Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T12:36:35.417Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Clogs to Clogs in Three Generations? Explaining Entrepreneurial Performance in Britain Since 1850

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Tom Nicholas
Affiliation:
British Academy Postdoctoral Fellow, Economic History Department, London School of Economics, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE. E-mail: t.nicholas@lse.ac.uk.

Abstract

Research into sculture and entrepreneurship in Britain has been dominated by casual empiricism. This article shows the benefits of using a new method. Lifetime wealth accumulation is specified as a measure of entrepreneurial performance, and applied to data collected from dictionaries of business biography. Industry, region, and religious dissent are ruled out as explanations of entrepreneurial performance. Education and entrepreneurial type are the important predictors. Firm inheritors and those receiving a high-status education experienced relatively low lifetime rates of wealth accumulation. Firm founders, managers, and individuals with a lower-status education were comparatively successful.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1999

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Referenses

Aldcroft, D.The Entrepreneur and the British Economy 1870–1914.” Economic History Review 17, no. 1 (1964): 113–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashton, T. S.The Industrial Revolution 1760–1830. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1968.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A. B.The Economics of Inequality. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Banmol, W. J.Entrepreneurship, Management and the Structure of Payoffs. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Berghoff, H. “Public Schools and the Decline of the British Economy.” Past & Present, no. 129 (1990): 148–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berghoff, H.British Businessmen as Wealth Holders, 1870–1914: A Closer Look.” Business History 33, no. 2 (1991): 222–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berghoff, H., and Möller, R.. “Tired Pioneers and Dynamic Newcomers? A Comparative Essay on English and German Entrepreneurial History, 1870–1914.” Economic History Review 47, no. 2 (1994): 262–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchflower, D. G. and Oswald, A. J.. “Entrepreneurship, Happiness and Supernormal Returns: Evidence from Britain and the US.” Centre for Economic Performance Discussion paper No. 134, 1993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchflower, D. G. and Oswald, A. J.. “What Makes an Entrepreneur?Journal of Labour Economics 16, no. 1 (1998): 2660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadberry, S. N.How did the United States and Germany Overtake Britain? A Sectoral Analysis of Comparative Productivity Levels 1870–1990.” this JOURNAL 58, no. 2 (1998): 375407.Google Scholar
Cassis, Y.Big Business. The European Experience in the Twentieth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
Casson, M.The Entrepreneur: An Economic Theory. Oxford: Martin Robertson, 1991.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D.Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, D. C.Gentlemen and Players.” Economic Histoiy Review 26, no. 1 (1973): 92116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, B., and Robbins, K., eds. British Culture and Economic Decline. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1990.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. F. R.Forging Ahead and Falling Behind: The Rise and Relative Decline of the First Industrial Nation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 12, no. 2 (1998): 193210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagen, E. E.On the Theory of Social Change. London: Tavistock, 1964.Google Scholar
Hall, R. E.Stochastic Implications of the Life Cycle Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Political Economy 86, no. 6 (1978): 971–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. E., and Mishkin, F. S.. “The Sensitivity of Consumption to Transitory Income: Estimates from Panel Data on Households.” Econometrica 50, no. 2 (1982): 461–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Halvorsen, R., and Palmquist, R.. “Interpretation of Dummy Variables in Semi-Logarithmic Equations.” American Economic Review 70, no. 3 (1980): 474–75.Google Scholar
Harbury, C. D., and Hitchens, D. M. W. N.. Inheritance and Wealth inequality in Britain. London: Allen and Unwin, 1979.Google Scholar
Harbury, C. D., and McMahon, P. C.. “Inheritance and the Characteristics of Top Wealth Leavers in Britain.” Economic Journal 83, no. 331 (1973): 810–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
HMSO, The Taxes Acts. London: HMSO, 1982.Google Scholar
Horsman, E. G.The Avoidance of Estate Duty by Gifts Inter Vivos: Some Quantitative Evidence.” Economic Journal 83, no. 339 (1975): 516–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howe, A. C.Cotton Masters 1830–1860. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Jeremy, D. J. “Important Questions About Business and Religion in Modem Britain.” In Business and Religion in Britain, edited by Jeremy, D. J., 126. Aldershot: Gower, 1988.Google Scholar
Jeremy, D. J.Capitalists and Christians: Business Leaders andthe Churches in Britain, 1900–1960. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jeremy, D. J., and Shaw, C., eds. The Dictionary of Business Biography. 5 vols. London: Butterworths, 19841986.Google Scholar
Jeremy, D. J., and Tweedale, G.. Dictionary of Twentieth Century British Business Leaders. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P.Economic Growth in France and Britain, 1851–1950. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirby, M. “Quakerism, Entrepreneurship and the Family Firm in North-East England.” In Entrepreneurship, Networks and Modern Business, edited by Brown, J. B. and Rose, M. B., 105–26. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Knight, F. H.Risk Uncertainty and Profit. Boston: Houghton Muffin, 1923.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, L. J.Intergenerational Transfers and Savings.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, no. 2 (1988): 4158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, D. S.The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Lawday, D. J., and Mann, E. J.. Green's Death Duties. London: Butterworth, 1971.Google Scholar
Marshall, A.Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan, 1890.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N.Did Victorian Britain Fail?Economic History Review 23, no. 3 (1970): 446–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, D. N., and Sandberg, L.. “From Damnation to Redemption: Judgements on the Late Victorian Entipreneur.” Explorations in Economic History 9, no. 1 (1971): 89108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, J. G.The Machinery of Succession. Abingdon: Professional Books, 1977.Google Scholar
Mitchell, B. R.British Historical Statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Modigliani, F.The Role of Intergenerational Transfers and Life Cycle Saving in the Accumulation of Wealth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, no. 2 (1988): 1540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, D. C.Profits in the Long Run. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicholas, T.Wealth Making in Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Century Britain: Industry v. Commerce and Finance.” Business History 41, no. 1 (1999): 1636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Payne, P. L.British Entrepreneurship in the Nineteenth Century. London: Macmillan, 1974.Google Scholar
Perkin, H. J.Elites in British Society Since 1880 [computer file]. Coichester, Essex: The Data Archive [distributor] (1979). SN: 1157.Google Scholar
Roper, M.Masculinity and the British Organisarion Man Since 1945. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, M. B. “Beyond Buddenbrooks: The Family Firm and the Management of Succession in Nineteenth Century Britain.” In Entrepreneurship, Networks and Modern Business, edited by Brown, J. B. and Rose, M. B., 127143. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, W. D.The Victorian Middle Class: Wealth, Occupation and Geography.” Economic History Review 30, no. 4 (1977): 602–23.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, W. D.Men of Property: The Very Wealthy in Britain Since the Industrial Revolution. London: Croom Helm, 1981.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, W. D.Capitalism, Culture and Decline in Britain 1750–1990. London: Routledge, 1994.Google Scholar
Runkle, D. E.Liquidity Constraints and the Permanent Income Hypothesis: Evidence From Panel Data.” Journal of Monetary Economics 27, no. 1 (1991): 7398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J.The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle. New York: Oxford University Press, 1961.Google Scholar
Ward, D.The Public Schools and Industry in Britain After 1870.” Journal of Contemporary History 2, no. 3 (1967): 3752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, P.Did Britain Change? An Inquiry into the Causes of National Decline.” Journal of Contemporary History 20, no. 1 (1985): 99133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whalley, J.The Avoidance of Estate Duty by Gifts Inter Vivos: Some Quantitative Evidence.” Economic Journal 85, no. 339 (1975): 516–30.Google Scholar
Wiener, M.English Culture and the Decline of the Industrial Spirit 1850–1990. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Zelder, S. P.Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Political Economy 97, no. 2 (1989): 305–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar