We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
An abstract is not available for this content so a preview has been provided. Please use the Get access link above for information on how to access this content.
Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)
References
Ashenfelter, Orley (1989), How auctions work for wine and art, Journal of Economic Perspectives3, 23–36.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. (1986), Unnatural value : or art investment as floating crap game, American Economic Review76, 10–14.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. and Bowen, William G. (1966), Performing Arts. The Economic Dilemma, New York : Twentieth Century Fund.Google Scholar
Beggs, Alan and Graddy, Kathryn (1997), Declining value and the afternoon effect : Evidence from art auctions, Rand Journal of Economics28, 544–565.Google Scholar
Benhamou, Françoise (2000), L’économie de la culture, Paris : La Découverte.Google Scholar
Buelens, Nathalie and Ginsburgh, Victor (1993), Revisiting Baumol’s “Art investment as floating crap game”, European Economic Review37, 1351–1371.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. and Eichenberger, Reiner (1995), On the rate of return in the art market : Survey and evaluation, European Economic Review39, 529–537.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Weber, R. (1982), A theory of auctions and competitive bidding, Econometrica50, 1089–1122.Google Scholar
Pesando, James E. and Shum, Pauline S., Price anomalies at auction : Evidence from the market for modern prints, in Ginsburgh, Victor and Menger, Pierre-Michel, eds., Economics of the Arts. Selected Essays, Amsterdam : North-Holland.Google Scholar