Hostname: page-component-745bb68f8f-f46jp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-01-07T18:31:33.222Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Framing effects on bribery behaviour: experimental evidence from China and Uganda

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2025

Alessio Gaggero*
Affiliation:
Nottingham University Business School, Nottingham, UK
Simon Appleton
Affiliation:
School of Economics, University of Nottingham, Ningbo, China
Lina Song
Affiliation:
Nottingham University Business School, Nottingham, UK
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In this study we investigate the effect of framing on bribery behaviour. To do this, we replicate Barr and Serra (Exp Econ, 12(4):488–503, (2009) and carry out a simple one-shot bribery game that mimics corruption. In one treatment, we presented the experiment in a framed version, in which wording was embedded with social context; in the other, we removed the social context and presented the game in a neutral manner. The contribution of this paper is that it offers a comparison of framing effects in two highly corrupt countries: China and Uganda. Our results provide evidence of strong and significant framing effects for Uganda, but not for China.

Type
Replication Paper
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Copyright
Copyright © 2018 The Author(s)

1 Introduction and motivation

In the last decades, there has been increasing interest in the effects of framing on decision making and experimental tasks. In particular, recent studies have reported the existence of significant framing effects in prisoner’s dilemma games (Ross and Ward, Reference Ross, Ward, Reed, Turiel and Brown1996; Liberman et al. Reference Liberman, Samuels and Ross2004), public goods games (Andreoni Reference Andreoni1995; Cookson Reference Cookson2000; Rege and Telle Reference Rege and Telle2004), and dictator games (Eckel and Grossman Reference Eckel and Grossman1996; Branas-Garza Reference Branas-Garza2007). There is little consensus among economists, however, on the existence of framing effects on bribery behaviour.

Abbink and Hennig-Schmidt (Reference Abbink and Hennig-Schmidt2006, AHS hereafter) first investigate whether, and to what extent, presenting a bribery game framed as a (repeated) corrupt exchange between a firm and a public official, as opposed to the same game framed neutrally and in abstract terms, would reduce bribery behaviour.Footnote 1 In the study, the authors find no evidence that loading the context of the instructions with an immoral ethical preconception has an effect on bribery behaviour, for a sample of students at the University of Bonn.

As argued by Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009), however, the obtained null results may be driven by either artificiality, in that participants did not identify themselves with either being a firm or a public official, or by the fact that the original AHS game was repeated for thirty rounds with fixed matching and hence also involved feelings of trust and reciprocity.Footnote 2 Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009) tackle these potential issues by designing a simple one-shot petty corruption experiment, in which participants interact with each other as ‘citizens’ and ‘officials.’ The main advantages of their setting are that (1) all students are citizens and, consequently, more likely to identify themselves with the frame adopted, and (2) in a one-shot game, feelings such as trust and reciprocity are negligible. Using a sample of students at the University of Oxford, the authors do find evidence of framing effects, and successfully show that the existence of a framing effect depends on the specific experimental design employed as well as the degree of artificiality of the corruption frame applied.

In this study, we contribute to the literature by replicating the Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009) petty corruption game in two highly corrupt countries, China and Uganda, currently ranked 77th and 151st out of 176 respectively in the Corruption Perception Index. In 2012, China initiated the largest campaign against graft and corruption ever made in the history of its Communist Party, leading to the indictment of over 120 high-ranking officials and 100,000 individuals. The latter, although its corruption level keeps worsening, still has not embraced any official anti-corruption campaign. Our results provide evidence of strong and significant framing effects for Uganda, but not for China.

2 Experimental design

The game includes 15 players. We randomly assigned players to three roles: private citizens, public officials, and other members of society (henceforth, ‘citizens’, ‘officials’, and ‘members of society’).

Each citizen is randomly matched with an official, and gets an initial endowment of I C . He has to decide whether to offer a bribe to the matched official for a corrupt service, for which he will obtain a benefit of V . Let B be a dummy variable that equals unity if the citizen chooses to offer a bribe, and let b { 1 , 2 , , 20 } denote the amount of the bribe offered. Notice, if the citizen decides to offer a bribe to the official, he will pay a (deterministic) cost, denoted K , which reflects the expected cost of getting caught and punished.

Each official receives an initial endowment of I O . He has to decide whether or not to accept the bribe offered by the matched citizen. Let A be a dummy variable which equals one if the official decides to accept the bribe. Similar to above, if the official accepts the bribe, he will also incur a deterministic loss, K , reflecting the expected cost of being caught.

Finally, each member of society receives an initial endowment of I M . They are a passive group, and as such do not make any decisions in the game. They will, however, incur a loss of endowment, h , each time a citizen-official pair chooses to act corruptly.

Let Y C , Y O , and Y M represent the final payoffs of the citizens, officials, and members of society, respectively, at the end of the bribery game. Thus, the payoff schedule for the three types of players can be written in the following compact form:

(1) Y C = I C if B = 0 I C - K if B = 1 and A = 0 I C + V - K - b if B = 1 and A = 1 ,
(2) Y O = I O if A = 0 I O + b - K if A = 1
(3) Y M = I M - N · h ,

where N { 0 , 1 , 2 , 3 , 4 , 5 } represents the number of citizen-officials pairs who successfully exchange bribes. Following the original paper, we set I C = I O = 35 money units and I M = 25 money units.Footnote 3 Further, we set V = 20 , h = 4 , and K = 5 . A total of 54 experimental sessions were conducted, 27 in each country.Footnote 4 Every session involved 15 players, with the exception of two sessions in China, in which we only managed to recruit 9 and 12 players, respectively. Table 1 presents demographic features of the sample of students, and reports that participants in China were younger and there was a higher proportion of females.Footnote 5 The sessions were conducted in various teaching and seminar rooms, depending on availability, and carried out with pen and paper. Participants were randomly allocated to their role, and at no time knew which player they were matched with. Besides the instructions, on each desk, participants found tables describing the payoff schedule of the game, and an envelope containing a specially designed form for players to express their preferences. In particular, citizens had to state the amount, if any, they wanted to offer to their matched official; officials, instead, had to state whether they would accept or reject each one of the possible bribes, b { 1 , 2 , , 20 } . This allows us to identify officials who would reject all of the possible bribes, as well as the minimum amount offered for the bribe to be accepted. Once all the forms were filled, envelopes were collected and payoffs calculated.

Table 1 Summary statistics

(1) China

(2) Uganda

(3) p value

Female

0.77 (0.424)

0.34 (0.474)

0.000

Years of age

21.45 (1.952)

23.87 (3.573)

0.000

Father years of schooling

11.82 (2.867)

10.82 (3.864)

0.000

Mother years of schooling

10.95 (3.326)

9.13 (4.198)

0.000

Observations

396

405

801

The table presents summary statistics of the experimental sample, comparing China and Uganda. Standard deviations in parenthesis

We had two treatments of the game. In the framed treatment, each role and action was embedded in the social context, as explained above. In the neutral treatment, however, we removed the social context and presented the game in an abstract manner. Specifically, player roles went from citizen, official, and member of society, to player A, player B, and player C, respectively; and the word “bribe” was replaced with the word “offer”. In each country, we randomly drew 14 sessions to be presented in the framed version, and the remaining in the neutral one.

Before presenting our result, it is important to mention the power of this replication. Accordingly, we follow the guidelines of Nikiforakis and Slonim (Reference Nikiforakis and Slonim2015) and Drichoutis et al. (Reference Drichoutis, Lusk and Nayga2015), and implement a power calculation for our study to find whether or not there is an effect statistically significant at the 5% level. Given our sample size, and the observed means and standard deviations in the original study of Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009), the power of our experiment is 99%.Footnote 6

3 Results

Table 2 reports the effect of framing on bribery behaviour. Specifically, in columns (1) and (2) we compare the behaviour under the neutral and framed treatments for the Chinese sample, and in column (3) we report the p value of a t-test which compares the means of the two groups. Similarly, in columns (4), (5), and (6), we report the same for the participants from Uganda. The table shows that framing had virtually no effect on the behaviour of participants in China. Whether the game was played in the neutral or in the framed version, an average of 4.6 successful bribes per session occurred, that is, citizens’ offers were successfully accepted by the randomly paired officials. The table shows that only a small proportion of Chinese students either did not offer any bribes (8%), or did not accept any possible bribes (2%). Similarly, framing had no effect on the conditional amount of bribes offered, nor accepted.

Table 2 Descriptive analysis

China

Uganda

(1) Neutral

(2) Framed

(3) p value

(4) Neutral

(5) Framed

(6) p value

Successful bribes per session private Citizen

4.62 (0.045)

4.61 (0.040)

0.715

4.46 (0.045)

3.42 (0.072)

0.000

Offered no bribe

0.08 (0.267)

0.06 (0.239)

0.715

0.11 (0.312)

0.31 (0.468)

0.003

Mean bribe offered

7.67 (3.439)

8.21 (3.038)

0.361

6.66 (6.192)

5.77 (4.660)

0.416

Public official

No acceptable bribes

0.02 (0.124)

0.04 (0.207)

0.336

0.05 (0.211)

0.20 (0.403)

0.007

Conditional mean acceptable offer

11.67 (3.904)

11.55 (3.433)

0.856

13.23 (4.107)

12.64 (4.201)

0.448

Observations

131

135

266

130

140

270

The table compares bribing behaviour of participants who played the bribery game in the framed and in the neutral treatment. Standard deviations in parenthesis

Conversely, framing had a strong and significant effect in Uganda. Specifically, students who played the bribery game in the framed form were significantly less likely to either offer or accept any bribe, and consequently, the number of successful bribes in framed sessions were significantly lower than in the neutral ones. The table, moreover, shows that while framing has a strong effect on the propensity to either offer or accept a bribe, it does not have an effect on the conditional amount offered nor on the conditional amount accepted.

In Tables 3 and 4, we check the robustness of our results in a regression framework that allows us to control for a set of potentially confounding variables, as well as allowing for interdependence within sessions by clustering. Specifically, Table 3 reports framing effects on the citizens, and in Table 4 we report estimated coefficients for the officials. The results confirm our descriptive analysis and show strong and significant framing effects for the sample from Uganda, and no significant effect for China. Further, in order to directly test whether there is a significant differential framing effect between the two countries, in Table 5, we conduct a regression analysis on the pooled data in which we include an interaction term combining the framing dummy variable together with the Uganda dummy variable. The table confirms a statistically significant differential framing effect for the private citizens in Uganda with respect to the private citizens in China, but reports no differential framing effect for the public officials between the two countries.

Table 3 Framing effects for private citizens

China

Uganda

(1) Offered no bribe

(2) Mean bribe offered

(3) Offered no bribe

(4) Mean bribe offered

Framed [0, 1]

− 0.067 (0.367)

0.524 (0.599)

0.727*** (0.266)

− 0.784 (1.081)

Covariates

Female

− 0.186 (0.431)

− 0.387 (0.727)

− 0.235 (0.277)

− 2.814** (1.144)

Years of age

− 0.164 (0.142)

− 0.010 (0.146)

− 0.025 (0.043)

0.028 (0.151)

Beijing

0.107 (0.557)

− 0.702 (0.816)

Chengdu

0.450 (0.543)

0.683 (0.835)

Kampala

− 0.016 (0.312)

1.269 (1.310)

Constant

1.886 (3.137)

8.216** (3.356)

− 0.524 (1.194)

6.057 (4.297)

Observations

132

124

133

104

The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Table 4 Framing effects for public officials

China

Uganda

(1) Accepted no bribe

(2) Minimum acceptable bribe

(3) Accepted no bribe

(4) Minimum acceptable bribe

Framed [0, 1]

0.473 (0.567)

0.230 (0.641)

0.947*** (0.335)

-0.071 (0.794)

Covariates

Female

− 1.034 (0.716)

− 0.438 (0.831)

− 0.214 (0.340)

− 0.469 (0.839)

Years of age

− 0.173 (0.131)

− 0.617*** (0.177)

− 0.058 (0.077)

0.119 (0.128)

Beijing

4.232 (702.133)

− 1.730* (0.876)

Chengdu

5.096 (702.133)

− 1.072 (0.918)

Kampala

0.563 (0.454)

1.930* (0.983)

Constant

− 2.421 (702.138)

26.115*** (4.028)

− 0.781 (2.009)

9.034** (3.577)

Observations

132

128

132

115

The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Table 5 Framing effects

Private citizen

Public official:

(1) Offered no bribe

(2) Offered no bribe

(3) Mean bribe offered

(4) Mean bribe offered

(5) Accepted no bribe

(6) Accepted no bribe

(7) Minimum acceptable bribe

(8) Minimum acceptable bribe

Framed [0, 1]

− 0.123 (0.320)

− 0.087 (0.343)

0.534 (0.481)

0.363 (0.499)

0.455 (0.508)

0.305 (0.468)

− 0.118 (0.687)

0.038 (0.673)

Uganda

0.195 (0.309)

0.344 (0.546)

− 1.017 (0.997)

− 3.085*** (1.032)

0.477 (0.510)

3.084*** (0.430)

1.554** (0.735)

− 1.013 (1.085)

Framed* Uganda

0.878** (0.406)

0.841** (0.412)

− 1.419 (1.358)

− 1.008 (1.308)

0.386 (0.629)

0.676 (0.594)

− 0.465 (1.064)

− 0.179 (1.005)

Covariates

Female

− 0.157 (0.229)

− 1.756*** (0.618)

− 0.303 (0.272)

− 0.216 (0.589)

Year of Enrolment

− 0.051 (0.133)

− 0.285 (0.328)

− 0.183 (0.156)

− 0.231 (0.254)

Beijing

0.196 (0.551)

− 0.385 (0.614)

3.513*** (0.618)

− 1.323 (0.826)

Chengdu

0.427 (0.476)

1.018 (0.725)

4.094*** (0.504)

− 0.953 (0.971)

Kampala

0.085 (0.301)

1.391 (1.010)

0.753** (0.315)

1.537* (0.778)

Constant

− 1.434*** (0.242)

− 1.453** (0.701)

7.672*** (0.414)

9.991*** (1.516)

− 2.160*** (0.385)

− 4.880*** (0.355)

11.672*** (0.513)

13.625*** (1.274)

Observations

266

266

229

229

264

264

243

243

The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

4 Discussion and conclusion

In this paper, we replicate Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009) one-shot petty corruption game, and compare framing effects between two countries with a high level of corruption: China and Uganda. We find strong and significant framing effects for the participants from Uganda. Specifically, students exposed to the framed version of the petty corruption game were significantly less likely to offer, as well as accept, any bribe. On the contrary, we do not find any significant effects of framing on bribery behaviour in China.

The results for Uganda are consistent with those obtained by Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009); however, this is not the case for China, suggesting other factors might be causing the differences in framing effects between the two countries. Following Cooper et al. (Reference Cooper, Kagel, Lo and Gu1999) and Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2010), the magnitude of the framing effect may change depending on the degree participants have been exposed to a corrupt environment, as well as on the social norms and values prevailing in a certain society. For example, it is likely that in a society with a higher exposure to corruption, in which people engage in bribery in their everyday life, individuals would be less responsive to the corruption frame. As both China and Uganda have high levels of corruption, it is not obvious that differences in the degree of corruption in the two countries explain our result. Indeed, our results are somewhat paradoxical: Transparency International’s data (based on perceptions by elites and business people) suggest Uganda has higher levels of corruption than China. Uganda certainly lacks China’s fierce official anti-corruption drive. However, our Ugandan subjects are more sensitive to framing the experiment in terms of corruption than their Chinese counterparts. Nor is there clear evidence that corruption is more socially acceptable in China than Uganda. Indeed, in the World Values Survey, Chinese citizens were less likely to agree that “it was justifiable that someone accepts a bribe in the course of their duties”. On scale of 1 = never justifiable to 10 = always justifiable, China averaged 1.20 in 1995 while Uganda averaged 2.14 in 2001—the latest years available (Inglehart et al. Reference Inglehart, Haerpfer, Moreno, Welzel, Kizilova, Diez-Medrano, Lagos, Norris, Ponarin and Puranen2014; Gatti et al. Reference Gatti, Paternostro and Rigolini2003).

Further research is necessary to explain our results. This may be a case where there is a disconnect between the attitudes people espouse in public opinion surveys and their behaviour in private games. One may disapprove of something in public—particularly when done by others—but engage in it personally in private. China has a culture of Guanxi (or personal relations) in business that can involve gift giving which potentially strays into corruption (Zhan Reference Zhan2012). For example, the government has recently cracked down on lavish banquets by public officials. A 2014 Pew survey of public attitudes found 38% of Chinese respondents thought bribery was important for getting ahead—the highest proportion in all the countries in the world and ahead of the 15% average for the African countries in the sample (which included Uganda, but the country specific figure was not available, Gao, Reference Gao2014). Potentially related to this, corruption has sometimes been seen by economists as “greasing the wheels” of economic development in China by substituting for private property rights and the rule of law. For example, Qian (Reference Qian and Rodrik2003) argues that the incentivising cadres was the key to successful reform in China: local officials would encourage the development of publicly or collectively owned enterprises because they received a private share of the benefits (sometimes through corruption). Conversely, economists studying Uganda (and indeed the rest of Africa), tend to view corruption unequivocally a barrier to economic development, raising the costs of doing business, undermining government services, private property rights and the rule of law (Godfrey and Yu Reference Godfrey and Yu2014). Future research to understand better private behaviour regarding corruption may be very important for policy, as anti-graft campaigns may not be successful if citizens do not adhere to the expected norms against corruption.

Acknowledgements

We thank Thorsten Chmura, Roberto Hernan Gonzalez, Simona Demel, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. Special thanks to Abigail Barr for the help during the initial stages of the project, and for providing the necessary experimental scripts. Financial support of the Economic and Social Research Council [ES/M004333/1] is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendix

See Tables 6 and 7.

Table 6 Comparison

China

Uganda

Barr and Serra

(1) Neutral

(2) Framed

(3) Diff.

(4) Neutral

(5) Framed

(6) Diff.

(7) Neutral

(8) Framed

(9) Diff.

No bribe offered

0.08 (0.267)

0.06 (0.239)

0.02 (0.044)

0.11 (0.312)

0.31 (0.468)

− 0.21 (0.069)

0.10 (0.305)

0.40 (0.497)

− 0.30 (0.104)

No acceptable bribes

0.02 (0.124)

0.04 (0.207)

− 0.03 (0.030)

0.05 (0.211)

0.20 (0.403)

− 0.15 (0.056)

0.10 (0.305)

0.26 (0.443)

− 0.16 (0.096)

Observations

131

135

266

130

140

270

30

35

65

The table compares results of our experimental sample with those of Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009). Standard deviations in parenthesis

Table 7 Framing effects

Private citizen

Public official

(1) Offered no bribe

(2) Offered no bribe

(3) Mean bribe offered

(4) Mean bribe offered

(5) Accepted no bribe

(6) Accepted no bribe

(7) Minimum acceptable bribe

(8) Minimum acceptable bribe

Framed [0, 1]

0.59.3* (0.307)

0.616** (0.314)

− 0.235 (1.236)

− 0.476 (1.251)

0.814** (0.324)

0.815** (0.355)

− 0.683 (0.780)

− 0.407 (0.694)

Female

− 0.263 (0.334)

− 0.098 (0.376)

− 0.990 (0.787)

− 1.777** (0.852)

− 0.498 (0.368)

− 0.332 (0.479)

− 1.288 (0.808)

− 0.394 (0.816)

Framed* female

− 0.249 (0.401)

− 0.207 (0.392)

0.415 (1.309)

0.336 (1.281)

− 0.087 (0.439)

0.014 (0.458)

0.673 (1.048)

0.488 (0.954)

Covariates

Year of Enrolment

− 0.108 (0.118)

0.044 (0.309)

− 0.204 (0.136)

− 0.110 (0.226)

Beijing

− 0.411 (0.470)

1.437* (0.731)

0.079 (0.556)

− 0.738 (0.785)

Chengdu

− 0.209 (0.339)

2.799*** (0.804)

0.604 (0.505)

− 0.426 (0.920)

Kampala

0.216 (0.295)

0.078 (1.049)

0.820*** (0.303)

1.168* (0.684)

Constant

− 1.231*** (0.246)

− 0.991* (0.553)

7.714*** (0.843)

7.246*** (1.435)

− 1.668*** (0.277)

− 1.697*** (0.493)

13.150*** (0.570)

12.763*** (0.900)

Observations

266

266

229

229

264

264

243

243

The table presents regression estimates of the effect of framing on corruption behaviour. Probit models were estimated if the dependent variable was dichotomous [0, 1]. Standard errors in parenthesis are clustered at the session level * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Footnotes

1 The game was first designed by Abbink et al. (Reference Abbink, Irlenbusch and Renner2002).

2 See Bardsley (Reference Bardsley2005) for a discussion of artificiality in experimental economics.

3 This difference in initial endowments reflects the fact that other members of the society do not usually have the means to engage in corrupt behaviour.

4 In order to increase the representativeness of our samples, experiments were carried out in Kampala and Jinja, in Uganda, and Beijing, Ningbo, and Chengdu in China.

5 It is important to emphasise that regression analysis can only partially account for this important difference in composition of men and women across countries. In order to dispel potential issues, in Table 7 in the “Appendix”, we check for the possibility of a composition effect, but this does not seem to be the case.

6 Table 6 in the “Appendix” compares our experimental results with those of Barr and Serra (Reference Barr and Serra2009).

References

Abbink, K., Hennig-Schmidt, H. (2006). Neutral versus loaded instructions in a bribery experiment. Experimental Economics, 9(2), 103121. 10.1007/s10683-006-5385-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., Renner, E. (2002). An Experimental Bribery Game. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organisation, 18(2), 428454. 10.1093/jleo/18.2.428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (1995). Warm-glow versus cold-prickle: the effects of positive and negative framing on cooperation in experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 121. 10.2307/2118508CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, N. (2005). Experimental economics and the artificiality of alteration. Journal of Economic Methodology, 12(2), 239251. 10.1080/13501780500086115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barr, A., Serra, D. (2009). The effects of externalities and framing on bribery in a petty corruption experiment. Experimental Economics, 12(4), 488503. 10.1007/s10683-009-9225-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barr, A., Serra, D. (2010). Corruption and culture: an experimental analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 94(11–12), 862869. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2010.07.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Branas-Garza, P. (2007). Promoting helping behavior with framing in dictator games. Journal of Economic Psychology, 28(4), 477486. 10.1016/j.joep.2006.10.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cookson, R. (2000). Framing effects in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 3, 5579. 10.1023/A:1009994008166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, B. D. J., Kagel, J. H., Lo, W. E. I., Gu, Q. L. (1999). Gaming against managers in incentive systems: experimental results with Chinese Students and Chinese Managers. The American Economic Review, 89(4), 781804. 10.1257/aer.89.4.781CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drichoutis, A. C., Lusk, J. L., Nayga, R. M. Jr. (2015). The veil of experimental currency units in second price auctions. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 182196. 10.1007/s40881-015-0014-2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckel, C. C., Grossman, Ph J. (1996). Altruism in anonymous dictator games. Games and Economic Behavior, 16, 181191. 10.1006/game.1996.0081CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gao, G. (2014). Where people say giving bribes gets you ahead in life, Pew Research Center. http://www.pewresearch.org/fact-tank/2014/10/23/where-people-say-giving-bribes-gets-you-ahead-in-life/.Google Scholar
Gatti, R., Paternostro, S., Rigolini, J. (2003). Individual attitudes toward corruption: do social effects matter? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3122, Washington DC: The World Bank 10.1596/1813-9450-3122Google Scholar
Godfrey, M., Yu, P. J. (2014). Patronage driven corruption undermining the fight against poverty in Uganda. African Social Science Review, 7(1), 5469.Google Scholar
Inglehart, R., Haerpfer, C., Moreno, A., Welzel, C., Kizilova, K., Diez-Medrano, J., Lagos, M., Norris, P., Ponarin, E., Puranen, B. et al., (2014). World Values Survey: Round Four - Country-Pooled Datafile Version: ww.worldvaluessurvey.org/WVSDocumentationWV4.jsp, Madrid: JD Systems Institute.Google Scholar
Liberman, V., Samuels, S., Ross, L. (2004). The name of the game: predictive power of reputations vs. situational labels in determining prisoner’s dilemma game moves. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 30, 11751185. 10.1177/0146167204264004CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nikiforakis, N., Slonim, R. (2015). Editors’ preface: statistics, replications and null results. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1, 127131. 10.1007/s40881-015-0018-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Y., & Rodrik, Dani. (2003). How reform worked in China In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, Princeton: Princeton University Press 297333.Google Scholar
Rege, M., Telle, K. (2004). The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public goods situations. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 16251644. 10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00021-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, L., Ward, A., & Reed, E. S., Turiel, E., Brown, T. (1996). Naive realism in everyday life: implications for social conflict and misunderstanding Values and knowledge, Mahwah: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates 103135.Google Scholar
Zhan, J. V. (2012). Filling the gap of formal institutions: the effects of Guanxi network on corruption in reform-era China. Crime, Law and Social Change, 58(2), 93109. 10.1007/s10611-012-9379-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1 Summary statistics

Figure 1

Table 2 Descriptive analysis

Figure 2

Table 3 Framing effects for private citizens

Figure 3

Table 4 Framing effects for public officials

Figure 4

Table 5 Framing effects

Figure 5

Table 6 Comparison

Figure 6

Table 7 Framing effects