Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-11T06:09:20.380Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Inequality and Optimal Redistribution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2019

Hannu Tanninen
Affiliation:
University of Eastern Finland
Matti Tuomala
Affiliation:
University of Tampere, Finland
Elina Tuominen
Affiliation:
University of Tampere, Finland

Summary

From the 1980s onward, income inequality increased in many advanced countries. It is very difficult to account for the rise in income inequality using the standard labour supply/demand explanation. Fiscal redistribution has become less effective in compensating increasing inequalities since the 1990s. Some of the basic features of redistribution can be explained through the optimal tax framework developed by J. A. Mirrlees in 1971. This Element surveys some of the earlier results in linear and nonlinear taxation and produces some new numerical results. Given the key role of capital income in the overall income inequality, it also considers the optimal taxation of capital income. It examines empirically the relationship between the extent of redistribution and the components of the Mirrlees framework. The redistributive role of factors such as publicly provided private goods, public employment, endogenous wages in the overlapping generations model and income uncertainty are analysed.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781108567503
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 28 March 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aaberge, R. (2000), Characterizations of Lorenz curves and income distributions, Social Choice and Welfare 17, 639653.Google Scholar
Aaberge, R. and Colombino, U. (2006), Designing optimal taxes with a microeconometric model of household labour supply, IZA, DP No. 2468.Google Scholar
Adler, M. (2012), Well-Being and Fair Distribution: A Framework for Policy Analysis, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ahmad, E. and Stern, N. (1984), The theory of reform and Indian indirect taxes, Journal of Public Economics 25, 259298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aitchison, J. and Brown, J. A. C. (1957), The Lognormal Distribution, London, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Alstadsaeter, A. and Jacob, M. (2016), Dividend taxes and income shifting, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 118(4), 693717.Google Scholar
Apps, P., Long, N. V. and Rees, R. (2013), Optimal piecewise linear income taxation, Journal of Public Economic Theory 16(4), 523545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aronsson, T. and Johansson-Stenman, O. (2008), When the Joneses’ consumption hurts: Optimal public good provision and nonlinear income taxation, Journal of Public Economics 92, 986997.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Association of Finnish Local and Regional Authorities (2017).Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1973), ‘La Maxi-Min’ et l’Imposition Optimale des Revenus, Cahiers du Séminaire d’Econométrie’, 1975, No. 16: 73–86 (French version of University of Essex discussion paper No. 47, January 1973, ‘Maxi-Min’ and Optimal Income Taxation’, accepted for publication by the Review of Economic Studies, but never resubmitted).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1990), Public economics and the economic public, European Economic Review 34, 225248 (Presidential Address to the European Economic Association Annual Congress in Augsburg, September 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1995), Public economics in action: The basic income/flat tax proposal, Lindahl Lectures, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (1999), Is rising income inequality inevitable? A critique of transatlantic consensus, Wider Annual Lectures 3. Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (2012), The Mirrlees Review and the state of public economics, Journal of Economic Literature 50(3), 770780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (2014), Public economics in age of austerity. The Graz Schumpeter Lecture, Routledge.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Brandolini, A. (2001), Promise and pitfalls in the use of ‘secondary’ data-sets: Income inequality in OECD countries as a case study, Journal of Economic Literature 39(3), 771799.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Brandolini, A. (2010), On analyzing the world distribution of income, World Bank Economic Review 24(1), 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Piketty, T. (eds.) (2010), Top Incomes: A Global Perspective, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B., Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2011), Top incomes in the long-run of history, Journal of Economic Literature 49(1), 371.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Sandmo, A. (1980), Welfare implications of the taxation of savings, Economic Journal 90, 529549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1976), The design of tax structure: Direct versus indirect taxation, Journal of Public Economics 6(1–2), 5575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1980), Lectures in Public Economics, New York, NY, McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Banks, J. and Diamond, P. (2010), The base for direct taxation, in Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review, ed. Adam, S., Besley, T., Blundell, R., Bond, S., Chote, R., Gammie, M., Johnson, P., Myles, G. and Poterba, J.. Oxford, Oxford University Press, 548–648.Google Scholar
Bargain, O., Dolls, M., Neumann, D., Peichl, A. and Siegloch, S. (2014), Comparing inequality aversion across countries when labor supply responses differ, International Tax and Public Finance 21(5), 845873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bastani, S. and Lundberg, J. (2017). Political preferences for redistribution in Sweden, Journal of Economic Inequality 15(4), 345367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bastani, S. and Waldenström, D. (2018), How should capital be taxed? Theory and evidence from Sweden, CEPR Discussion Papers 12880.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, D. G. and Rangel, A. (2007), Behavioural public economics: Welfare and policy analysis with non-standard decision makers, in Behavioural Economics and Its Applications, ed. Diamond, P. and Vartiainen, H., Princeton, NJ, Princeton University Press, 7–84.Google Scholar
Blackorby, C. and Donaldson, D. (1988), Cash versus kind, self selection and efficient transfers,American Economic Review 78, 691700.Google Scholar
Blanchflower, D. and Oswald, A. (2004), Well-being over time in Britain and the USA, Journal of Public Economics 88, 13591386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, S. (1993), Interdependent behaviour and the effect of taxes, Journal of Public Economics, 51, 211218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, S. and Christiansen, V. (1995), Public provision of private goods as a redistributive device in an optimum income model, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97(4), 547567.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, S. and Christiansen, V. (1998), Price subsidies versus public provision, International Tax and Public Finance 5(3), 283306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, S., Christiansen, V. and Micheletto, L. (2010), Public provision of private goods and nondistortionary marginal tax rates, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2, 127.Google Scholar
Boadway, R. (2012), From Optimal Tax Theory to Tax Policy: Retrospective and Prospective Views, the 2009 Munich Lectures, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, R. and Jacquet, L. (2008), Optimal marginal and average income taxation under maximin, Journal of Economic Theory 143, 425441.Google Scholar
Boadway, R. and Marchand, M. (1995), The use of public expenditures for redistributive purposes, Oxford Economic Papers 47(1), 4559.Google Scholar
Boadway, R., Marchand, M. and Sato, M. (1998), Subsidies versus public provision of private goods as instruments for redistribution, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 100(39), 545564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, R. and Sato, M. (2011), Optimal income taxation with uncertain earnings: A synthesis, CESIfo Working Papers 3654, CESIfo Group, Munich.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, R., Marchand, M., and Pestieau, P. (2000), Redistribution with unobservable bequests: A case for taxing capital income, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 102(2), 253267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boskin, M. J. and Sheshinski, E. (1978), Individual welfare depends upon relative income, Quarterly Journal of Economics 92, 589601.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F. and Spadaro, A. (2012), Tax-benefit revealed social preferences, Journal of Economic Inequality 10(1), 75108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. and Park, Y. (2005), Emulation, inequality, and work hours: Was Thorsten Veblen right?Economic Journal 115, F397F412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brett, C. (1997), Notes on non-linear taxation in an OLG model. University of Essex. mimeo.Google Scholar
Chamley, C. (1986), Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives, Econometrica 54(3), 607622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Champernowne, D. G. (1937), Notes on Income Distribution, Econometrica, Report of Econometric Conference at New College in 1936.Google Scholar
Champernowne, D. G. (1952), The graduation of income distributions, Econometrica 20, 591615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Champernowne, D. G. and Cowell, F. A. (1999), Economic Inequality and Income Distribution, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Chetty, R. (2006), A new method of estimating risk aversion, American Economic Review 96(5), 18211834.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, V. (1981), Evaluation of public projects under optimal taxation, Review of Economic Studies 48, 447457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, V. and Jansen, E. S. (1978). Implicit social preferences in the Norwegian system of social preferences, Journal of Public Economics 10, 217245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, V. and Tuomala, M. (2008), On taxing capital income with income shifting, International Tax and Public Finance 15(4), 527545.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowell, F. (1977), Measuring Inequality, Oxford University Press, 3rd edn (2011).Google Scholar
Cowell, F. and Gardiner, K. (1999), Welfare weights, LSE, mimeo.Google Scholar
Creedy, J. (2009), An approximation for the optimal linear income tax rate, Australian Economic Papers 48(3), 224236.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, H. and Gahvari, F. (1997), In-kind transfers, self-selection and optimal tax policy, European Economic Review 41(1), 97114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, H., Pestieau, P. and Rochet, J.-C. (2003), Capital income taxation when inherited wealth is not observable, Journal of Public Economics 87, 24752490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahan, M. and Strawczynski, M. (2012), Optimal asymptotic income tax rate, Journal of Public Economic Theory 14(5), 737755.Google Scholar
Deininger, K. and Squire, L. (1996), A new data set measuring income inequality, World Bank Economic Review 10(3), 565591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1965), National debt in a neo-classical growth model, American Economic Review 55, 11261150.Google Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1968), Negative taxes and the poverty problem – A review article, National Tax Journal 21(3), 288303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P. A. (1998), Optimal income taxation: An example with a U-shaped pattern of optimal marginal tax rates, American Economic Review 88(1), 8395.Google Scholar
Eaton, J. and Rosen, H. S. (1980), Optimal redistributive taxation and uncertainty, Quarterly Journal of Economics 95(2), 357364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldstein, M. (2012), The Mirrlees review, Journal of Economic Literature 50(3), 781790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, J., Greer, J. and Thorbecke, E. (1984), A class of decomposable poverty measures, Econometrica 52, 761766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerritsen, A. (2016), Optimal nonlinear taxation: The dual approach. Working Paper of the Max Planck Institute for Tax Law and Public Finance No. 2016–2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruber, J. and Saez, E. (2002), The elasticity of taxable income: Evidence and implications, Journal of Public Economics 84, 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harju, J. and Matikka, T. (2016), The elasticity of taxable income and income shifting: What is ‘real’ and what is not? International Tax and Public Finance 23(4), 640669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsu, M. and Yang, C. C. (2013), Optimal linear and two-bracket income taxes with idiosyncratic earnings risk, Journal of Public Economics 105, 5871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Immervoll, H. and Richardson, L. (2011), Redistribution policy and inequality reduction in OECD countries: What has changed in two decades? OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers, No. 122, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5kg5dlkhjq0x-en (24 January 2016).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Immonen, R., Kanbur, R., Keen, M. and Tuomala, M. (1998), Tagging and taxing: The optimal use of categorical and income information, Economica 65, 179192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, N. (2001), Optimal income tax in the presence of status effects, Journal of Public Economics 81, 193212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, B., Jongen, E. L. W. and Zoutman, F. T. (2017), Revealed social preferences of Dutch political parties, Journal of Public Economics 156, 81100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jäntti, M., Riihelä, M., Sullström, R. and Tuomala, M. (2010), Trends in top income shares in Finland, in Top Incomes: A Global Perspective, ed. Atkinson, A. B. and Piketty, T., Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Judd, K. (1985), Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model, Journal of Public Economics 28(1), 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R., Keen, M. and Tuomala, M. (1994), Optimal non-linear income taxation for the alleviation of income-poverty, European Economic Review 38, 16131632.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R., Paukkeri, T., Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2018), Optimal taxation and public provision for poverty minimization, International Tax and Public Finance 25(1), 6498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R., Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2008), Moral hazard, income taxation and prospect theory, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110(2), 321337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R. and Tuomala, M. (1994), Inherent inequality and the optimal graduation of marginal tax rates, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 96(2), 275282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R. and Tuomala, M. (2010), Charitable conservatism, poverty radicalism and inequality aversion, Journal of Economic Inequality 9(3), 417431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R. and Tuomala, M. (2013), Relativity, inequality, and optimal nonlinear income taxation, International Economic Review 54(4), 11991217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanbur, R. and Tuomala, M. (2014), Groupings and the gains from tagging, Tampere Economic Working Papers, Net Series No. 86, University of Tampere.Google Scholar
Kaplow, L. (2010), Concavity of utility, concavity of welfare, and redistribution of income, International Tax Public Finance 17, 2542.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keane, M. and Moffitt, R. (2001), A structural model of multiple welfare program participation and labor supply, International Economic Review 39(3), 553589.Google Scholar
Kesselman, J. R. and Garfinkel, I. (1978), Professor Friedman, meet Lady Rhys-Williams: NIT vs. CIT, Journal of Public Economics 10(2), 179216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindhe, T., Södersten, J. and Öberg, A. (2002), Economic effects of taxing closed corporations under a dual income tax, Ifo Studies 48, 575610.Google Scholar
Lockwood, B. B., Nathanson, C. and Glen Weyl, E. (2012), Taxation and the Allocation of Talent. Unpublished.Google Scholar
Lockwood, B. B. and Weinzierl, M. (2016), Positive and normative judgments implicit in U.S. tax policy, and the costs of unequal growth and recessions, Journal of Monetary Economics 77, 3047.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Low, H. and Maldoom, D. (2004), Optimal taxation, prudence and risk-sharing, Journal of Public Economics 88, 443464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, G. N., Weinzierl, M. and Yagan, D. (2009), Optimal taxation in theory and practice, Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(4), 147174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Micheletto, L. (2011), Optimal nonlinear redistributive taxation and public good provision in an economy with Veblen effects, Journal of Public Economic Theory 13(1), 7196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. (1971), An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation, Review of Economic Studies 38, 175208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. (1974), Notes on welfare economics, information and uncertainty, in Essays in Equilibrium Behaviour under Uncertainty, ed. Balch, M., McFadden, D., and Wu, S., Amsterdam, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. (1976), Optimal tax theory: A synthesis, Journal of Public Economics 6, 327358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. A. (1990), Taxing uncertain incomes, Oxford Economic Papers 42, 3445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naito, H. (1999), Re-examination of uniform commodity taxes under a non-linear income tax system and its implication for production efficiency, Journal of Public Economics 71, 165188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nichols, A. L. and Zeckhauser, R. J. (1982), Targeting transfers through restrictions on recipients, American Economic Review 72, 372377.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (2001), Choice and procrastination, Quarterly Journal of Economics 116, 121160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (2003), Studying optimal paternalism, illustrated by a model of sin taxes, American Economic Review 93, 186191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ordover, J. and Phelps, E. (1979), The concept of optimal taxation in the overlapping generations model of capital and wealth, Journal of Public Economics 2, 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oswald, A. (1983), Altruism, jealousy and the theory of optimal nonlinear taxation, Journal of Public Economics 20, 7787.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pareto, V. (1896), Cours d’économie politique professé a l’université de Lausanne, Vol. I 1896, Vol. II 1897.Google Scholar
Parfit, D. (1991), Equality or Priority, Lindley Lecture.Google Scholar
Park, N.-H. (1991), Steady-state solutions of optimal tax mixes in an overlapping generations model, Journal of Public Economics 46, 227246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, M. and Sandmo, A. (2005), Taxation and tournaments, Journal of Public Economic Theory 7, 543559.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. (1997), La redistribution fiscale face au chômage, Revue française d’économie 12(1), 157201.Google Scholar
Piketty, T., Saez, E. and Stantcheva, S. (2014), Optimal taxation of top labor incomes: A tale of three elasticities, American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6(1), 230271.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. and Zucman, G. (2014), Capital is back: Wealth-income ratios in rich countries 1700–2010, Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3), 11551210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Selin, H. (2011), Income shifting within a dual income tax system: evidence from the Finnish tax reform of 1993, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 113(1), 120144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2001), On optimal non-linear taxation and public good provision in an overlapping generations economy, Journal of Public Economics 79, 485501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2002), Publicly provided private goods and redistribution: A general equilibrium approach, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104(1), 173188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2004), Poverty alleviation and tax policy. European Economic Review 48, 10751090.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2005), Public versus private production decisions: Redistribution and the size of the public sector, FinanzArchiv 61(1), 120137.Google Scholar
Pirttilä, J. and Tuomala, M. (2007), Labour income uncertainty, taxation and public good provision, Economic Journal 117, 567582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971), Theory of Justice., Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J. (1974), Some reasons for the maxi-min criterion, American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings.141146.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1982), Social unity and primary goods, in Utilitarianism and Beyond, ed. Sen, A. and Williams, B., Cambridge University Press, 159185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Revesz, J. T. (1989), The optimal taxation of labour income, Public Finance/Finances Publiques 44, 433475.Google Scholar
Riihelä, M., Sullström, R. and Tuomala, M. (2007), Varallisuuserot kasvussa, in Kasvun hedelmät, ed. Taimio, H., Helsinki, TSL (in Finnish).Google Scholar
Riihelä, M., Sullström, R. and Tuomala, M. (2014), Top incomes and top tax rates: Implications for optimal taxation of top incomes in Finland, Tampere Economic Working Papers, Net series No. 88, University of Tampere.Google Scholar
Roberts, K. (2000), A reconsideration of optimal income tax, in Incentives, Organization and Public Economics, Papers in Honour of Sir James Mirrlees, ed. Hammond, P. and Myles, G., Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (1998), Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy 106(5), 9971032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, C. and Scheuer, F. (2014), Optimal Taxation with Rent-Seeking. www.wiwi.uni-frankfurt.de/kolloquium/ws1213_/Scheuer.pdf.Google Scholar
Sadka, E. (1976), On income distribution, incentive effects and optimal income taxation, Review of Economic Studies 43(2), 261267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, E. (2001), Using elasticities to derive optimal income tax rates, Review of Economic Studies 68, 205229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saez, E. and Stantcheva, S. (2016), A simpler theory of optimal capital taxation, NBER Working Paper No. 22664.Google Scholar
Sandmo, A. (1983), Ex post welfare economics and the theory of merit goods, Economica 50, 1933.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seade, J (1980), Optimal non-linear policies for non-utilitarian motives, in Income Distribution: The Limits to Redistribution, ed. Collard, D. A., Lecomber, R. and Slater, M., Bristol, Scientechnica.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1974), Informational bases of alternative welfare approaches: Aggregation and income distribution, Journal of Public Economics 3(4), 387403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheshinski, E. (1972), The optimal linear income tax, Review of Economic Studies 39(3), 297302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slemrod, J., Yitzhaki, S., Mayshar, J. and Lundholm, M. (1994), The optimal two-bracket linear income tax, Journal of Public Economics 53(2), 269290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stern, N. (1976), On the specification of optimum income taxation, Journal of Public Economics 6, 123162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stern, N. (1977), Welfare weights and the elasticity of the marginal valuation of income, in Studies in Modern Economic Analysis, ed. Artis, M. and Nobay, R., Oxford, Basil Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1987), Pareto-efficient and optimal taxation and the new welfare economics, in Handbook of Public Economics, Vol. II, ed. Auerbach, A., and Feldstein, M., Amsterdam, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Straub, L. and Werning, I. (2014), Positive long run capital taxation: Chamley-Judd revisited, NBER Working Paper No. 20441.Google Scholar
Tanninen, H. and Tuomala, M. (2005), Inherent inequality and the extent of redistribution in OECD Countries. CESifo DICE Report 3(1), 4853.Google Scholar
Tanninen, H. and Tuomala, M. (2008), Work hours, inequality and redistribution: Veblen effects reconsidered. Tampere Economic Working Papers, Net Series No. 70, University of Tampere.Google Scholar
Tanninen, H., Tuomala, M. and Tuominen, E. (2018), Income inequality, redistributive preferences and the extent of redistribution: An empirical application of optimal tax approach. Tampere Economic Working Papers, Net Series No. 124, University of Tampere.Google Scholar
Thoresen, T. O. and Alstadsaeter, A. (2010), Shifts in organizational form under a dual income tax system, FinanzArchiv 66(4), 384418.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuomala, M. (1979), Optimal Income Taxation and Uncertainty, mimeo, University of HelsinkiGoogle Scholar
Tuomala, M. (1984), Optimal degree of progressivity under income uncertainty, Scandinavian Journal of Economics 87, 184–93.Google Scholar
Tuomala, M. (1986), On the optimal income taxation and educational decisions, Journal of Public Economics 30, 183198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuomala, M. (1990), Optimal Income Tax and Redistribution, New York, NY, and Oxford, Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuomala, M. (2016), Optimal Redistributive Taxation. Oxford, Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. (1980), Redistributive taxation as social insurance, Journal of Public Economics 14, 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weinzierl, M C. (2012), Why do we redistribute so much but tag so little? The principle of equal sacrifice and optimal taxation, Harvard Business School Working Paper, No. 12–64.Google Scholar
Wilson, R. (1993), Nonlinear Pricing. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Inequality and Optimal Redistribution
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Inequality and Optimal Redistribution
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Inequality and Optimal Redistribution
Available formats
×