Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gxg78 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T16:57:43.595Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Explaining choice of development strategies: suggestions from Mexico, 1970–1982

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

David R. Mares
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor of Political Science at the University of California, San Diego.
Get access

Abstract

Economic development requires choices among a broad spectrum of alternative strategies and, as the recent experience of Mexico suggests, those choices are not easy. A complex politics is involved in the transition from one development strategy to another. The international political economy and domestic social coalitions both influence the costs and benefits associated with various development policies; they rule out some choices, but numerous options still remain. How can one explain actual outcomes? Observers may significantly increase their ability to explain outcomes by incorporating a statist component into their analyses. Within the very broad parameters set by the international political economy the state influences (but does not determine) the creation and the demands of the social coalition itself. In addition, the state may use policy instruments and advantages from the domestic and international arenas to implement policy even in the face of domestic opposition. The structure of the domestic political economy determines the space within which the statist perspective contributes to explanatory power. Eventually, it is in a historically based ideology that the chief explanation for the state's choice of policy and the construction of particular domestic coalitions is to be found.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1985

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Gerschenkron, Alexander, Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1962)Google Scholar; Moore, Barrington Jr, Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (Boston: Beacon, 1966)Google Scholar; and Cardoso, Fernando Henrique and Faletto, Enzo, Dependency and Development in Latin America (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1979)Google Scholar.

2. Balassa, Bela, The Newly Industrializing Countries in the World Economy (Elmsford, N. Y.: Pergamon, 1981)Google Scholar, essay 1.

3. For a discussion of ISI and its problems, see Little, Ian et al., Industry and Trade in Some Developing Countries (London: Oxford University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Baer, Werner, “Import Substitution and Industrialization in Latin America: Experiences and Interpretations,” Latin American Research Review 7 (Spring 1972), pp. 95122Google Scholar; Grunwald, Joseph, “Some Reflections on Latin American Industrial Policy,” Journal of Political Economy 78 (08 1970), pp. 826–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; the special issue of World Development 5, 1–2 (1977) devoted to Latin America in the post-ISI era; and Hirschman, Albert O., “The Political Economy of Import-Substituting Industrialization in Latin America,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 82 (02 1968), pp. 232CrossRefGoogle Scholar, which emphasizes the sociopolitical obstacles to the continued success of ISI.

4. Villarreal, René, “The Policy of Import-Substituting Industrialization, 1929–1975,” in Reyna, José Luis and Weinert, Richard S., eds., Authoritarianism in Mexico (Philadelphia: ISHI, 1977), pp. 67107Google Scholar, for Mexico; Baer, Werner, The Brazilian Economy, 2d ed. (New York: Praeger, 1983)Google Scholar, for Brazil. For Colombia see Balassa, Newly Industrializing Countries; Berry, Albert and Thoumi, Francisco, “Import Substitution and Beyond: Colombia,” World Development 5, 1–2 (1977), pp. 89109CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Morawetz, David, Why the Emperor's New Clothes Are Not Made in Colombia (New York: Oxford University Press, 1981)Google Scholar.

5. See, respectively, Bosworth, Barry P. and Lawrence, Robert Z., Commodity Prices and the New Inflation (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1982)Google Scholar; Mares, David R., “Agricultural Trade: Domestic Interests and Transnational Relations,” in Dominguez, Jorge I., ed., Mexico's Political Economy (Beverly Hills: Sage, 1982), pp. 79132Google Scholar, and Morawetz, The Emperor's New Clothes.

6. Cohen, Benjamin J., Banks and the Balance of Payments (Montclair, N.J.: Allanheld, Osmun, 1981)Google Scholar; Lipson, Charles, “The International Organization of Third World Debt,” International Organization 35 (Autumn 1981), pp. 603–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jeff Freiden, “Third World Indebted Industrialization: International Finance and State Capital in Mexico, Brazil, Algeria, and South Korea,” ibid. 35 (Summer 1981), pp. 407–31; and Balassa, , Newly Industrializing Countries, pp. 5253Google Scholar.

7. Little et al., Industry and Trade, Balassa, Newly Industrializing Countries; Cline, William R. and Weintraub, Sidney, eds., Economic Stabilization in Developing Countries (Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1981)Google Scholar; Thorp, Rosemary and Whitehead, Lawrence, eds., Inflation and Stabilization in Latin America (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1979)Google Scholar; Griffin, Keith, The Political Economy of Agrarian Change (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1974)Google Scholar.

8. This is perhaps best explained by the domination of two models in the analysis of Latin American political economies, bureaucratic-authoritarianism and dependency. Initially, they provided very important critiques of modernization theorists and “developmentalists.” But their alternative explanatory power waned as evidence surfaced to dispute the models’ economic underpinnings. On bureaucratic-authoritarianism see Collier, David, ed., The New Authoritarianism in Latin America (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1979)Google Scholar; on dependency see Moran, Theodore H., Multinational Corporations and the Politics of Dependence (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1974)Google Scholar.

9. Allende faced internal problems, of course, but the U.S. economic boycott and covert activity were fundamental to his overthrow.

10. Gourevitch, Peter A., “The Second Image Reversed: International Sources of Domestic Politics,” International Organization 32 (Autumn 1978), pp. 881912CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11. On the threat of nontariff barriers and neoprotectionism see Baer, “Import Substitution,” and Villarreal, René, “Proteccionismo industrial, fomento a las exportaciones y el nuevo GATT de los 80's,” Economista Mexicano 14 (0102 1980), pp. 3246Google Scholar; for criticisms of the IMF strategy, see Villarreal, , La Contrarrevolucion Monetarista (Mexico, D.F.: Oceano, 1983)Google Scholar; Payer, Cheryl, The Debt Trap (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1974)Google Scholar.

12. Balassa, Bela, “The Newly Industrializing Countries after the Oil Crisis,” in Belassa, , Newly Industrializing Countries, pp. 2981Google Scholar.

13. Murray, Tracy, Trade Preferences for Developing Countries (New York: Wiley, 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; the author points out, however, that the GSP has not done enough for the majority of developing countries.

14. Mikesell, Raymond R., “Appraising IMF Conditionally: Too Loose, Too Tight, or Just Right?” in Williamson, John, ed., IMF Conditionalily (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983), pp. 4849Google Scholar.

15. Balassa, , Newly Industrializing Countries, essay 2, pp. 5253Google Scholar.

16. Gourevitch, Peter A., “International Trade, Domestic Coalitions and Liberty: Comparative Responses to the Crisis of 1873–1896,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 8 (Autumn 1977), pp. 281313CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Breaking with Orthodoxy: The Politics of Economic Policy Responses to the Depression of the 1930s,” International Organization 38 (Winter 1983), pp. 95129Google Scholar.

17. Gourevitch, , “Breaking with Orthodoxy,” pp. 9799Google Scholar.

18. Krasner, Stephen D., Defending the National Interest (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978)Google Scholar.

19. Cf. Zysman, John, Governments, Markets and Growth (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983)Google Scholar; Schmitter, Philippe C., “Still the Century of Corporatism?Review of Politics 36 (01 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stepan, Alfred, The State and Society: Peru in Comparative Perspective (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1978)Google Scholar.

20. Katzenstein, Peter J., ed., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978)Google Scholar; see especially his concluding essay.

21. See the collection of essays in Malloy, James, ed., Authoritarianism and Corporatism in Latin America (Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 1977)Google Scholar.

22. See, respectively, Krasner, , Defending the National Interest; John S. Odell, U.S. International Monetary Policy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1983)Google Scholar, and Krasner, Stephen D., “U.S. Commercial and Monetary Policy: Unravelling the Paradox of External Strength and Internal Weakness,” in Katzenstein, , Between Power and Plenty, pp. 5187Google Scholar; and Hirschman, Albert O., “The Turn to Authoritarianism in Latin America and the Search for Its Economic Determinants,” in Collier, , Bureaucratic Authoritarianism, pp. 6198Google Scholar.

23. Trade policy is an important component of development strategy. During the primary export stage its purpose was to stimulate the competitiveness of national products in the international market. With the turn to ISI its task changed to protecting the domestic market. In the diversified export strategy the task of trade policy becomes more complex, for it must now perform both external and internal functions. The external task is similar to the primary export stage, although more complicated because the export of industrial products is alsosought. Internally, its function is to make the domestic economy competitive internationally without destroying the productive plant created by ISI.

24. FitzGerald, E. V. K., “Stabilization Policy in Mexico,” in Thorp, and Whitehead, , Inflation and Stabilization, p. 51Google Scholar.

25. Weintraub, Sidney, “Case Study of Economic Stabilization: Mexico,” in Cline, and Weintraub, , Economic Stabilization, p. 286Google Scholar.

26. Whitehead, Lawrence, “Mexico from Bust to Boom: A Political Evaluation of the 1976–1979 Stabilization Programme,” World Development 8 (11 1980), pp. 843–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27. Cohen, , Banks and BOP, pp. 4347Google Scholar; Lipson, “International Organization of Third World Debt.”

28. Standard works on Mexico's political economy include Brandenberg, Frank, The Making of Modern Mexico (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1964)Google Scholar; Vemon, Raymond, The Dilemma of Mexico's Development (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1963)Google Scholar; Reynolds, Clark, The Mexican Economy (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Hansen, Roger D., The Politics of Mexican Development (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1971)Google Scholar; and Purcell, Susan Kaufman and Purcell, John F. H., “State and Society: Must a Stable Polity Be Institutionalized?World Politics 32 (01 1980)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

29. Almond, Gabriel A. and Verba, Sidney, The Civic Culture (Boston: Little, Brown, 1965)Google Scholar.

30. Hirschman, , “Turn to Authoritarianism in Latin America,” 6568Google Scholar, makes a similar argument.

31. See Dominguez, Jorge I., “Introduction,” in Dominguez, , Mexico's Political Economy, pp. 1011Google Scholar; and Purcell and Purcell, “State and Society.”

32. For a similar argument about the United States, see Skocpol, Theda, “Political Response to Capitalist Crisis: Neo-Marxist Theories of the State and the Case of the New DealPolitics and Society 10, 2 (1980), pp. 155201CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33. Douglas Bennett and Kenneth Sharpe draw upon Gershenkron, Economic Backwardness, and Hirschman, “Political Economy of ISI,” in “The State as Banker and Entrepreneur: The Last Resort Character of the Mexican State's Economic Intervention, 1917–1970,” in Sylvia Hewlett, A. and Weinert, Richard, eds., Brazil and Mexico (Philadelphia: ISHI, 1982)Google Scholar.

34. On Stabilizing Development see Villarreal, René, El desequilibho externo en la industrialización de México (1929–1975) (Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economics, 1976)Google Scholar; Solís, Leopoldo, Economic Policy Reform in Mexico (Elmsford, N.Y.: Pergamon, 1981)Google Scholar; Tello, Carlos, La politico econdmica en México, 1970–1976 (Mexico: Siglo XXI, 1979)Google Scholar; FitzGerald, “Stabilization Policy”; Weintraub, “Case Study”; and Whitehead, “Mexico from Bust to Boom.”

35. Villarreal, , El desequilibrio, p. 72Google Scholar.

36. The bias against agriculture tends to accompany all ISI strategies; cf. Johnston, Bruce F. and Clark, William C., Redesigning Rural Development (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1982), pp.70115Google Scholar.

37. Villarreal, , El desequilibrio, p. 110Google Scholar.

38. Anderson, Bo and Cockcroft, James D., “Control and Cooptation in Mexican Politics,” in Cockcroft, James D., Frank, Andre Gunder, and Johnson, Dale L., Dependence and Underdevelopment (Garden City, N.Y.: Anchor, 1972), pp. 219–44Google Scholar.

39. Solís, , who was director of planning at the time, Economic Policy Reform, pp. 4143, 57–62Google Scholar; see also Villarreal, , El desequilibrio, p. 19Google Scholar.

40. The phrase is from Gourevitch, , “Breaking with Orthodoxy,” p. 98Google Scholar.

41. I thank Elan Bisberg for bringing this threat to my attention; the politics of the Echeverria period is analyzed at length in Mares, David R., “Agriculture and Dependent Development: Politics in an Evolving Enclave Economy” (Ph.D. diss., Harvard University, 1982)Google Scholar.

42. Ibid., chap. 4; Sanderson, Steven, Agrarian Populism and the Mexican State (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981)Google Scholar.

43. FitzGerald, , “Stabilization Policy,” p. 42Google Scholar.

44. Financial authorities did fear capital flight if there was a devaluation in 1982. But there were other reasons as well for allowing a progressive overvaluation to occur. Increased inflation would follow a devaluation, at least in the short run. In addition, after two decades of exchangerate stability devaluation would be seen as a policy failure rather than policy tool. Finally, many of Mexico's exports would not respond to currency depreciation because they were denominated in dollars (e.g., minerals, coffee, petroleum).

45. Villarreal, , El desequilibrio, pp. 195–97Google Scholar.

46. Cornelius, Wayne A., “The Political Economy of Mexico under De la Madrid: Austerity, Routinized Crisis, and Nascent Recovery,” Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos (Winter 1985), p. 89Google Scholar.

47. Weintraub, , “Case Study,” p. 19Google Scholar.

48. It is often assumed that an export emphasis requires wage repression. Although repression may initially be the case, export success can expand the economic pie, allowing wages to rise. Morawetz, , The Emperor's New Clothes, shows that wages in the Colombian textile industry were lower than in the East Asian (pp. 8285)Google Scholar. And if our concern is with the quality of life, family income in Brazil in the late 1960s rose as more jobs became available because of the success of export policies.

49. Story, Dale, “Trade Politics in the Third World: A Case Study of the Mexican GATT Decision,” International Organization 36 (Autumn 1982), pp. 770–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50. Yoffie, David B., Power and Protectionism (New York: Columbia University Press, 1983)Google Scholar, illustrates quite clearly that these strategies are fundamental to East Asia's export success, which does not depend on surrender to some market-determined price.

51. Story, “Trade Politics in Third World.”

52. Hacienda, Secretaría de y Crédito Público y Secretaría de Programación y Presupuesto, “La politica económica a corto y mediano plazo,” Comercio Exterior, 01 1978, p. 101Google Scholar.

53. Cf. Little, et al., Industry and Trade, pp. 362–74Google Scholar. Statistics from World Bank, Mexico: Manufacturing Sector (Washington, D.C., 1979), p. 1Google Scholar.

54. Hempel, Gretchen, “Mexico: Profile,” draft (U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, 03 1981)Google Scholar, see. 4, p. 40; Comercio Exterior, January 1979, p. 31. Under the official value system the government established official prices for an article if there was reason to believe that the declared invoice value was low; ad valorem duties would then be collected on the basis of the new price. The administrative character of the system permitted its use as a nontariff barrier.

55. Comercio Exterior, April 1979, p. 398; September 1980, p. 949; and May 1980, p. 445.

56. Ibid., May 1980, p. 445.

57. SPP, 10 Anōos de indicadores económicos y sociales de México (Mexico, D.F., 1982), p. 184Google Scholar, Table VI.70.

58. The chief organ of the industrial protectionists did not take an opposing stance on the opening of the economy until the very end of the GATT debate in 1980.

59. “El Bancomext durante 1977. Resumen,” Comercio Exterior, April 1978, pp. 392, 399.

60. Quintero, Francisco Alcalá, “El financiamiento al comercio exterior de México,” Comercio Exterior, 09 1978, pp. 1048–49Google Scholar.

61. “Recuento nacional,” Comercio Exterior, September 1980, p. 949.

62. “El sector externo de Mexico en 1978 y sus perspectivas,” Comercio Exterior, March 1979, pp. 268–70; “Los objectivos del Plan Industrial,” May 1979, pp. 521–28. For a critique of these plans see Gerardo Bueno, “Petroleo y planes de desarrollo en Mexico,” ibid., August 1981, pp. 831–40.

63. Cf. Ford, Charles A. and Morlock, Alejandro A. Violante, “Policy Concerns over the Impact of Trade-Related Mexican Automotive Policy and U.S.-Mexican Relations,” Inter-American Economic Affairs 36 (Autumn 1982), pp. 342Google Scholar; see also Bennett, Douglas C. and Sharpe, Kenneth E., “Agenda Setting and Bargaining Power: The Mexican State versus Transnational Automobile Corporations,” World Politics 32 (10 1979), pp. 5789CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

64. Agreement: On Trade Matters between the United States of America and the United Mexican Stater, I am grateful to Gustavo del Castillo for providing me with a copy of the text.

65. Fagen, Richard R. and Nau, Henry R., “Mexican Gas: The Northern Connection,” in Fagen, , ed., Capitalism and the State in U.S.-Latin American Relations (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1979), pp. 382427Google Scholar.

66. Freiden, “Third World Indebted Industrialization”; Cohen, Banks and the BOP.

67. Cf. Villarreal, , “Proteccionismo industrial,” pp. 3246Google Scholar.

68. Confidential interviews, 1983 in the Foreign Ministry and 1985 with an ex-Cabinet member, Story maintains that the president in fact favored joining GATT when the debate began. My point is that he favored it in January, but by November circumstances seemed to allow him to avoid this external constraint on his and future presidents’ behavior.

69. There were two major justifications given for the SAM program of self-sufficiency. There were indications that this trade could be very expensive for Mexico: the industrial plan projected that if the current trend continued to 1990, 54% of petroleum revenues would have to be used for imports of basic foodstuffs, thereby leaving little to finance other projects in the economy. In addition, there was fear that supplies from the international market would be unavailable either for domestic political reasons (U.S. president Nixon embargoed the export of soybeans in the fight against inflation during 1973) or for foreign-policy concerns (the United States has historically attempted to use food aid as a tool of foreign policy).

70. Comercio Exterior, March 1981, p. 261.

71. Petroleum Intelligence Weekly, 6 July 1981, p. 4. The initial Mexican response was to fill its contracts with a greater mixture of heavier Maya crude (a 70–30 mix, up from 60–40) despite the protests of buyers. Ibid., 2 March 1981, pp. 11–12, and 23 March 1981, pp. 5–6.

72. “Recuento nacional,” Comercio Exterior, June 1981, pp. 613–14; August 1981, pp. 858–59; and September 1981, p. 984.

73. Ibid., August 1981, p. 861.

74. Ibid., June 1981, p. 615.

75. “La evolution reciente y las perspectivas de la economia mexicana,” Economia Mexicana 3:1981, p. 11.

76. Comercio Exterior, February 1978, p. 243; February 1979, p. 254; May 1980, p. 444; March 1981, p. 355; and April 1982, p. 475.

77. “La evolution…,” Economia Mexicana 3:1981, p. 11.

78. “Recuento national,” Comercio Exterior, October 1980, p. 1081; August 1981, p. 861; September 1981, p. 983; October 1981, pp. 1114–15; and November 1981, p. 1247.

79. In 1981 the Mexican WPI rose 24.5% while the U.S. PFP increased 9.2%. The Mexican Wholesale Price Index is from SPP, lO Anōos the U.S. Producer Finished Prices, not seasonally adjusted, are from the Federal Reserve Bulletin, April 1982, no. 68 Table 2.10, p. A46.

80. Green, Rosario, “México: crisis financiera y deuda externa,” Comercio Exterior, 02 1983, p. 105Google Scholar.

81. SPP, , “Exposici6n de motivos de la Iniciativa de Decreto del presupuesto de Egresos de la Federación para el anò de 1982 (fragmentos),” Comercio Exterior, 02 1982, pp. 191–97Google Scholar.

82. Solís, Economic Policy Reform.

83. This is one of the chief failings of a recent attempt to examine the importance of domestic politics in Mexican foreign economic policy. Story, “Trade Politics in Third World,” uses Mexico's rejection of GATT membership to argue the importance of bureaucratic and interestgroup politics. A closer look at trade policy and not just the GATT decision, which was only one part of it, albeit an important one, demonstrates the probems of transferring a model derived from a pluralist political system to one characterized by an authoritarian-corporatist structure. If the national debate on the GATT was to be the key element in the president's decision, it would have marked the first time in Mexico's history that policy was determined by the uncontrolled articulation of societal interests. In the general area of trade policy one could also ask, if protectionist and nationalist forces were so strong, why was significant rationalization/liberalization possible in 1977–1979? With respect to the GATT case itself, despite detailed investigation of the positions of various social and bureaucratic forces, Story is never able to demonstrate their impact on the actual decision. (The vote in the Cabinet is insufficient. The 5–3 vote was negative only because the president had replaced a liberal foreign minister with a nationalist one. Also, Cabinet votes have rarely determined major decisions; if a vote had been taken, the banks would probably not have been nationalized in 1982.) In fact, Story's evidence that López Portillo favored GATT entry in November 1979 is weak. He assumes on the basis of facial expressions and cryptic remarks that Lopez Portillo's previously favorable stance did not change.

84. This is the argument of Little et al., Industry and Trade, for the advanced Third World countries they studied.

85. Soíls, , Economic Policy Reform, p. 29Google Scholar.