Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T07:15:10.909Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Interest Rate Risk and the Cross Section of Stock Returns

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 March 2014

Abraham Lioui
Affiliation:
abraham.lioui@edhec.edu, EDHEC Business School, BP 3116, Nice, Cedex 3 06202, France
Paulo Maio
Affiliation:
paulo.maio@hanken.fi, Department of Finance and Statistics, Hanken School of Economics, Arkadiankatu, 22, Helsinki 00101, Finland.

Abstract

We derive a macroeconomic asset pricing model in which the key factor is the opportunity cost of money. The model explains well the cross section of stock returns in addition to the excess market return. The interest rate factor is priced and seems to drive most of the explanatory power of the model. In this model, both value stocks and past long-term losers enjoy higher average (excess) returns because they have higher interest rate risk than growth/past winner stocks. The model significantly outperforms the nested models (capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and consumption CAPM (CCAPM)) and compares favorably with alternative macroeconomic models.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aït-Sahalia, Y.; Parker, J.; and Yogo, M.. “Luxury Goods and the Equity Premium.” Journal of Finance, 59 (2004), 29593004.Google Scholar
Bakshi, G., and Chen, Z.. “Inflation, Asset Prices, and the Term Structure of Interest Rates in Monetary Economics.” Review of Financial Studies, 1 (1996), 241275.Google Scholar
Balvers, R., and Huang, D.. “Money and the (C)CAPM.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44 (2009), 337368.Google Scholar
Bansal, R., and Coleman, W. II. “A Monetary Explanation of the Equity Premium, Term Premium, and Risk-Free Rate Puzzles.” Journal of Political Economy, 104 (1996), 11351171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bansal, R.; Dittmar, R.; and Kiku, D.. “Cointegration and Consumption Risks in Asset Returns.” Review of Financial Studies, 22 (2009), 13431375.Google Scholar
Bansal, R.; Gallant, A.; and Tauchen, G.. “Rational Pessimism, Rational Exuberance, and Asset Pricing Models.” Review of Economic Studies, 74 (2007), 10051033.Google Scholar
Bansal, R., and Yaron, A.. “Risks for the Long Run: A Potential Resolution of Asset Pricing Puzzles.” Journal of Finance, 59 (2004), 14811510.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., and Gertler, M.. “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9 (1995), 2748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyle, G., and Young, L.. “Asset Prices, Commodity Prices, and Money: A General Equilibrium, Rational Expectations Model.” American Economic Review, 78 (1988), 2445.Google Scholar
Breeden, D. “An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities.” Journal of Financial Economics, 7 (1979), 265296.Google Scholar
Breeden, D.; Gibbons, M.; and Litzenberger, R.. “Empirical Test of the Consumption-Oriented CAPM.” Journal of Finance, 44 (1989), 231262.Google Scholar
Brennan, M.; Wang, A.; and Xia, Y.. “Estimation and Test of a Simple Model of Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing.” Journal of Finance, 59 (2004), 17431775.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bufman, G., and Leiderman, L.. “Currency Substitution under Nonexpected Utility: Some Empirical Evidence.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 25 (1993), 320335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buraschi, A., and Jiltsov, A.. “Habit Formation and Macroeconomic Models of the Term Structure of Interest Rates.” Journal of Finance, 62 (2007), 30093063.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. “Understanding Risk and Return.” Journal of Political Economy, 104 (1996), 298345.Google Scholar
Campbell, J. “Consumption-Based Asset Pricing.” In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Vol. 1B, Constantinides, G., Harris, M., and Stulz, R., eds. Amsterdam: North-Holland (2003), 801885.Google Scholar
Campbell, J., and Cochrane, J.. “By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior.” Journal of Political Economy, 107 (1999), 205251.Google Scholar
Campbell, J., and Mankiw, G.. “Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time-Series Evidence.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 4 (1989), 185216.Google Scholar
Campbell, J., and Vuolteenaho, T.. “Bad Beta, Good Beta.” American Economic Review, 94 (2004), 12491275.Google Scholar
Chan, K.; Foresi, S.; and Lang, L.. “Does Money Explain Asset Returns? Theory and Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Finance, 51 (1996), 345361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, N.; Roll, R.; and Ross, S.. “Economic Forces and the Stock Market.” Journal of Business, 59 (1986), 383403.Google Scholar
Chen, X.; Favilukis, J.; and Ludvigson, S.. “An Estimation of Economic Models with Recursive Preferences.” Quantitative Economics, 4 (2013), 3983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, J. “A Cross-Sectional Test of an Investment-Based Asset Pricing Model.” Journal of Political Economy, 104 (1996), 572621.Google Scholar
Cochrane, J. Asset Pricing, rev. ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (2005).Google Scholar
Cochrane, J. “Financial Markets and the Real Economy.” In Handbook of the Equity Premium, Mehra, R., ed. Amsterdam: North-Holland (2008), 237325.Google Scholar
Da, Z. “Cash Flow, Consumption Risk, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 64 (2009), 923956.Google Scholar
Da, Z., and Warachka, M.. “Cashflow Risk, Systematic Earnings Revisions, and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics, 94 (2009), 448468.Google Scholar
Danthine, J., and Donaldson, J.. “Inflation and Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy.” Econometrica, 54 (1986), 585605.Google Scholar
De Bondt, W., and Thaler, R.. “Does the Stock Market Overreact?Journal of Finance, 40 (1985), 793805.Google Scholar
Epstein, L., and Zin, S.. “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework.” Econometrica, 57 (1989), 937969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, L., and Zin, S.. “Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy, 99 (1991), 263286.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eraker, B. “Affine General Equilibrium Models.” Management Science, 54 (2008), 20682080.Google Scholar
Fama, E., and French, K.. “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.” Journal of Financial Economics, 33 (1993), 356.Google Scholar
Fama, E., and French, K.. “Multifactor Explanations of Asset Pricing Anomalies.” Journal of Finance, 51 (1996), 5584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R. “Functional Equivalence between Liquidity Costs and the Utility of Money.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 17 (1986), 271291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferson, W., and Harvey, C.. “Conditioning Variables and the Cross Section of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 54 (1999), 13251360.Google Scholar
Finn, M.; Hoffman, D.; and Schlagenhauf, D.. “Intertemporal Asset-Pricing Relationships in Barter and Monetary Economies.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 25 (1990), 431451.Google Scholar
Gomes, J.; Kogan, L.; and Yogo, M.. “Durability of Output and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Political Economy, 117 (2009), 941986.Google Scholar
Gu, L., and Huang, D.. “Consumption, Money, Intratemporal Substitution and Cross-Sectional Asset Returns.” Journal of Financial Research, 36 (2013), 115146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, J., and Lee, H.. “Yield Spreads as Alternative Risk Factors for Size and Book-to-Market.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 41 (2006), 245269.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. “Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators.” Econometrica, 50 (1982), 10291054.Google Scholar
Hansen, L.; Heaton, J.; and Li, N.. “Consumption Strikes Back? Measuring Long-Run Risk.” Journal of Political Economy, 116 (2008), 260302.Google Scholar
Holman, J. “GMM Estimation of a Money-in-the-Utility Function Model: The Implications of Functional Forms.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30 (1998), 679698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lettau, M., and Ludvigson, S.. “Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A Cross-Sectional Test When Risk Premia Are Time-Varying.” Journal of Political Economy, 109 (2001), 12381287.Google Scholar
Lettau, M.; Ludvigson, S.; and Wachter, J.. “The Declining Equity Premium: What Role Does Macroeconomic Risk Play?Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2008), 16511687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewellen, J.; Nagel, S.; and Shanken, J.. “A Skeptical Appraisal of Asset-Pricing Tests.” Journal of Financial Economics, 96 (2010), 175194.Google Scholar
Lintner, J. “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 47 (1965), 1337.Google Scholar
Lioui, A., and Poncet, P.. “General Equilibrium Real and Nominal Interest Rates.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 28 (2004), 15691595.Google Scholar
Lioui, A., and Rangvid, J.. “Stock Return Predictability in a Monetary Economy.” Working Paper, Copenhagen Business School (2009).Google Scholar
Lucas, R. “Asset Prices in an Exchange Economy.” Econometrica, 46 (1978), 14291445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lustig, H., and Van Nieuwerburgh, S.. “Housing Collateral, Consumption Insurance, and Risk Premia: An Empirical Perspective.” Journal of Finance, 60 (2005), 11671219.Google Scholar
Maio, P. “Intertemporal CAPM with Conditioning Variables.” Management Science, 59 (2013), 122141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maio, P., and Santa-Clara, P.. “Multifactor Models and Their Consistency with the ICAPM.” Journal of Financial Economics, 106 (2012), 586613.Google Scholar
Malloy, C.; Moskowitz, T.; and Vissing-Jørgensen, A.. “Long-Run Stockholder Consumption Risk and Asset Returns.” Journal of Finance, 64 (2009), 24272479.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N., and Shapiro, M.. “Risk and Return: Consumption Beta versus Market Beta.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 68 (1986), 452459.Google Scholar
Marshall, D. “Inflation and Asset Returns in a Monetary Economy.” Journal of Finance, 47 (1992), 13151342.Google Scholar
Mehra, R., and Prescott, E.. “The Equity Premium: A Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 15 (1985), 145161.Google Scholar
Parker, J., and Julliard, C.. “Consumption Risk and the Cross Section of Expected Returns.” Journal of Political Economy, 113 (2005), 185222.Google Scholar
Petkova, R. “Do the Fama–French Factors Proxy for Innovations in Predictive Variables?Journal of Finance, 61 (2006), 581612.Google Scholar
Roll, R. “A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory’s Tests, Part I: On Past and Potential Testability of the Theory.” Journal of Financial Economics, 4 (1977), 129176.Google Scholar
Shanken, J., and Zhou, G.. “Estimating and Testing Beta Pricing Models: Alternative Methods and Their Performance in Simulations.” Journal of Financial Economics, 84 (2007), 4086.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sharpe, W. “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of Risk.” Journal of Finance, 19 (1964), 425442.Google Scholar
Tristani, O. “Model Specification, the Equilibrium Natural Interest Rate, and the Equity Premium.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41 (2009), 14531479.Google Scholar
Walsh, C. Monetary Theory and Policy, 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (2003).Google Scholar
Weil, P. “The Equity Premium Puzzle and the Risk-Free Rate Puzzle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 24 (1989), 401421.Google Scholar
Yogo, M. “A Consumption-Based Explanation of Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 61 (2006), 539580.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Lioui and Maio supplementary material

Appendix

Download Lioui and Maio supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 482.9 KB