Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T02:40:04.189Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Production Relations, Labor Productivity, and Choice of Technique: British and U.S. Cotton Spinning

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

William H. Lazonick
Affiliation:
Department of Economics at Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts, 02138.

Extract

The role of capital-labor relations in the transformation of inputs into output is central to the Marxian theory of capitalist development but is neglected by neoclassical theory. By comparing the development of cotton spinning in Britain and the U.S. in the last half of the nineteenth century, this paper analyzes the ways in which capital-labor relations affected the level and structure of wages, labor productivity, and choice of technique. This case study demonstrates the descriptive and predictive limitations of the neoclassical theory of choice of technique while at the same time pointing the way towards the development of a more incisive, and historically relevant, theory.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1981

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

He wishes to thank Stephen Marglin, who offered considerable advice that helped to improve the analysis presented here. The author also benefited from discussions with Thomas Brush, Robert McCauley, and William Mass as well as from a number of suggestions made by participants at the Cliometrics Conference, University of Chicago, May 1980. The comments of an anonymous referee were extremely useful in compelling the author to clarify his arguments. Thomas Brush provided research assistance. This paper is based upon research supported by the National Science Foundation under Grant No. SES 78–25671 and by a grant-in-aid from the Merrimack Valley Textile Museum. A related paper was presented at the Annual Meeting of the Economic History Association, September 1980 in Boston and was published in this JOURNAL in March 1981.Google Scholar

1 Clark, J[ohn] B., The Distribution of Wealth (New York, 1899), pp. 1920. More recently, Paul Samuelson has remarked: “Remember that in a perfectly competitive market it really doesn't matter who hires whom; so have labor hire ‘capital’.…”Google ScholarSamuelson, Paul A., “Wages and Interest: A Modern Dissection of Marxian Economic Models,” American Economic Review, 47 (12 1957), 884912. For a seminal critique of the neoclassical theory of production,Google Scholarsee Marglin, Stephen A., “What Do Bosses Do?: The Origin and Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 6 (Summer 1974).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Arrow, Kenneth J., “The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing,” Review of Economic Studies, 29 (06 1962), 155–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 For a more general critique of the neoclassical conception of managerial activity, see Lazonick, William H., “Factor Costs and the Diffusion of Ring Spinning in Britain prior to World War I,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 96 (02 1981), 89109;CrossRefGoogle Scholaridem., “Competition, Specialization, and Industrial Decline,” this JOURNAL, 41 (March 1981), 31–38.

4 See Lazonick, William H., “Industrial Relations and Technical Change: The Case of the Self-Acting Mule,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 3 (09 1979), 236–37.Google Scholar

5 Ibid., pp. 238–45.

6 Chadwick, David, “On the Rate of Wages in Manchester and Salford, and the Manufacturing Districts of Lancashire 1839–1859,” Journal of the Statistical Society of London (1860), pp. 23–29;Google ScholarWood, G[eorge] H., The History of Wages in the Cotton Trade during the Past Hundred Years (London, 1910);Google ScholarHobsbawm, E[ric] J., Labouring Men (London, 1964), ch. 15.Google Scholar

7 Turner, H[erbert] A., Trade Union Growth, Structure and Policy (Toronto, 1962), pp. 137–38;Google ScholarWebb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, Industrial Democracy(London, 1919), p. 475;Google ScholarGreat Britain, Board of Trade (Labour Department), Trade Unions Report, 1905–1907 (London, 1919), p. xlv;Google ScholarTippett, L. H. C., A Portrait of the Lancashire Textile Industry (London, 1969), p. 105.Google Scholar

8 Ashworth, Henry, The Preston Strike (Manchester, 1854);Google ScholarCommittee on Trades' Societies, “Report,” and Lowe, J., “An Account of the Strike in the Cotton Trade at Preston in 1853,” both in National Association for the Promotion of Social Science, Trades' Societies and Strikes (London, 1860);Google ScholarFawcett, Henry, “Strikes: Their Tendencies and Remedies,” Westminster Review (July 1860);Google ScholarBritish Association for the Advancement of Science, On the Regulation of Wages by Means of Lists in the Cotton Industry (Manchester, 1887), pp. 1112;Google ScholarCotton Factory Times (henceforth CFT), 4 May 1888, 26 October 1894.Google Scholar

9 British Association, Regulation of Wages; Wood, History of Wages, pp. 1–2;Google ScholarWiggins, W. M., “The Cotton Industry,” in Gannett, Frank E. and Catherwood, B. F., eds., Industrial and Labour Relations in Great Britain (London, 1939);Google ScholarJewkes, John and Gray, E. M., Wages and Labour in the Lancashire Cotton Spinning Industry (Manchester, 1935), chs. 4–7;Google ScholarTippett, Portrait, p. 102.Google Scholar

10 Porter, J. H., “Industrial Peace in the Cotton Trade 1875–1913,” Yorkshire Bulletin of Economic and Social Research, 19 (05 1967), 50.Google Scholar

11 British Association, Regulation of Wages, p. 197ff;Google ScholarOldham Master Cotton Spinners' Association, Yearbook (Oldham, 1910);Google ScholarWood, History of Wages, pp. 52–55;Google ScholarWinterbottom, James, “A Criticism of the Oldham and Bolton Lists of Earnings for Mule Spinning,” Journal of the British Association of Managers of Textile Works, vol. 6 (19141915).Google Scholar

12 Porter, “Industrial Peace,” pp. 49–55.Google Scholar

13 Smith, Roland, “A History of the Lancashire Cotton Industry between the Years 1873 and 1896” (Ph.D. diss., University of Birmingham, 1954), pp. 276318, 506–09;Google ScholarMacara, Charles, The New Industrial Era (Manchester, 1923), p. 322;Google ScholarWiggins, “Cotton Industry,” pp. 230–32; Porter, “Industrial Peace,” pp. 52–57.Google Scholar

14 Hobsbawm, Labouring Men, ch. 15.Google Scholar

15 Thorpe, Ellis, “Industrial Relations and the Social Structure: A Case Study of Bolton Cotton Mule-Spinners, 1884–1910” (M.Sc. thesis, University of Salford, 1969);Google ScholarTextile Mercury, 26 April 1890; CFT, 20 July 1894, 19 August 1894, 7 May 1897. For an extensive account of the unsuccessful attempts by Lancashire capitalists and piecers to undermine the minder-piecer system, see Lazonick, “Industrial Relations,” pp. 246–51.Google Scholar

16 See e.g. CFT, 16 March 1888.Google Scholar

17 Silvia, Philip T. Jr “ The Position of Workers in a Textile Community: Fall River in the Early 1880s,” Labor History, 16 (Spring, 1975), 230–48.Google Scholar

18 Farnie, D[ouglas] A., The English Cotton Industry and the World Market 1815–1896 (Oxford, 1979), ch. 7;Google ScholarLintner, Sylvia, “A Social History of Fall River, 1859–1879” (Ph.D. diss., Radcliffe College, 1945), pp. 2628;Google ScholarEarl, H., comp., Fall River and Its Manufactories, 14th ed. (Fall River, 1894), pp. 3650.Google Scholar

19 Lamb, Robert K., “The Development of Entrepreneurship in Fall River: 1813–1859” (Ph.D. diss., Harvard University, 1935), ch. 12, pp. 68; Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics of Labor (henceforth Mass. BSL),Google ScholarEleventh Annual Report (Boston, 1880), pp. 69;Google ScholarHoward, Robert, “Progress in the Textile Trades”, in McNeil, George, ed., The Labor Movement: The Problem of Today (Milwaukee, 1891), p. 215.Google Scholar

20 Peck, F. and Earl, H., Fall River and Its Industries (Fall River, 1877), p. 8;Google ScholarLintner, “Social History”, pp. 14–16; 564; Mass. BSL, 11th Report, pp. 57–62; Mass. BSL, Thirteenth Annual Report (Boston, 1882), p. 229ff; Howard, “Progress,” pp. 217–19.Google Scholar

21 Lintner, “Social History,” ch. 3; Silvia, Philip T. Jr “The Spindle City: Labor, Politics and Religion in Fall River, Massachusetts, 1870–1905” (Ph.D. diss., Fordham University, 1973), chs. 3–4;Google ScholarHoward, “Progress,” pp. 219–33; Mass. BSL, 11th Report, pp. 30, 36–42, 53–63; Mass. BSL, 13th Report, pp. 201–07.Google Scholar

22 Silvia, “Spindile City,” pp. 109–10.Google Scholar

23 Howard, “Progress,” pp. 233–34.Google Scholar

24 Silvia, “Spindle City,” ch. 6; Lintner, “Social History,” pp. 26–28.Google Scholar

25 Silvia, “Spindle City,” ch. 9.Google Scholar

26 Wade's Fibre and Fabric, 22 September 1888, p. 234, and 18 January 1889, p. 372.Google Scholar

27 Mosely Industrial Commission to the United States of America, October-December 1902, Reports of the Delegates (n.p., n.d.), p. 126.Google Scholar

28 See Pollard, Sidney, The Genesis of Modern Management (Harmondsworth, 1965), pp. 5166;Google ScholarHobsbawm, Labouring Men, pp. 297–300;Google ScholarButtrick, John, “The Inside Contract System,this JOURNAL, 7 (Summer 1952), 205–21;Google ScholarMontgomery, David, Workers' Control in America (New York, 1979), ch. 2.Google Scholar

29 See Chapman, S[idney] J., “Some Policies of the Cotton Spinners' Trade Unions,” Economic Journal, 10 (12 1900), 469;CrossRefGoogle ScholarTurner, Trade Union Growth, p. 128.Google Scholar

30 See Lazonick, “Industrial Relations,” pp. 242–46.Google Scholar

31 Ibid., pp. 236–46.

32 CFT, 1 May 1885, 12 Feb. 1886, 26 Feb. 1886, 3 March 1894, 21 Dec. 1894, 19 Nov. 1897;Google ScholarLomax, J. W., Fine Cotton Spinning (Manchester, 1913), p. 116.Google Scholar

33 CFT, 13 Feb. 1885;Google ScholarCatling, Harold, The Spinning Mule (Newton Abbott, 1970), p. 149.Google Scholar

34 See Lazonick, “Industrial Relations,” pp. 248–50; Chapman, “Some Policies.”Google Scholar

35 Taggart, William S., Cotton Mill Management: A Practical Guide for Managers, Carders and Over-lookers (London, 1923), pp. xix–xx.Google Scholar

36 CFT, 20 March 1885; Ministry of Labour and National Service, The Cotton Spinning Industry, Supplement: Mule-Spinners' Wages (London, 1946), p. 9.Google Scholar

37 Jewkes and Gray, Wages and Labour, p. 16; Hobsbawm, Labouring Men, pp. 286–87.Google Scholar

38 CFT, 13 March 1885, 3 April 1885, 20 Nov. 1885, 11 May 1888, 22 June 1888, 6 July 1888, 7 Dec. 1888, 22 May 1891, 7 Dec. 1894;Google ScholarTrade Union Problems,” Journal of the National Federation of Textile Works Managers Associations, 5 (19251926), pp. 3637.Google Scholar

39 See Taylor, Frederick W., Scientific Management (New York, 1947), pp. 7985;Google ScholarWhyte, William F., Money and Motivation (New York, 1955);Google ScholarBrown, Geoff, Sabotage (Nottingham, 1977), Parts II and III;Google ScholarMathewson, Stanley, Restriction of Output among Unorganized Workers (New York, 1931);Google ScholarStone, Katherine, “Origins of Job Structures in the Steel Industry,” Review of Radical Political Economics, 6 (Summer 1974);Google ScholarNelson, Daniel, Managers and Workers (Madison, 1975), pp. 4546;Google ScholarMontgomery, Workers' Control, ch. 1; U.S., Commissioner of Labor, Eleventh Annual Report, “Regulation and Restriction of Output” (Washington, 1904).Google Scholar

40 See e.g. CFT, 2 March 1894, 13 Nov. 1905.Google Scholar

41 CFT, 4 Dec. 1885; Smith, “Lancashire Cotton Industry,” pp. 392–93; Jewkes and Gray, Wages and Labour, p. 205.Google Scholar

42 See Lazonick, “Industrial Relations,” p. 253; Wood, History of Wages, p. 141;Google ScholarJones, G. T., Increasing Return (Cambridge, 1933), p. 277;Google ScholarAshton, T[homas] S., “The Growth of Textile Businesses in the Oldham District, 1884–1924,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 88 (1926), 573;Google ScholarLazonick, “Factor Costs,” pp. 92–104.Google Scholar

43 For an extensive analysis of the trends in cotton spinning productivity see Lazonick, William H. and Mass, William, “Productivity in the British Cotton Industry, 1870–1940,” photocopy (Harvard University, Sept. 1980).Google Scholar

44 Wood, History of Wages, pp. 53–54.Google Scholar

45 See e.g., CFT, 25 Dec. 1885, 23 Nov. 1888, 14 Dec. 1888, 4 Jan. 1889, 9 Jan. 1891, 1 Jan. 1897. See also Porter, “Industrial Peace”; Smith, “Lancashire Cotton Industry,” pp. 271ff, 394–95, 458–78;Google ScholarWhite, Joseph L., The Limits of Trade Union Militancy: The Lancashire Textile Workers, 1910–1914 (Westport, CT, 1978), pp. 212–15.Google Scholar

46 In 1889 the spinners' union observed: “Some few years ago we noticed that the great majority of our disputes were due to old machinery. Last year the majority were owing to bad work.” Amalgamated Association of Operative Cotton Spinners, Annual Report for Year Ending December 31, 1888 (Manchester, 1889), p. 14.Google Scholar

47 Porter, “Industrial Peace,” pp. 51, 53; Smith, “Lancashire Cotton Industry,” pp. 458–78; Wiggins, “Cotton Industry,” pp. 230–32; CFT, 22 Jan. 1897.Google Scholar

48 Porter, “Industrial Peace,” pp. 52–57;Google Scholarsee also Dyson, Roger F., “The Development of Collective Bargaining in the Cotton Spinning Industry 1893–1914” (Ph.D. diss., University of Leeds, 1971).Google Scholar

49 Smith, “Lancashire Cotton Industry,” p. 459; CFT, 15 Jan. 1889.Google Scholar

50 Mass. BSL, 11th Report, p. 7.Google Scholar

51 Lamb, “Entrepreneurship,” ch. 15, p. 52; Silvia, “Spindle City,” pp. 180, 270; Mass. BSL, 11th Report, p. 54; Mass. BSL, 13th Report, p. 304; U.S., Congress, Senate, Report of the Committee of the Senate Upon the Relation Between Labor and Capital, S. Rept. 1262, 48th Cong., 2d sess. 1885, vol. 1, p. 631, vol. 3, p. 74; Annawan Manufacturing Co., Payroll Book, 7 Jan. 1882, Manuscript Division, Baker Library, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar

52 CFT, 26 March 1886; Mosely, Reports, pp. 125–28;Google ScholarYoung, T. M., The American Cotton Industry (London, 1902), pp. 15, 44;Google ScholarUttley, T. W., Cotton Spinning and Manufacturing in the United States of America (Manchester, 1903), pp. 16, 32, 35, 38;Google ScholarBolton and District Managers and Overlookers' Association, Report of Delegates on American Tour (Bolton, 1920), pp. 7579.Google Scholar

53 Mosely, Reports, p. 126.Google Scholar

54 Amalgamated Association of Operative Cotton Spinners, Annual Report, 31 Dec. 1903.Google Scholar

55 I am grateful to lain Murton of Cambridge University for personal communication on the mobility of mule spinners and other related issues; Uttley, Cotton Spinning, p. 27; Young, American Cotton Industry, p. 12; Bolton and District Association, Report, p. 80.Google Scholar

56 Silvia, “Spindle City.” pp. 265–68; Lintner, “Social History,” pp. 62, 119, 139;Google ScholarGarraty, John A., ed., Labor and Capital in the Gilded Age (Boston, 1968), pp. 3336.Google Scholar

57 Fall River versus the Massachusetts Bureau of Statistics(Fall River, 1882), p. 8.Google Scholar

58 Textile Manufacturer, 15 July 1884; New England Cotton Manufacturers Association (henceforth NECMA), Transactions, 21 (1879), p. 40; CFT, 1 March 1886; Mosely, Reports, pp. 127–29; Uttley, Cotton Spinning, p. 13; Young, American Cotton Industry, p. 12;Google ScholarCopeland, Melvin T., The Cotton Manufacturing Industry of the United States (Cambridge, MA, 1912), p. 61;Google Scholarwinterbottom, James, Cotton Spinning, Calculations and Yarn Costs, 2nd ed., (London, 1921), p. 204.Google Scholar

59 See Mass, William, “The Adoption of the Automatic Loom,” photocopy (Harvard University, 04 1980); Lazonick and Mass, “Productivity,” pp. 2231.Google Scholar

60 See footnote 39 above for evidence on this restrictive behavior drawn from a number of industries. No detailed study of this phenomenon exists for Fall River mule spinning rooms. Thomas Brush has found ample evidence, however, of piece-rate cuts accompanying increases in productivity in an antebellum Lowell weave room along with the development of restrictive psychology on the part of the workers. See Brush, Thomas, “Lawrence Mill, #2, Upper Weave Room, 1834–1855: The Nature of the Labor Force and its Relation to Productivity,” photocopy (Harvard University, 04 1981).Google Scholar

61 Copeland, Cotton Manufacturing, p. 184; see also Silvia, “Spindle City”, p. 603.Google Scholar

62 Derived from data in Cramer, Stuart W., Useful Information for Cotton Manufacturers, 2nd ed. (Charlotte, NC, 1904);Google ScholarTaggart, Cotton Mill, pp. 202–03.Google Scholar

63 Based on average hourly earnings in 1891 and 1897, the wages of a Massachusetts mule spinner were 32 percent and 44 percent greater than those of an Oldham minder and 174 percent and 203 percent greater than those of an Oldham big piecer. Mass. BSL, Twenty-Seventh Annual Report (Boston, 1898), p. 6;Google ScholarWood, History of Wages, p. 54.Google Scholar

64 Unit labor cost figures were derived from the sources cited in notes 61 and 62. For data on cotton prices by grade and staple length, see Winterbottom, Cotton Spinning, p. 232ff.Google Scholar

65 See Lazonick, “Factor Costs”; idem., “Competition.” A detailed and, in some ways pioneering, neoclassical analysis of the rings versus mules question can be found in Sandberg, Lars, Lancashire in Decline (Columbus, 1974), chs. 2–3.Google Scholar

66 Lintner, “Social History,” p. 164; Lamb, “Entrepreneurship,” ch. 15, p. 51; NECMA, Transactions, 31 (1881), p. 21; NECMA, Transactions, 34 (1883), p. 54; Mass. BSL, 13th Report, pp. 313–14; Garraty, Labor and Capital, pp. 33–36;Google ScholarU.S. Industrial Commission, Report on the Relations and Conditions of Capital and Labor (Washington, 1901), pp. 344–48;Google ScholarKnowlton, Evelyn, Pepperell's Progress (Cambridge, MA, 1948), p. 171;CrossRefGoogle ScholarYoung, American Cotton Industry, p. 4; Silvia, “Spindle City,” pp. 553–54.Google Scholar

67 For more discussion on this point, see Lazonick, “Industrial Relations,” pp. 256–57.Google Scholar

68 See e.g., CFT, 17 April 1885, 31 Dec. 1886; Webb and Webb, Industrial Democracy, pp. 424–25.Google Scholar

69 While ignoring the relative magnitudes of unit cotton-cost differentials in the two countries, Sandberg and, following him, Harley have argued that it was the higher unit labor-cost differentials of mule yarn over ring yarn in the United States as compared to Britain that accounts for the relatively rapid diffusion of ring spinning in New England. Sandberg, Lancashire, ch. 2;Google ScholarHarley, C. K., “Skilled Labour and the Choice of Technique in Edwardian Industry,” Explorations in Economic History, 11 (Summer 1974), p. 399. Sandberg, however, overestimates the unit labor costs on mules in both countries as well as output per spindle on ring-frames in the United States, and as a result overstates the relative unit labor-cost advantage of rings in the U.S. When correct data are used, we find that, while the labor-cost saving of rings over mules favored the introduction of rings in both the United States and Britain, it was an insignificant factor in accounting for the differences in the rate of diffusion of the newer technology.CrossRefGoogle ScholarSee Lazonick, , “Factor Costs,” and productivity data in Whittam, William, Report on England's Cotton Industry (Washington, 1907), p. 19;Google ScholarMason Machine Works, Cotton Machinery (Taunton, MA, 1898), pp. 122–26;Google ScholarMosely, Reports, pp. 129–30.Google Scholar