Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T14:26:49.475Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Retirement in an overlapping generations model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Leon Bettendorf
Affiliation:
Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, Den Haag
Guido Pepermans
Affiliation:
School of Economics, Sint-Aloysius, Brussels, and Center for Economic Studies, University of Leuven
Get access

Summary

With an overlapping generations model, Williamson and Jones [1983] demonstrated that the long-run savings ratio in the U.S. was not affected by the introduction and the reform of the unfunded social security system. This paper extends their model by including a production sector, endogenous labor supply and a wage profile. Simulations show that incorporating general equilibrium and (exogenous) leisure is sufficient to generate a declining savings ratio in the steady state. Reforms of the social security system are evaluated in welfare terms. The new features of the model may significantly change the sign and the magnitude of the welfare gains for steady state generations.

Résumé

Résumé

En utilisant un modèle de générations imbriquées, Williamson et Jones [1983] ont démontré que le taux d'épargne de long terme aux USA n'est pas affecté par l'introduction et la réforme d'une sécurité sociale sans capitalisation. Cet article étend leur modèle en introduisant un secteur productif, une offre de travail endogène et un profil de salaire. Les simulations montrent que l'adoption d'une perspective d'équilibre général et l'introduction du loisir (exogène) suffisent à générer une baisse du taux d'épargne à l'équilibre. Les réformes du système d'assurance sociale sont évaluées en terme de bien être. Les nouvelles caractéristiques du modèle peuvent considérablement changer le signe et la grandeur des gains sociaux.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1997 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

(*)

The authors are obliged to F. Abraham, C. de Vries, M. Marchand, P. Pestieau, S. Proost, E. Schokkaert, F. Spinnewyn, D. Van de Gaer and P. Van Rompuy for their helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. Any errors are, of course, ours.

References

REFERENCES

Auerbach, A.J. and Kotlikoff, L.J. [1985], Simulating alternative social security responses to the demographic transition, National Tax Journal, 38(n°2),pp. 153168.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A.J. and Kotlikoff, L.J. [1987], Dynamic Fiscal Policy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A.J., Kotlikoff, L.J. Hagemann, R.P. and Nicoletti, G. [1989], The economic dynamics of an ageing population: The case of four OECD countries, OECD Working Papers, nr. 62.Google Scholar
Ballard, C.L. and Goulder, L.H. [1985], Consumption taxes, foresight and welfare : A computable general equilibrium analysis, in : Piggott, J. and Whalley, J. (eds.), New Developments in Applied General Equilibrium Models, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, pp. 253282.Google Scholar
Broer, D.P., Westerhout, E.W.M.T. and Bovenberg, A.L. [1994], Taxation, pensions and saving in a small open economy, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 96(3), pp. 403424.Google Scholar
Feldstein, M. [1974], Social security, induced retirement and aggregate capital accumulation, Journal of Political Economy, 82(n° 5), pp. 905926.Google Scholar
Ghez, G.R. and Becker, G.S. [1975], The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Lifecycle, Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Heckman, J. [1974], Life cycle consumption and labor supply: An explanation of the relationship between income and consumption over the life cycle, The American Economic Review, 64(n° 1), pp. 188194.Google Scholar
King, M.A. [1983], Welfare analysis of tax reforms using household data, Journal of Public Economics, 21(n° 2), pp. 183214.Google Scholar
King, R.G., Plosser, C.I. and Rebelo, S.T. [1988], Production, growth and business cycles, I: The basic neoclassical model, Journal of Monetary Economics, 21(n°2/3),pp. 195232.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, L.J. and Summers, L.H. [1981], The role of intergenerational transfers in aggregate capital accumulation, Journal of Political Economy, 89(n°4), pp. 706732.Google Scholar
Perelman, S. and Pestieau, P. [1984], The effect of social security on saving: The case of Belgium with a particular emphasis on the behaviour of the aged, Empirical Economics 2(1), pp. 1526.Google Scholar
Raffelhuschen, B. [1993], Funding social security through Pareto-optimal conversion policies, Journal of Economics, (Suppl.), pp. 105131.Google Scholar
Raffelhuschen, B. and Risa, A.E. [1995], Reforming social security in a small open economy, European Journal of Political Economy, ll(n°3), pp. 469485.Google Scholar
Smith, R.S. [1990], Factors affecting saving, policy tools, and tax reform: A review, IMF Staff Papers 37, pp. 170.Google Scholar
Williamson, S.H. and Jones, W.L. [1983], Computing the impact of social security using the life cycle consumption function, The American Economic Review, 73(n° 5), pp. 10361052.Google Scholar