scholar
Domar, Evsey D., and Machina, Mark J. 1984. On the Profitability of Russian Serfdom. The Journal of Economic History, 44(4), 919955.Google Scholar
Dubow, Saul. 2014. Apartheid, 1948–1994. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Duncan, Mike. 2017. The Storm before the Storm: The Beginning of the End of the Roman Empire. New York: PublicAffairs Books.Google Scholar
Dunning, Thad. 2008. Crude Democracy: Natural Resource Wealth and Political Regimes. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Easley, Roxanne. 2002. Opening Public Space: The Peace Arbitrator and Rural Politicization, 1861–1864. Slavic Review, 61(4), 707731.Google Scholar
Eckstein, Harry. 1975. Case Studies and Theory in Political Science. In Greenstein, Fred I., and Polsby, Nelson W. (eds), Handbook of Political Science, Volume 7. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, pp. 94137.Google Scholar
Evtuhov, Catherine. 2011. Portrait of a Russian Province. Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1995. Rationalist Explanations for War. International Organization, 49(3), 379414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, Daniel. 1976. Rebels in the Name of the Tsar. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
Finkel, Evgeny, and Gehlbach, Scott. 2018. The Tocqueville Paradox: When Does Reform Prevent Rebellion? Mimeo. https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3202013.Google Scholar
Finkel, Evgeny, Gehlbach, Scott, and Olsen, Tricia D. 2015. Does Reform Prevent Rebellion? Evidence from Russia’s Emancipation of the Serfs. Comparative Political Studies, 48(8), 9841019.Google Scholar
Gailmard, Sean, and Patty, John. 2012. Formal Models of Bureaucracy. Annual Review of Political Science, 15, 353377.Google Scholar
Gandhi, Jennifer, and Przeworski, Adam. 2006. Cooperation, Cooptation, and Rebellion under Dictatorship. Economics and Politics, 18(1), 126.Google Scholar
Gehlbach, Scott. 2008. What Is a Big Bureaucracy? Reflections on Rebuilding Leviathan and Runaway State-Building. Czech Sociological Review, 44(6), 11891197.Google Scholar
Gehlbach, Scott, Sonin, Konstantin, and Svolik, Milan. 2016. Formal Models of Nondemocratic Politics. Annual Review of Political Science, 19, 565–84.Google Scholar
Gerring, John. 2007. Is There a (Viable) Crucial-Case Method? Comparative Political Studies, 40(3), 231253.Google Scholar
Gerschenkron, Alexander. 1965. Agrarian Policies and Industrialization in Russia 1861–1917. The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 6(2), 706800.Google Scholar
Grieder, Peter. 2012. The German Democratic Republic. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Grillo, Edoardo. 2016. The Hidden Cost of Raising Voters’ Expectations: Reference Dependence and Politicians’ Credibility. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 130, 126143.Google Scholar
Gurr, Ted R. 1970. Why Men Rebel. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R. 1992. The Politics of Economic Adjustment: International Constraints, Distributive Conflicts, and the State. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, Stephan, and Kaufman, Robert R. 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hanioğlu, M. Şükrü. 2010. A Brief History of The Late Ottoman Empire. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Holmstrom, Bengt. 2010. A Theory of Firm Scope. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(2), 483513.Google Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Moore, John. 2008. Contracts as Reference Points. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1), 148.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew, Kosec, Katrina, and Mo, Cecilia Hyunjung. 2017. Economic Development, Mobility, and Political Discontent: An Experimental Test of Tocqueville’s Thesis in Pakistan. American Political Science Review, 111(3), 605621.Google Scholar
Hoch, Steven L. 1989. Serfdom and Social Control in Russia: Petrovskoe, a Village in Tambov. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hoch, Steven L. 1991. The Banking Crisis, Economic Reform, and Economic Development in Russia, 1857–1861. American Historical Review, 96(3), 795820.Google Scholar
Hoch, Steven L. 2004. Did Russia’s Emancipated Serfs Really Pay Too Much for Too Little Land? Statistical Anomalies and Long-Tailed Distributions. Slavic Review, 63(2), 247274.Google Scholar
Hopkins, Keith. 1978. Conquerors and Slaves. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Howarth, Randall S. 1999. Rome, the Italians, and the Land. Historia: Zeitschrift fur Alte Geschichte, 48(3), 282300.Google Scholar
Huber, John D., and McCarty, Nolan. 2004. Bureaucratic Capacity, Delegation, and Political Reform. American Political Science Review, 98(3), 481494.Google Scholar
Humphreys, Macartan, and Weinstein, Jeremy M. 2008. Who Fights? The Determinants of Participation in Civil War. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 436455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huntington, Samuel P. 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
İnalcık, Halil. 1976. Application of the Tanzimat and its Social Effects. Lisse: Peter De Ridder Press.Google Scholar
Ivanov, Leonid (ed.). 1964. Krest’ianskoe Dvizhenie v Rossii v 1861–1869 gg.: Sbornik Dokumentov. Moscow: Mysl’.Google Scholar
Javeline, Debra. 2003a. Protest and the Politics of Blame: The Russian Response to Unpaid Wages. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Javeline, Debra. 2003b. The Role of Blame in Collective Action: Evidence from Russia. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 107121.Google Scholar
Jones, Peter M. 1988. The Peasantry in the French Revolution. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L., and Thaler, Richard H. 1990. Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 13251348.Google Scholar
Kay, Cristóbal. 2001. Reflections on Rural Violence in Latin America. Third World Quarterly, 22(5), 741775.Google Scholar
Khristoforov, Igor’. 2011. Sud’ba Reformy: Russkoe krest’ianstvo v pravitel’stvennoi politike do i posle otmeny krepostnogo prava (1830–1890-e gg.). Moscow: Sobranie.Google Scholar
Wirtschafter, Kimerling, Elise. 2008. Russia’s Age of Serfdom: 1649–1861. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L. 1989. The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves. American Economic Review, 79(5), 12771284.Google Scholar
Kőszegi, Botond, and Rabin, Matthew. 2006. A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 11331165.Google Scholar
Lapp, Nancy. 2004. Landing Votes: Representation and Land Reform in Latin America. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lockwood, Ben, and Rockey, James. 2015. Negative Voters: Electoral Competition with Loss-Aversion. Mimeo. www.le.ac.uk/economics/research/RePEc/lec/leecon/dp15-15.pdf.Google Scholar
Markevich, Andrei, and Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina. 2018. The Economic Effects of the Abolition of Serfdom: Evidence from the Russian Empire. American Economic Review, 108(4–5), 10741117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Markoff, John. 1996. Abolition of Feudalism: Peasants, Lords, and Legislators in the French Revolution. University Park, PA: Penn State University Press.Google Scholar
Mason, T. David. 1998. ‘Take Two Acres and Call Me in the Morning’: Is Land Reform a Prescription for Peasant Unrest? The Journal of Politics, 60(1), 199230.Google Scholar
Mayer, Enrique. 2009. Ugly Stories of The Peruvian Agrarian Reform. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
McPhee, Peter. 2016. Liberty or Death: The French Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Miller, Michael K. 2013. Electoral Authoritarianism and Democracy: A Formal Model of Regime Transitions. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 25(2), 153181.Google Scholar
Mo, Cecilia Hyunjung. 2018. Perceived Relative Deprivation and Risk: An Aspiration-Based Model of Human Trafficking Vulnerability. Political Behavior, 40(1), 247277.Google Scholar
Moon, David. 2001a. The Abolition of Serfdom in Russia. New York: Longman.Google Scholar
Moon, David. 2001b. The Inventory Reform and Peasant Unrest in Right-Bank Ukraine in 1847–48. The Slavonic and East European Review, 79(4), 653697.Google Scholar
Moulin, Annie. 1991. Peasantry and Society in France since 1789. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Oberschall, Anthony. 1995. Social Movements: Ideologies, Interests, and Identities. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Okun’, Semen (ed.). 1962. Krest’ianskoe Dvizhenie v Rossii v 1850–1856 gg.: Sbornik Dokumentov. Moscow: Izdatel’stvo sotsial’no-ekonomicheskoi literatury.Google Scholar
Okun’, Semen, and Sivkov, Konstantin (eds.). 1963. Krest’ianskoe Dvizhenie v Rossii v 1857–mae 1861 gg.: Sbornik Dokumentov. Moscow: Izdatel’stvo sotsial’no-ekonomicheskoi literatury.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Passarelli, Francesco, and Tabellini, Guido. 2017. Emotions and Political Unrest. Journal of Political Economy, 125(3), 903946.Google Scholar
Pinson, Mark. 1975. Ottoman Bulgaria in the First Tanzimat Period: The Revolts in Nish (1841) and Vidin (1850). Middle Eastern Studies, 11(2), 103146.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2009. Conquered or Granted? A History of Suffrage Extensions. British Journal of Political Science, 39(2), 291321.Google Scholar
Pushkarev, Sergei G. 1968. The Russian Peasants’ Reaction to the Emancipation of 1861. Russian Review, 27(2), 199214.Google Scholar
Quataert, Donald. 1993. Workers, Peasants, and Economic Change in the Ottoman Empire, 1730–1914. Istanbul: Isis Press.Google Scholar
Quataert, Donald. 1994. The Age of Reforms, 1812–1914. In İnalcık, Halil, and Quataert, Donald (eds.), An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, Volume II. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1993. Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics. American Economic Review, 83(5), 12811302.Google Scholar
Rauch, James E., and Evans, Peter. 2000. Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less Developed Countries. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 4962.Google Scholar
Richardson, John S. 1980. The Ownership of Roman Land: Tiberius Gracchus and the Italians. The Journal of Roman Studies, 70, 111.Google Scholar
Robertson, Graeme B. 2011. The Politics of Protest in Hybrid Regimes: Managing Dissent in Post-Communist Russia. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Roselaar, Saskia T. 2010. Public Land in the Roman Republic: A Social and Economic History of Ager Publicus in Italy, 396–89 BC. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenbaum, Paul R. 1984. The Consquences of Adjustment for a Concomitant Variable that Has Been Affected by the treatment. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (General), 656666.Google Scholar
Schiavo-Campo, Salvatore, de Tommaso, Giulio, and Mukherjee, Amitabha. 1997. An International Statistical Survey of Government Employment and Wages. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1806.Google Scholar
Scott, James C. 1976. The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Seligmann, Linda J. 1995. Between Reform and Revolution: Political Struggles in the Peruvian Andes, 1969–1991. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Seligson, Mitchell A. 1984. Implementing Land Reform: The Case of Costa Rica. Managing International Development, 1(2), 2946.Google Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi. 2014. Mobilization, Repression, and Revolution: Grievances and Opportunities in Contentious Politics. Journal of Politics, 76(3), 621635.Google Scholar
Shaw, Stanford J., and Shaw, Ezel Kural. 1977. History of the Ottoman Empire and Modern Turkey: Volume 2. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shochat, Yanir. 1970. The ‘Lex Agraria’ of 133 BC and the Italian Allies. Athenaeum, 48, 2545.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Spillane, James P. 2000. Cognition and Policy Implementation: District Policymakers and the Reform of Mathematics Education. Cognition and Instruction, 18(2), 141179.Google Scholar
Starr, Frederick S. 2015. Decentralization and Self-government in Russia, 1830–1870. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Stockton, David. 1979. The Gracchi. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 1995. Cultures in Conflict: Social Movements and the State in Peru. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2012. The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tarrow, Sidney. 1989. Struggle, Politics, and Reform: Collective Action, Social Movements and Cycles of Protest. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Center for International Studies.Google Scholar
Tarrow, Sidney. 2011. Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Politics (Third Edition). New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. 1980. Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(1), 3960.Google Scholar
Thiesenhusen, William C. 1995. Broken Promises: Agrarian Reform and the Latin American Campesino. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Thome, Joseph R. 1989. Law, Conflict, and Change: Frei’s Law and Allende’s Agrarian Reform. In Thiesenhusen, William C. (ed.), Thiesenhusen, William C.(ed.)Searching for Agrarian Reform in Latin America. Boston, MA.Google Scholar
Ting, Michael M. 2011. Organizational Capacity. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27(2), 245271.Google Scholar
Tsentr Ekonomicheskikh i Politicheskikh Reform. 2018. Rost protestnoi aktivnosti naseleniia: Resul’taty vserossiiskogo monitoringa 2017–2018 gg. http://cepr.su/2018/11/08/protests–2017–2018.Google Scholar
Tuma, Elias H. 1965. Twenty-Six Centuries of Agrarian Reform: A Comparative Analysis. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Ust’iantseva, N. 1992. Institut Mirovykh Posrednikov v Krest’ianskoi Reforme. Pages 166–183 of: Zakharova, Larisa, Eklof, Ben, and Bushnell, John (eds), Velikie Reformy v Rossii: 1856–1874. Moscow: Izdatel’stvo Moskovskogo Universiteta.Google Scholar
van Zomeren, Martijn, Spears, Russell, Fischer, Agneta H., and Leach, Colin Wayne. 2004. Put Your Money Where Your Mouth Is! Explaining Collective Action Tendencies Through Group-Based Anger and Group Efficacy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87, 649664.Google Scholar
van Zomeren, Martijn, Leach, Colin Wayne, and Spears, Russell. 2012. Protesters as “Passionate Economists”: A Dynamic Dual Pathway Model of Approach Coping with Collective Disadvantage. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 16(2), 180199.Google Scholar
Volin, Lazar. 1943. The Russian Peasant and Serfdom. Agricultural History, 17(1), 4161.Google Scholar
Watts, Edward J. 2018. Mortal Republic: How Rome Fell into Tyranny. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wood, Elisabeth Jean. 2003. Insurgent Collective Action and Civil War in El Salvador. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Zaionchkovskii, Petr. 1968. Otmena Krepostnogo Prava v Rossii. 3rd edn. Moscow: Prosveshchenie.Google Scholar
Zaionchkovskii, Petr, and Paina, Esfir’ (eds.). 1968. Krest’ianskoe Dvizhenie v Rossii v 1870–1880 gg.: Sbornik Dokumentov. Moscow: Nauka.Google Scholar
Zamosc, Leon. 1986. The Agrarian Question and the Peasant Movement in Colombia: Struggles of the National Peasant Association, 1967–1981. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Zürcher, Erik J. 2004. Turkey: A Modern History. London: IB Tauris.Google Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Reform and Rebellion in Weak States
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Reform and Rebellion in Weak States
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Reform and Rebellion in Weak States
Available formats
×