Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T06:41:10.015Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Politics, Popery, and Property: A Comment on North and Weingast

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Bruce G. Carruthers
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor of Sociology, Northwestern University, 1810 Chicago Avenue, Evanston, IL 60208.

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Notes and Discussion
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1990

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 North, Douglass C. and Weingast, Barry R., “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolutionof Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” this JOURNAL, 49 (12 1989), pp. 803–32.Google Scholar

2 Ibid., p. 803.

3 Ibid., p. 819.

4 Ibid., pp. 809–12.

5 Ibid., pp. 816, 829.

6 See Shaw, W. A., ed., Calender of Treasury Books (London, 1908), vol. 3, p. xlviii.Google Scholar

7 The connection of the Stop with the Third Dutch War is consistent with North and Weingast's point that wars raise the discount rate of rulers and make repudiations of sovereign debt more likely.Google Scholar

8 Horsefield, J. Keith, “The ‘Stop of the Exchequer’ Revisited,” Economic History Review, 35 (11 1982), p. 514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 The terms of the letters patent allowed the goldsmith-bankers the option of assigning a portion of the interest payments they received directly to their own creditors, most of whom were former depositors.Google Scholar

10 Horsefield, “The ‘Stop of the Exchequer,’” p. 517.Google Scholar

11 Clay, C. G. A., Economic Expansion and Social Change: England 1500–1700 (Cambridge, 1984), vol. 2, p. 277.Google Scholar

12 Holdsworth, Sir William, A History of English Law (3rd edn., London, 1944), vol. 9, pp. 815, 22–23.Google Scholar

13 The Court of Exchequer had jurisdiction over cases involving Crown revenue. A monstrans de droit was a fourteenth-century offshoot of the petition of right. For some situations it provided an alternative remedy against the Crown. See Holdsworth, A History, p. 25.Google Scholar

14 Ibid., p. 33.

15 Sachse, William L., Lord Somers: A Political Portrait (Manchester, 1975), p. 75.Google Scholar

16 Horsefield, “The ‘Stop of the xchequer,’” pp. 519–20.Google Scholar

17 See the Historical Manuscripts Commission, Manuscripts of the House of Lords, new series (London, 1905), vol. 3, pp. 407–9.Google Scholar

18 North and Weingast, “Constitutions and ommitment,” p. 820.Google Scholar

19 Burton, I. F., Riley, P. W. J., and Rowlands, E., Political Parties in the Reigns of William III and Anne (Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research. Special Supplement No. 7, London, 1968), pp. 13Google Scholar; Johnson, Richard R., “Politics Redefined: An Assessment of Recent Writings on the Late Stuart Period of English History, 1660 to 1714,” William and Mary Quarterly, 35 (10 1978), pp. 705–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Jones, J. R., The First Whigs: The Politics of the Exclusion Crisis, 1678–1683 (London, 1961), pp. 2, 4, 214.Google Scholar

21 Speck, W. A., Reluctant Revolutionaries: Englishmen and the Revolution of 1688 (Oxford, 1988), pp. 66, 128.Google Scholar

22 Horwitz, Henry, Parliament, Policy and Politics in the Reign of William III (Newark, 1977), pp. 217, 316–17.Google Scholar

23 Holmes, Geoffrey, British Politics in the Age ofAnne (London, 1967), p. 63Google Scholar; Speck, W. A., Tory and Whig: The Struggle in the Constituencies, 1701–1715 (London, 1970), pp. 1, 22.Google Scholar

24 Horwitz, Parliament, Policy and Politics, pp. 130–31;Google ScholarRubini, Dennis, “Politics and the battle for the Banks, 1688–1697,” English Historical Review, 337 (10 1970), p. 694.Google Scholar

25 Holmes, Geoffrey, British Politics, p. 27;Google ScholarHill, B. W., The Growth of Parliamentary Parties, 1689–1742 (Hamden, 1976), p. 69.Google Scholar

26 SirClapham, John, The Bank of England (Cambridge, 1945), vol. 1, pp. 7475Google Scholar; Hill, B. W., “The Change of Government and the ‘Loss of the City,’ 1710–1711,” Economic History Review, 24 (08 1971), p. 395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

27 Dickson, P. G. M., The Financial Revolution in England (London, 1967), p. 65.Google Scholar

28 Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783 (New York, 1989), p. 120Google Scholar; Sperling, John G., The South Sea Company (Boston, 1962), pp. 7, 14.Google Scholar

295 Horwitz, Henry, “The East India Trade, The Politicians, and the Constitution; 1689–1702,” Journal of British Studies, 17 (Spring 1978), p. 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

30 Ibid., pp. 10–11.

31 Horwitz, Henry, Parliament, Policy and Politics, pp. 232–33;Google ScholarJones, D. W., War and Economy in the Age of William 111 and Marlborough (Oxford, 1988), pp. 221, 301.Google Scholar

32 North and Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitment,” p. 804.Google Scholar

33 Miller, John, Popery and Politics in England, 1660–1688 (Cambridge, 1973), pp. 197, 202, 250;CrossRefGoogle ScholarSpeck, Reluctant Revolutionaries, p. 128.Google Scholar

34 Speck, Reluctant Revolutionaries, pp. 233, 235.Google Scholar

35 Giuseppi, J. A., “Sephardi Jews and the early years of The Bank of EnglandTransactions ofthe jewisjh Historical Society of England, 19, (19551959), pp. 5354Google Scholar; Carter, A. C., “The Huguenot Contribution to the Early Years of the Funded Debt, 1694–1714Proceedings of the Huguenot society of London, 19 (1955), p. 22.Google Scholar

36 Lee, Maurice Jr, The Cabal (Urbana, 1965), p. 159.Google Scholar

37 North and Weingast, “Constitutions and Commitments,” p. 805.Google Scholar