Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-05T20:50:08.521Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An experimental study of leadership institutions in collective action games

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Selhan Garip Sahin
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Rochester Institute of Technology, 1355 George Eastman Building (#1), 92 Lomb Memorial Drive, 14623 Rochester, NY, USA
Catherine Eckel*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Texas A&M University, 3052 ALLN, 77843-4228 College Station, TX, USA
Mana Komai
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, St. Cloud State University, 381 SH, 720 4th Ave. South, 56301-4498 St. Cloud, MN, USA
*

Abstract

We investigate the effectiveness of two leadership institutions in each of two games: a weakest link and a linear public good game. An “Exemplar” leader is a first mover who commits to a level of contribution; a “Manager” is a first mover who makes cheap talk suggestions to the team members. Our results show that both leadership institutions reduce coordination failures as compared to a simultaneous move, baseline scenario with no leader. Although the Manager treatment seems to be slightly more effective at the outset, both leadership institutions significantly and equally improve contributions in the coordination game over time. According to our results none of the leadership institutions seem effective in the linear public good game. This may be due to the fact that our marginal per capita return is rather large, keeping the contribution levels high regardless of the treatment. Subjects who choose to free ride continue to do so with or without leaders, and subjects who choose to be cooperative do not become discouraged by others’ lack of cooperation. These results both replicate earlier findings and allow direct comparison across similar games.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © Economic Science Association 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:10.1007/s40881-015-0010-6) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Andreoni, J. (1998). Toward a theory of charitable fund-raising. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 11861213. 10.1086/250044CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (2006). Leadership giving in charitable fund raising. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 8(1), 122. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2006.00250.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arbak, E., Villeval, M. C. (2013). Voluntary leadership: Motivation and influence. Social Choice and Welfare, 40(3), 635662. 10.1007/s00355-011-0626-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N., Sausgruber, R. (2005). Conformity and reciprocity in public good provision. Journal of Economic Psychology, 26(5), 664681. 10.1016/j.joep.2005.02.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J., Cooper, D., Fatas, E. (2007). Leadership and overcoming coordination failure with asymmetric costs. Experimental Economics, 10, 269284. 10.1007/s10683-007-9182-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brandts, J., Cooper, D. J., & Weber, R. A. (2014). Legitimacy, communication and leadership in the turnaround game. Working Paper No. 755, Barcelona Graduate School of Economics.Google Scholar
Charness, G. (2000). Self-serving cheap talk: A test of Aumann’s conjecture. Games and Economic Behavior, 33(2), 177194. 10.1006/game.1999.0776CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, V. (1998). A survey of experiments on communication via cheap talk. Journal of Economic theory, 78(2), 286298. 10.1006/jeth.1997.2359CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, R. (2007). Theories of commitment, altruism, and reciprocity: evidence from linear public good games. Economic Inquiry, 45, 199216. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2006.00006.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J., Feltovich, N. (2002). Do actions speak louder than words? An experimental comparison of observation and cheap talk. Games and Economic Behavior, 39(1), 127. 10.1006/game.2001.0892CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., Fatas, E., Wilson, R. (2010). Cooperation and status in organizations. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(4), 737762. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01472.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., Harwell, H., & Castillo, J. (2014). Four classic public goods experiments: A replication study. ERL Working Paper, Texas A&M University.Google Scholar
Erkal, N., Gangadharan, L., Nikiforakis, N. (2011). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. The American Economic Review, 101, 33303348. 10.1257/aer.101.7.3330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U., Gachter, S., Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71, 397404. 10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00394-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S., Meier, S. (2003). Are political economists selfish and indoctrinated? Evidence from a natural experiment. Economic Inquiry, 41, 448462. 10.1093/ei/cbg020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S., Nosenzo, D., Renner, E., Sefton, M. (2012). Who makes a good leader? Cooperativeness, optimism, and leading-by-example. Economic Inquiry, 50(4), 953967. 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00295.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G., Baldassarri, D. (2012). The impact of elections on cooperation: Evidence from a lab-in-the-field experiment in Uganda. American Journal of Political Science, 56(4), 964985. 10.1111/j.1540-5907.2012.00596.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grossman, P. J., Komai, M., & Jensen, J. (2015). Leadership and gender in groups: An experiment. Canadian Journal of Economics, 48(1).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guth, W., Levati, V. M., Sutter, M., van der Heijden, E. (2007). Leading by example with and without exclusion power in voluntary contribution experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 91, 10231042. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2006.10.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hermalin, B. E. (1998). Toward an economic theory of leadership: Leading by example. American Economic Review, 88, 11881206.Google Scholar
Houser, D., Levy, D. M., Padgitt, K., Peart, S. J., Xiao, E. (2014). Raising the price of talk: An experimental analysis of transparent leadership. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 105, 208218. 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.05.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M. (1988). Group size effects in public goods provision: The voluntary contributions mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 179199. 10.2307/1882648CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jack, B. K., Recalde, M. P. (2015). Leadership and the voluntary provision of public goods: Field evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Economics, 122, 8093. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2014.10.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keser, C., Van Winden, F. (2000). Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 102, 2329. 10.1111/1467-9442.00182CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Komai, M., Grossman, P. J. (2009). Leadership and group size: An experiment. Economics Letters, 105, 2022. 10.1016/j.econlet.2009.05.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Komai, M., Grossman, P. J., Deters, T. (2011). Leadership and information in a single-shot collective action game: An experimental study. Managerial and Decision Economics, 32, 119134.Google Scholar
Komai, M., Stegeman, M. (2010). Leadership based on asymmetric information. Rand Journal of Economics, 41, 3563. 10.1111/j.1756-2171.2009.00089.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Komai, M., Stegeman, M., Hermalin, B. E. (2007). Leadership and information. American Economic Review, 97, 944947. 10.1257/aer.97.3.944CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kulas, J. T., Komai, M., Grossman, P. J. (2013). Leadership, information, and risk attitude: A game theoretic approach. The Leadership Quarterly, 24(2), 349362. 10.1016/j.leaqua.2013.01.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumru, C. S., Vesterlund, L. (2010). The effect of status on charitable giving. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(4), 709735. 10.1111/j.1467-9779.2010.01471.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levati, M. V., Sutter, M., van der Heijden, E. (2007). Leading by example in a public goods experiment with heterogeneity and incomplete information. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51, 793818. 10.1177/0022002707302796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, D. M., Padgitt, K., Peart, S. J., Houser, D., Xiao, E. (2011). Leadership, cheap talk and really cheap talk. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 77(1), 4052. 10.1016/j.jebo.2010.02.018CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A., Rondeau, D. (2003). The impact of challenge gifts on charitable giving: An experimental investigation. Economics Letters, 79(2), 153159. 10.1016/S0165-1765(02)00300-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moxnes, E., van der Heijden, E. (2003). The effect of leadership in public bad projects. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 47, 773795. 10.1177/0022002703258962CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, J., Sefton, M., Vesterlund, L. (2005). After you: Endogenous sequencing in voluntary contribution games. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 13991419. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.02.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potters, J., Sefton, M., Vesterlund, L. (2007). Leading by example and signaling in voluntary contribution games: An experimental study. Economic Theory, 33, 169182. 10.1007/s00199-006-0186-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rivas, M. F., Sutter, M. (2011). The benefits of voluntary leadership in experimental public goods games. Economics Letters, 112(2), 176178. 10.1016/j.econlet.2011.04.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty, and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80(1), 234248.Google Scholar
Van Huyck, J. B., Gillette, A. B., Battalio, R. C. (1992). Credible assignments in coordination games. Games and Economic Behavior, 4(4), 606626. 10.1016/0899-8256(92)90040-YCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vesterlund, L. (2003). The informational value of sequential fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 87, 627657. 10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00187-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, R. K., Rhodes, C. M. (1997). Leadership and credibility in n-person coordination games. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(6), 767791. 10.1177/0022002797041006003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, R. K., Sell, J. (1997). “Liar, liar…” cheap talk and reputation in repeated public goods settings. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41(5), 695717. 10.1177/0022002797041005005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 1

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 1
Download Sahin et. al. supplementary material 1(File)
File 978.9 KB
Supplementary material: File

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 2

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 2
Download Sahin et. al. supplementary material 2(File)
File 634 KB
Supplementary material: File

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 3

Sahin et. al. supplementary material 3
Download Sahin et. al. supplementary material 3(File)
File 607.7 KB