Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T04:46:59.916Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How to measure informal institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 June 2017

STEFAN VOIGT*
Affiliation:
Institute of Law and Economics, University of Hamburg, Hamburg, Germany

Abstract

There have been repeated claims that informal institutions play an important or even crucial role in economic development. Yet measuring informal institutions entails serious challenges. This paper identifies the difficulties in measuring informal institutions, critically discusses some attempts hitherto taken and encourages the more intensive use of experiments to measure them.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Allina-Pisano, J. (2007), The Post-Soviet Potemkin Village: Politics and Property Rights in the Black Earth, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barnett, A., Yandle, B. and Naufal, G. (2013), Regulation, trust, and cronyism in Middle Eastern societies: the simple economics of ‘wasta’, Journal of Socio-Economics, 44: 41–6.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, C. (2006), The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cason, T. and Mui, V. L. (2014), Coordinating resistance through communication and repeated interaction, Economic Journal, 124 (574): F226–F256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casson, M., della Giusta, M. and Kambhampati, U. (2010), Formal and informal institutions and development (Special issue), World Development, 38 (2): 137–41.Google Scholar
Chaudhuri, A. (2011), Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: a selective survey of the literature, Experimental Economics, 14 (1): 4783.Google Scholar
Ensminger, J. (1997), Changing property rights: reconciling formal and informal rights to land in Africa. In: Drobak, J. and Nye, J. (eds): The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, San Diego, Academic Press, pp. 165–96.Google Scholar
Ensminger, J. and Henrich, J. (eds) (2014). Experimenting with Social Norms – Fairness and Punishment in Cross-Cultural Perspective. New York et al.: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Falk, A., Becker, A., Dohmen, T., Enke, B., Huffman, D. and Sunde, U. (2015), The Nature and Predictive Power of Preferences: Global Evidence, typescript, November (Revise & Resubmit at Quarterly Journal of Economics).Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., Rosenbladt, B. v., Schupp, J. and Wagner, G. (2002), A nationwide laboratory examining trust and trustworthiness by integrating experiments into representative surveys, Schmollers Jahrbuch, 122 (4): 519–42.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. (2006), The economics of fairness, reciprocity and altruism – experimental evidence and new theories. In: Kolm, S.-C. and Ythier, J. (eds): Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Volume 1. North Holland: Elsevier, pp. 616–91.Google Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L. (2004), The role of social capital in financial development, American Economic Review, 94 (3): 526–56.Google Scholar
Gutmann, J. and Voigt, S. (2016), Why is traditional law so prevalent? Identifying reasons for its widespread use, mimeo, available from: Institute of Law & Economics, University of Hamburg, Germany.Google Scholar
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L. (2008), Long-term persistence, NBER Working Paper 14278.Google Scholar
Helmke, G. and Levitsky, S. (2006), Informal Institutions and Democracy: Lessons from Latin America, Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H. and McElreath, R. (2001), In search of homo economicus: behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies, American Economic Review, 91 (2): 73–8.Google Scholar
Herbst, J. (2014), States and Power in Africa: Comparative Lessons in Authority and Control, Second Edition Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Herrmann, B., Thöni, C. and Gächter, S. (2008), Anti-social punishment across societies, Science, 319 (5868): 1362–7.Google Scholar
Hofstede, G. (1991), Cultures and Organizations – Intercultural Cooperation and its Importance for Survival, McGraw-Hill International.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R. and Welzel, C. (2005), Modernization, Cultural Change, and Democracy: The human Development Sequence, Cambridge University Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Jackson, M. O. and Xing, Y. (2014), Culture-dependent strategies in coordination games, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111 (3): 10,889–96.Google Scholar
Kiwit, D. and Voigt, S. (1995), Überlegungen zum institutionellen Wandel unter Berücksichtigung des Verhältnisses interner und externer Institutionen, ORDO – Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft, 46: 117–48.Google Scholar
Mason, W. and Suri, S. (2012), Conducting behavioral research on Amazon's Mechanical Turk, Behavior Research Methods, 44 (1), 123.Google Scholar
Mehta, J., Starmer, C. and Sugden, R. (1994), The nature of salience: an experimental investigation of pure coordination games, American Economic Review, 84 (3): 658–73.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P., North, D. and Weingast, B. (1990), The role of institutions in the revival of trade: the law merchant, private judges, and the champagne fairs, Economics and Politics, 2 (1): 23.Google Scholar
North, D. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Oosterbeek, H., Sloof, R. and van de Kuilen, G. (2004), Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: evidence from a meta-analysis, Experimental Economics, 7 (2): 171–88.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1996), Incentives, rules of the game, and development, Bruno, M. (ed.): Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, DC: World Bank, 207–34.Google Scholar
Paolacci, G., Chandler, J. and Ipeirotis, P. (2010), Running experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk, judgment and decision making, 5 (5): 411–19.Google Scholar
Peters, P. E. (2009), Challenges in land tenure and land reform in Africa: anthropological contributions, World Development, 37 (8), 1317–25.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (2013), Measuring institutions in the Trobriand Islands: a comment on Voigt's paper, Journal of Institutional Economics, 9 (1): 27–9.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A. and Trebbi, F. (2004), Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development, Journal of Economic Growth, 9 (2): 131–65.Google Scholar
Roland, G. (2009), Fast-moving and slow-moving institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Behaviour, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2008, 134–59.Google Scholar
Rustagi, D., Engel, S. and Kosfeld, M. (2010), Conditional cooperation and costly monitoring explain success in forest commons management, Science, 330 (6006): 961–5.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. (1960), The Strategy of Conflict, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B. (1987), The institutional foundations of committee power, American Political Science Review, 81 (1): 85104.Google Scholar
Sikor, T. and Müller, D. (2009), The limits of state-led land reform: an introduction, World Development (Special issue on the limits of state-led land reform), 37 (8): 1307–16.Google Scholar
Stoddard, O. and Leibbrandt, A. (2014), An experimental study on the relevance and scope of nationality as a coordination device, Economic Inquiry, 52 (4): 1392–407.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare, Volume 22. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Tabellini, G. (2010), Culture and institutions: economic development in the regions of Europe, Journal of the European Economic Association, 8 (4): 677716.Google Scholar
Vieider, F. M., Chmura, T. and Martinsson, P. (2012), Risk attitudes, development, and growth: Macroeconomic evidence from experiments in 30 countries (No. SP II 2012–401), WZB Discussion Paper.Google Scholar
Vieider, F. M., Lefebvre, M., Bouchouicha, R., Chmura, T., Hakimov, R., Krawczyk, M. and Martinsson, P. (2015), Common components of risk and uncertainty attitudes across contexts and domains: evidence from 30 countries, Journal of the European Economic Association, 13 (3): 421–52.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (2013), How (not) to measure institutions, Journal of Institutional Economics, 9 (1): 126.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. and Kiwit, D. (1998), The role and evolution of beliefs, habits, moral norms and institutions. In: Giersch, H. (ed.): The Merits of Markets: – Critical Issues of the Open Society, Berlin et al.: Springer, pp. 83108.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. and Park, S.-M. (2013), Arbitration is no substitute for state courts, Journal of Development Studies, 49 (11): 1514–31.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. (1993), Constitutions as governance structures: the political foundations of secure markets, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 149 (1): 286311.Google Scholar
Williamson, C. (2009), Informal institutions rule: institutional arrangements and economic performance, Public Choice, 139 (3/4): 371–87.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. (2000), The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead, Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (3): 595613.Google Scholar