Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T10:17:01.678Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The shop around the corner in the Internet age1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 January 2015

Get access

Summary

We study a spatial competition model which is a variant of the celebrated Hotelling (1929) framework. One of the firm is a brick-and-mortar one while the other is on-line. Both firms sell the same product except that (constant) marginal costs may differ. Consumers going to the shop around the corner face transportation costs according to their adress whereas on-line consumers bear a fix cost that may capture technological burden and risk premium. In the pricing Nash equilibria the “new economy” firm has smaller market shares eventhough it offers more attractive prices. For the on-line firm to become a leader, the cost difference must be large enough to offset the comparative disadvantage it face on the demand side. In the long run, increasing competition ultimately forces the local firm out of downtown. We argue that this effect may be related to some of the forecasts concerning the geographical impact of the development of remote access services.

Nous étudions un modèle de compétition spatiale inspiré de Hotelling (1929). L'une des firmes est localisée alors que l'autre est présente uniquement sur internet. Elles vendent le même produit et seuls les coûts marginaux – supposés constants – peuvent différer. Les clients de la firme traditionnelle supportent un coût de transport variable selon leur adresse, alors que les clients en ligne supportent un coût fixe qui peut rendre compte de difficultés d'accès à la technologie ou d'une prime de risque. Nous montrons que les équilibres de Nash en prix laissent une part de marché souvent faible à la firme en ligne, bien qu'elle pratique un prix plus bas. Il faut que les différences de coûts de production soient suffisamment importantes pour que la firme en ligne devienne leader. À long terme, nous montrons qu'il est optimal pour la firme traditionnelle de quitter le centre-ville si la concurrence d'Internet devient trop rude. Nous mettons cette prévision en relation avec les réflexions actuelles sur la place des technologies à distance dans le développement urbain.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2011 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

2

GREMARS, Université Lille 3

3

GREMARS, Université Lille 3 and CORE, Université Catholique de Louvain

1

We are grateful to François Nibart, Régis Renault, Isabel Grilo and Gérard Hamiache for very helpful comments on this work. Comments by the referees and the editor were especially helpful in improving the paper. All remaining errors are ours alone.

References

[1] d'Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J.J. and Thisse, J. (1979), “On Hotelling's “Stability in Competition”, Econometrica, 47, pp 11451150.Google Scholar
[2] Allen, F.A. and Santomero, A.M. (2001) “What do Financial Intermediaries do ?”, Journal of Banking and Finance, 21, pp. 271294.Google Scholar
[3] Bain, J.S. (1956), Barriers to new competition, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
[4] Balsubramanian, S. (1998), “Mail versus Mall: A strategic Analysis of Competition Between Direct Marketers and Conventional Retailers”, Marketing Science, 17, pp. 181195.Google Scholar
[5] Bouckaert, J. (2000), “Monopolistic Competition with a Mail Order Business”, Economics Letters, 66, pp.303310.Google Scholar
[6] Bouckaert, J. and Degryse, H. (1995), “Phonebanking”, European Economic Review, 39, pp. 229244.Google Scholar
[7] Brousseau, E. (2000), “Commerce électronique: ce que disent les chiffres et ce qu'il faudrait savoir”, Economie et Statistique, 339-340, pp. 147170.Google Scholar
[8] Degryse, H. (1996), “On the Interaction Between Vertical and Horizontal Product Differentiation: An Application to banking”, The Journal of Industrial Economics, 44, pp. 169185.Google Scholar
[9] European Commission (2000), “Commission proposal for the European Parliament and council directives on the taking up, the pursuit and the prudential supervision of the electronic money institutions”, http:\\europa.eu.int/comm/intemal_market/en/finances/general/1085en.pdf.Google Scholar
[10] Curien, N. and Oubejja, K. (1999), “Réseau multiservices: équilibres et dynamique”, Annales d'Economie et de statistique, 53, pp. 214228.Google Scholar
[11] Economides, N. (1996), “The Economies of Networks”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, pp. 673699.Google Scholar
[12] Glicksberg, I. L. (1952), “A Further Generalization of the Kakutani Fixed Point Theorem with Application to Nash Equilibrium Points”, Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 38, pp. 170174.Google Scholar
[13] Hotelling, H. (1929), “Stability in Competition”, Economic Journal, 39, pp. 4157.Google Scholar
[14] Kotkin, J. (2001) The New Geography: How the Digital Revolution is Reshaping the American Landscape, Random House, New York.Google Scholar
[16] Matutes, C. and Padilla, A.J. (1994), “Shared ATM Networks and Banking Competition”, European Economic Review, 38, pp. 10571069.Google Scholar
[17] Osborne, M. J. and Pitchik, C. (1987), “Equilibrium in Hotelling's Model of Spatial Competition”, Econometrica, 55, pp. 911922.Google Scholar