Hostname: page-component-5f745c7db-nc56l Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-06T07:18:41.989Z Has data issue: true hasContentIssue false

Hot versus cold behavior in centipede games

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Bernardo García-Pola*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, AGORA Center, UNSW Business School, Sydney, NSW 2052, Australia
Nagore Iriberri*
Affiliation:
Dpto. Fundamentos del Análisis Económico I and Bridge, University of the Basque Country UPV-EHU, Av. Lehendakari Aguirre 83, 48015 Bilbao, Spain
Jaromír Kovářík*
Affiliation:
Dpto. Fundamentos del Análisis Económico I and Bridge, University of the Basque Country UPV-EHU, Av. Lehendakari Aguirre 83, 48015 Bilbao, Spain

Abstract

There is a long-standing unresolved debate in game theory and experimental economics regarding the behavioral equivalence of the direct-response method (hot play) and the strategy method (cold play). Using a unified experimental framework, we compare behavior elicited via both methods in four different Centipede Games that differ in their incentives to take or pass, in the evolution of those incentives over decision nodes, and in the asymmetry of the incentives across the two player roles. Out of the four Centipede Games, we find that both methods yield statistically different behavior in two of them, while in the remaining two we cannot reject the same behavior across the hot and cold methods. Whenever the behavior diverges, hot play consistently makes individuals stop earlier. These findings should shift the question from whether both methods are generically behaviorally equivalent to under which conditions they are (not) and why.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © Economic Science Association 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-020-00096-z) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

N. Iriberri: IKERBASQUE, Basque Foundation for Research.

J. Kovářík: CERGE-EI, a joint workplace of Charles University in Prague and the Economics Institute of the Czech Academy of Sciences, Politických vĕznů 7, 111 21 Prague, Czech Republic.

References

Brandts, J., Charness, G. (2011). The strategy versus the direct-response method: a first survey of experimental comparisons. Experimental Economics, 14(3), 375398. 10.1007/s10683-011-9272-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G., Gneezy, U., Halladay, B. (2016). Experimental methods: Pay one or pay all. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 131, 141150. 10.1016/j.jebo.2016.08.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fey, M., McKelvey, R. D., Palfrey, T. (1996). An experimental study of constant-sum centipede games. International Journal of Game Theory, 25, 269287. 10.1007/BF02425258CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Pola, B., Iriberri, N., Kovářík, J. (2020). Non-equilibrium play in centipede games. Games and Economic Behavior, 120, 391433. 10.1016/j.geb.2020.01.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kawagoe, T., Takizawa, H. (2012). Level-k analysis of experimental centipede games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 82(2), 548566. 10.1016/j.jebo.2012.03.010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitt, S. D., List, J. A., Sadoff, S. E. (2011). Checkmate: Exploring backward induction among chess players. American Economic Review, 101(2), 975–90. 10.1257/aer.101.2.975CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1996). Out of control: Visceral influences on behavior. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 65(3), 272292. 10.1006/obhd.1996.0028CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, R. D., Palfrey, T. R. (1992). (1992) An experimental study of the centipede game. Econometrica, 60(4), 803836. 10.2307/2951567CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, R., Tang, F. F. (1998). Experimental results on the centipede game in normal form: an investigation on learning. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 42, 356384. 10.1006/jmps.1998.1225CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Palacios-Huerta, I., Volij, O. (2009). Field centipedes. The American Economic Review, 99(4), 16191635. 10.1257/aer.99.4.1619CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, A., Stein, W. E., Parco, J. E., Nicholas, T. E. (2003). Equilibrium play and adaptive learning in a three-person centipede game. Games and Economic Behavior, 43(2), 239265. 10.1016/S0899-8256(03)00009-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, R. W. (1981). Games of perfect information, predatory pricing and chain store paradox. Journal of Economic Theory, 25, 92100. 10.1016/0022-0531(81)90018-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, A. E. (1995). Bargaining experiments. Handbook of Experimental Economics, 1995, 253348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

García-Pola et al. supplementary material

García-Pola et al. supplementary material
Download García-Pola et al. supplementary material(File)
File 2 MB