Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T17:43:57.031Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Borrowing Stigma and Lender of Last Resort Policies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 October 2023

Yunzhi Hu*
Affiliation:
University of North Carolina Kenan-Flagler Business School
Hanzhe Zhang
Affiliation:
Michigan State University Department of Economics hanzhe@msu.edu
*
yunzhi_hu@kenan-flagler.unc.edu (corresponding author)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

How should the lender of last resort provide liquidity to banks during periods of financial distress? During the 2008–2010 crisis, banks avoided borrowing from the Fed’s long-standing discount window but actively participated in its special monetary program, the Term Auction Facility, although both programs had the same borrowing requirements. Using an adverse selection model with endogenous borrowing decisions, we explain why the two programs suffer from different stigma costs and how the introduction of TAF incentivized banks’ borrowing. We discuss the empirical relevance of the model’s predictions.

[Banks] deliberately did not ask for the liquidity they needed for fear of damaging their reputation—the ‘stigma’ problem… I do not think we were conscious of this before the crisis started and I do not think central banks have a convincing answer to it… This is, I think, still a challenge in how to manage the process of central bank provision of liquidity support. This is one of the big intellectual issues that has not been fully resolved. (Governor Mervyn King, Bank of England (2016))

For various reasons, including the competitive format of the auctions, [Term Auction Facility] has not suffered the stigma of conventional discount window lending and has proved effective for injecting liquidity into the financial system… Another possible reason that [Term Auction Facility] has not suffered from stigma is that auctions are not settled for several days, which signals to the market that auction participants do not face an immediate shortage of funds. (Ben Bernanke, testimony to U.S. House of Representatives (2010))

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington

Footnotes

We are grateful for comments and suggestions from an anonymous referee, Viral Acharya, Sriya Anbil, Olivier Armantier, Yasser Boualam, Chen Cheng, Jason Roderick Donaldson, Huberto Ennis, Paolo Fulghieri, Gary Gorton, Robin Greenwood, Anil Kashyap, Vijay Krishna, Aeimit Lakdawala, Raoul Minetti, Paige Ouimet, George Pennacchi (the editor), Jacob Sagi, Philipp Schnabl, David Thesmar, Larry Wall, Yiqing Xing, and participants at UNC Kenan-Flagler, JHU Carey, MSU economics, 2018 Doug Diamond’s birthday conference, 2019 EFA, 2019 Northeastern Finance Conference, 2019 FIRS, University of Wisconsin, 2019 Stony Brook Game Theory Festival, 2019 Yale Fighting a Financial Crisis Conference, the Chicago Fed, the Richmond Fed, Boston University, the Atlanta Fed, 2020 Midwest Macro Conference, 2019 AEA Conference, 2020 MFA Conference, 2020 Short-Term Funding Markets Conference, and 2020Australian National Finance Conference. We also thank Nathan Delaney, Nancy Gahlot, Sunwoo Hwang, Peiyi Jin, Dongming Yu, and especially Spencer Andrews for their research assistance. Zhang acknowledges the National Science Foundation.

References

Acharya, V. V.; Fleming, M. J.; Hrung, W. B.; and Sarkar, A.. “Dealer Financial Conditions and Lender-of-Last-Resort Facilities.” Journal of Financial Economics, 123 (2017), 81107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acharya, V. V., and Mora, N.. “A Crisis of Banks as Liquidity Providers.” Journal of Finance, 70 (2015), 143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Afonso, G.; Kovner, A.; and Schoar, A.. “Stressed, Not Frozen: The Federal Funds Market in the Financial Crisis.” Journal of Finance, 66 (2011), 11091139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angelini, P.; Nobili, A.; and Picillo, C.. “The Interbank Market After August 2007: What Has Changed, and Why?Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 43 (2011), 923958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armantier, O.; Ghysels, E.; Sarkar, A.; and Shrader, J.. “Discount Window Stigma During the 2007-2008 Financial Crisis.” Journal of Financial Economics, 118 (2015), 317335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armantier, O., and Holt, C.. “Overcoming Discount Window Stigma: An Experimental Investigation.” Review of Financial Studies, 33 (2020), 56305659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armantier, O., and Sporn, J.. “Auctions Implemented by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York During the Great Recession.” Staff Reports 635, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (2013).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashcraft, A.; Bech, M. L.; and Frame, W. S.. “The Federal Home Loan Bank System: The Lender of Next-to-Last Resort?Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42 (2010), 551583.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagehot, W. Lombard Street: A Description of the Money Market. London, UK: HS King (1873).Google Scholar
Bagnoli, M., and Bergstrom, T. C.. “Log-Concave Probability and Its Applications.” Economic Theory, 26 (2005), 445469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, A. N.; Black, L. K.; Bouwman, C. H.; and Dlugosz, J.. “Bank Loan Supply Responses to Federal Reserve Emergency Liquidity Facilities.” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 32 (2017), 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, B. S. “Statement by Ben S. Bernanke, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Prepared for the Committee on Financial Services, US House of Representatives.” available at https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20100210a.pdf (2010).Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. S. The Courage to Act: A Memoir of a Crisis and its Aftermath. New York, NY: W. W. Norton & Company (2015).Google Scholar
Carlson, M., and Rose, J. D., “Stigma and the Discount Window.” “FEDS Notes.” (2017).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Che, Y.-K.; Choe, C.; and Rhee, K.. “Bailout Stigma.” Journal of Finance, forthcoming (2024).Google Scholar
Chen, H.; Xie, H.; and Hu, T.. “Log-Concavity of Generalized Order Statistics.” Statistics and Probability Letters, 79 (2009), 396399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornett, M. M.; McNutt, J. J.; Strahan, P. E.; and Tehranian, H.. “Liquidity Risk Management and Credit Supply in the Financial Crisis.” Journal of Financial Economics, 101 (2011), 297312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courtois, R., and Ennis, H.. “Is There Stigma Associated with Discount Window?Richmond Fed Economic Brief, 10 (2010), 15.Google Scholar
Demirguc-Kunt, A.; Detragiache, E.; and Merrouche, O.. “Bank Capital: Lessons from the Financial Crisis.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45 (2013), 11471164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drechsler, I.; Drechsel, T.; Marques-Ibanez, D.; and Schnabl, P.. “Who Borrows from the Lender of Last Resort?Journal of Finance, LXXI (2016), 19331974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ennis, H. M.Interventions in Markets with Adverse Selection: Implications for Discount Window Stigma.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 51 (2019), 17371764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ennis, H. M., and Weinberg, J. A.. “Over-the-Counter Loans, Adverse Selection, and Stigma in the Interbank Market.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 16 (2013), 601616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federal Housing Finance Agency. “Federal Home Loan Bank Membership Data.” (2023), available at https://www.fhfa.gov/DataTools/Downloads/Pages/Federal-Home-Loan-Bank-Member-Data.aspx.Google Scholar
Federal Reserve. “Factors Affecting Reserve Balances.” (2007), available at https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h41/20071213/.Google Scholar
Freixas, X.; Giannini, C.; Hoggarth, G.; and Soussa, F.. “Lender of Last Resort: A Review of the Literature.” In Financial Crises, Contagion, and the Lender of Last Resort: A Reader, C. Goodhart and G. Illing, eds. Oxfordshire, UK: Oxford University Press (2002).Google Scholar
Fuchs, W., and Skrzypacz, A.. “Government Interventions in a Dynamic Market with Adverse Selection.” Journal of Economic Theory, 158 (2015), 371406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furfine, C.The Reluctance to Borrow from the Fed.” Economics Letters, 72 (2001), 209213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furfine, C.Standing Facilities and Interbank Borrowing: Evidence from the Federal Reserve’s New Discount Window.” International Finance, 6 (2003), 329347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furfine, C. “Discount Window Borrowing: Understanding Recent Experience.” Tech. Rep. 212, Fed Reserve Bank of Chicago (2005).Google Scholar
Gorton, G., and Metrick, A.. “Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo.” Journal of Financial Economics, 104 (2012), 425451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorton, G., and Ordoñez, G.. “Fighting Crises with Secrecy.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12 (2020), 218245.Google Scholar
Holmström, B., and Tirole, J.. “Private and Public Supply of Liquidity.” Journal of Political Economy, 106 (1998), 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kacperczyk, M., and Schnabl, P.. “When Safe Proved Risky: Commercial Paper During the Financial Crisis of 2007–2009.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24 (2010), 2950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, M.Newsmaker: Lord Mervyn King, Former Governor of the Bank of England.” Interviewed by The Trusted Professional, Aug. 6 (2016).Google Scholar
La’O, J.Predatory Trading, Stigma and the Fed’s Term Auction Facility.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 65 (2014), 5775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lowery, R.Comment on: ‘Predatory Trading, Stigma, and the Fed’s Term Auction Facility’ by Jennifer La’o.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 65 (2014), 7679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAndrews, J.; Sarkar, A.; and Wang, Z.. “The Effect of the Term Auction Facility on the London Interbank Offered Rate.” Journal of Banking & Finance, 83 (2017), 135152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, E., “Auction-Based Liquidity of Last Resort.” Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania (2017).Google Scholar
Myerson, R.Optimal Auction Design.” Mathematics of Operations Research, 6 (1981), 5873.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paribas, B. “BNP Paribas Suspends NAV Calculation.” (2007).Google Scholar
Peristiani, S.The Growing Reluctance to Borrow at the Discount Window: An Empirical Investigation.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 80 (1998), 611620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Philippon, T., and Skreta, V.. “Optimal Interventions in Markets with Adverse Selection.” American Economic Review, 102 (2012), 128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochet, J.-C., and Vives, X.. “Coordination Failures and the Lender of Last Resort: Was Bagehot Right After All?Journal of the European Economic Association, 2 (2004), 11161147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shin, H. S.Reflections on Northern Rock: The Bank Run that Heralded the Global Financial Crisis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23 (2009), 101119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thornton, D. L.What the LIBOR-OIS Spread Says.” Economic Synopses, 24 (2009).Google Scholar
Tirole, J.Overcoming Adverse Selection: How Public Intervention Can Restore Market Functioning.” American Economic Review, 102 (2012), 2959.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, W.Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders.” Journal of Finance, 16 (1961), 837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, T.The U.S. Money Market and the Term Auction Facility in the Financial Crisis of 2007-2009.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 93 (2011), 617631.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yale Program on Financial Stability. “The New Bagehot Project.” Available at https://newbagehot.yale.edu/ (2019).Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Hu and Zhang supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Hu and Zhang supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 432.2 KB