Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-mzp66 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-07T18:42:02.112Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Pushing the bad away: reverse Tullock contests

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Bettina Rockenbach*
Affiliation:
Chair in Behavioral Economics, University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany
Sebastian Schneiders
Affiliation:
Cologne Graduate School in Management, Economics and Social Sciences, University of Cologne, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Cologne, Germany
Marcin Waligora
Affiliation:
Frontier Economics Ltd., Im Zollhafen 24, 50678 Cologne, Germany

Abstract

The literature on rent-seeking primarily focuses on contests for achieving gains, although contests for avoiding losses are also omnipresent. Examples for such ‘reverse’ contests are activities to prevent the close-down of a local school or the construction of a waste disposal close-by. While under standard preferences, investments in ‘reverse’ and ‘conventional’ contests should not be different, loss aversion predicts contests for avoiding losses to be fiercer than conventional ones. In our experimental data, the difference in investments between conventional and reverse Tullock contests is small and statistically insignificant. We discuss several explanations for this remarkable finding.

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (https://doi.org/10.1007/s40881-018-0052-7) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Abbink, K., Brandts, J., Herrmann, B., Orzen, H. (2010). Intergroup conflict and intra-group punishment in an experimental contest game. American Economic Review, 100(1), 420447. 10.1257/aer.100.1.420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, T. K., Isaac, R. M., Salmon, T. C. (2011). Rent seeking in groups. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 29(1), 116125. 10.1016/j.ijindorg.2010.01.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaldoss, W., Rapoport, A., & Hangen, I. N., Nilsen, A. S. (2009). Excessive expenditures in two-stage contests: theory and experimental evidence Game Theory: Strategies, Equilibria and Theorems, NY: Nova Science Publishers 241266.Google Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1995). Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: The effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, CX.1, 121. 10.2307/2118508CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baik, K. H., Chowdhury, S. M., Ramalingam, A. (2015). Group size and matching protocol in contests. CBESS Discussion Paper, 13-11R 130.Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S. M., Jeon, J. Y., Ramalingam, A. (2017). Property rights and loss aversion in contests. Economic Inquiry.Google Scholar
Chowdhury, S., Sheremeta, R. M., Turocy, T. L. (2014). Overbidding and overspreading in rent-seeking experiments: Cost structure and prize allocation rule. Games and Economic Behavior, 87, 224238. 10.1016/j.geb.2014.05.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Congleton, R. D., Hillman, A. L., Konrad, K. A. (2008). 40 years of Research on Rent Seeking, Heidelberg: Springer 10.1007/978-3-540-79247-5Google Scholar
Cornes, R., Hartley, R. (2003). Loss aversion and the Tullock paradox. University of Nottingham Discussion Papers in Economics, 03(17), 125.Google Scholar
Cornes, R., Hartley, R. (2012). Loss aversion in contests. The University of Manchester Economics Discussion Paper Series, EDP-1204, 127.Google Scholar
Dechenaux, E., Kovenock, D., Sheremeta, R. M. (2015). A survey of experimental research on contests, all-pay auctions and tournaments. Experimental Economics, 18(4), 609669. 10.1007/s10683-014-9421-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutcher, E. G., Balafoutas, L., Lindner, F., Ryvkin, D., Sutter, M. (2015). Strive to be first or avoid being last: An experiment on relative performance incentives. Games and Economic Behavior, 94, 3956. 10.1016/j.geb.2015.08.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. H., Palfrey, T. R. (2002). Quantal response equilibrium and overbidding in private-value auctions. Journal of Economic Theory, 104, 247272. 10.1006/jeth.2001.2914CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 114125. 10.1007/s40881-015-0004-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrmann, B., Orzen, H. (2008). The Appearance of homo rivalis: Social preferences and the nature of rent seeking. CeDEx Discussion Paper, No. 2008–10, 140.Google Scholar
Hong, F., Hossain, T., List, J. A. (2015). Framing manipulations in contests: A natural field experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 118, 372382. 10.1016/j.jebo.2015.02.014CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291. 10.2307/1914185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kong, X. (2008). Loss aversion and rent-seeking: An experimental study. CeDEx Discussion Paper No., 2008–13, 132.Google Scholar
Masiliunas, A., Mengel, F., Reiss, J. P. (2014). Behavioral variation in Tullock contests. Working paper.Google Scholar
Palfrey, T. R., Wang, S. W. (2009). On eliciting beliefs in strategic games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 71, 98109. 10.1016/j.jebo.2009.03.025CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parco, J. E., Rapoport, A., Amaldoss, W. (2005). Two-stage contests with budget constraints: An experimental study. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 49, 320338. 10.1016/j.jmp.2005.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockenbach, B., Waligora, M. (2016a). On the reluctance to play best response in Tullock contests. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Rockenbach, B., Waligora, M. (2016b). Beliefs and behavior in Tullock contests. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Schlag, K. H., Tremewan, J., van der Weele, J. J. (2015). A penny for your thoughts: a survey of methods for eliciting beliefs. Experimental Economics, 18(3), 457490. 10.1007/s10683-014-9416-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt, P., Shupp, R., Swope, K., Cadigan, J. (2004). Multi-period rent-seeking contests with carryover: Theory and empirical evidence. Economic Governance, 5, 187211. 10.1007/s10101-004-0075-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic foundation of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 62, 4362. 10.1023/A:1009957816843CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, R. M. (2010). Experimental comparison of multi-stage and one-stage contests. Games and Economic Behavior, 68(2), 731747. 10.1016/j.geb.2009.08.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheremeta, R. M. (2013). Overbidding and heterogeneous behavior in contest experiments. Journal of Economic Surveys, 27(3), 491514. 10.1111/joes.12022CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sonnemans, J., Schram, A., Offerman, T. (1998). Public good provision and public bad prevention: The effect of framing. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 34, 143161. 10.1016/S0167-2681(97)00042-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szidarovsky, F., Okuguchi, K. (1997). On the existence and uniqueness of pure Nash equilibrium in rent-seeking games. Games and Economic Behavior, 18, 135140. 10.1006/game.1997.0517CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G., & Buchanan, J., Tollison, R., Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, Austin: Texas University Press 97112.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297323. 10.1007/BF00122574CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Rockenbach et al. supplementary material

Rockenbach et al. supplementary material
Download Rockenbach et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.1 MB