Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T19:09:58.896Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A behavioral approach to personalizing public health

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 July 2020

KAI RUGGERI*
Affiliation:
Columbia University, Mailman School of Public Health, Department of Health Policy and Management, New York, NY, USA
AMEL BENZERGA
Affiliation:
Columbia University, Mailman School of Public Health, Department of Health Policy and Management, New York, NY, USA Sciences Po Paris, School of Public Affairs, Paris, France
SANNE VERRA
Affiliation:
Columbia University, Mailman School of Public Health, Department of Health Policy and Management, New York, NY, USA Department of Interdisciplinary Social Science, Utrecht University, Utrecht, The Netherlands
TOMAS FOLKE
Affiliation:
Columbia University, Mailman School of Public Health, Department of Health Policy and Management, New York, NY, USA
*
*Correspondence to: Columbia University, Mailman School of Public Health, Health Policy and Management Department,722 W 168th St., New York, NY 10032, USA. E-mail: dr2946@cumc.columbia.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Behavioral policies are increasingly popular in a number of health care contexts. However, evidence of their effectiveness, specifically in low-income and highly disadvantaged populations, is limited. Some positive effects have been found for adaptive interventions, which merge more personalized approaches with advances in data collection and modern analytical methods. These approaches have only recently become feasible, as their implementation requires a confluence of large-scale datasets, contemporary machine learning, and validated behavioral insights. Such methods have considerable potential to improve outcomes without requiring substantial increases in effort on the part of individuals. Using examples from health insurance choice, clinical attendance rates, and prescription of medicines, we present an argument for how adaptive approaches, especially those considering disadvantaged populations explicitly, offer an opportunity to generate equity in public health.

Type
New Voices
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press

Introduction

The trend of applying behavioral insights to clinical settings and population health (King et al., Reference King, Greaves, Vlaev and Darzi2013) is not likely to fade anytime soon (Patel et al., Reference Patel, Volpp and Asch2018). Nor should it, given the impacts shown to date and possibilities for future initiatives (King et al., Reference King, Greaves, Vlaev and Darzi2013; Patel et al., Reference Patel, Volpp and Asch2018). While nudges that seek to implement small changes in the choice architecture are certainly the most popular tool (Hertwig & Grüne-Yanoff, Reference Hertwig and Grüne-Yanoff2017), other behavioral tools are increasingly relevant in public health. Boosts, another popular tool, are interventions that aid individuals in understanding the consequences of their choices, particularly when there is no evident or universal optimal decision or preference (Hertwig & Grüne-Yanoff, Reference Hertwig and Grüne-Yanoff2017). Boosts such as providing simple calculators for investment decisions (Kuhnen, Reference Kuhnen2015) or for choosing optimal insurance plans encourage deliberation to enhance competency and resilience to deal with future decisions (Franklin et al., Reference Franklin, Folke and Ruggeri2019). When effective, such interventions as nudges and boosts generally come at low implementation costs (Chaiyachati et al., Reference Chaiyachati2018), making them appealing to attempt in low-resource settings.

Evidence on nudges and boosts is compelling in a general population (Kuhnen Reference Kuhnen2015; Franklin et al., Reference Franklin, Folke and Ruggeri2019), yet their effectiveness for improving health outcomes in low-income populations is limited and the evidence is inconclusive (Chaiyachati et al., Reference Chaiyachati2018). This lack of conclusive results is caused both by the absence of evidence for behavioral interventions in low-income populations, as well as the occasional evidence of absence of the effectiveness of specific interventions that have been shown to work in other less vulnerable populations (Mullainathan & Shafir, Reference Mullainathan and Shafir2013; Allmark & Tod, Reference Allmark and Tod2014). One way to correct this may be through the personalization of behavioral approaches that increase efficacy and efficiency. This increases uptake by implementing interventions that reach those individuals who stand to benefit the most. For example, Franklin et al. (Reference Franklin, Folke and Ruggeri2019) recently compared nudges and boosts in a series of controlled experiments, and concluded that interventions have different effects based on individual behavioral patterns and circumstances. As we describe later, similar conclusions have been reached in real-world settings, indicating opportunities to maximize impact, avoid past mistakes or target the most critical groups.

A personalized strategy is distinct in that classical population approaches apply evenly and can result in inequitable outcomes. Personalized strategies consider inequities at the outset, aiming for equitable results. Consider a standard recommendation for employees to save 20% of their salary every month – although it as an even recommendation, it produces uneven outcomes. These potentially produce negative impacts for individuals who could be in a better financial position by paying down debt faster (i.e., saving less in the near term) or for individuals who may have fewer remaining working years and should therefore increase savings while still able to generate income.

Alternatively, a personalized approach begins with calibration based on individual circumstances (e.g., age, income, living in an urban or rural area), seeking an equitable result in spite of initial inequities. Such approaches align well with widespread interest in ‘personalized medicine’ in health care. Personalized medicine involves treatment plans based on individual patient characteristics and stage of illness, instead of offering the same treatment to all (Alyass et al., Reference Alyass, Turcotte and Meyre2015). To illustrate the benefits of moving from standard to personalized approaches, we briefly summarize three cases of current issues in health care: no-show rates, suboptimal insurance choices, and the overprescription of medication. While these examples are set in the context of US health care, the underlying behavioral aspects apply widely. We then explain the practice of personalization and discuss features leading to implementation and why the time is right to expand this approach.

Reducing no-shows

Missed appointments (‘no-shows’) in primary care represent a universal behavioral issue faced by health systems (Aggrawal et al., Reference Aggarwal, Davies and Sullivan2016). Dantas et al. (Reference Dantas, Fleck, Cyrino Oliveira and Hamacher2018) estimated that as many as 23.5% of all medical appointments in North America are missed. Among low-income populations in Federally Qualified Health Centers in the USA, the no-show rate becomes as high as 45% (Cruz et al., Reference Cruz, Gawrys, Thompson, Mejia, Rosul and Lazar2018). Such rates strain community health centers with limited resources (Kangovi et al., Reference Kangovi, Barg, Carter, Long, Shannon and Grande2013).

Text message reminders represent a common intervention to encourage attendance, with one systematic review finding them responsible for a 29% reduction in no-shows (Hasvold & Wootton, Reference Hasvold and Wootton2011). This benefit does not seem to extend to disadvantaged groups (Bellucci et al., Reference Bellucci, Dharmasena, Nguyen and Calache2017; Ruggeri et al., Reference Ruggeri, Folke, Benzerga, Verra, Büttner, Steinbeck, Yee and Chaiyachati2020a), suggesting that forgetting, though a common cause of no-shows generally (Kaplan-Lewis & Perac-Loma, Reference Kaplan-Lewis and Perac-Lima2013), is not the main barrier that low-income individuals face. Another barrier to attendance for low-income populations is transportation, with 24–51% reporting this as a reason for no-shows (Chaiyachati et al., Reference Chaiyachati2018). This is a barrier across rural and urban settings, even when within close proximity to public transport (Chaiyachati et al., Reference Chaiyachati2018). Chaiyachati et al. (Reference Chaiyachati2018) attempted to address this by offering low-income patients in Philadelphia free transportation to and from appointments through a ride-sharing platform. While all of the pieces seemed to be in place, minimal utilization resulted in little to no actual effect of the intervention.

Insurance choice

Whereas attendance behaviors can vary over time, insurance choices are a periodic decision with medium-term implications for receiving care as well as long-term implications for health and well-being. However, insurance behaviors tend to propagate and exploit the effects of inertia (Handel, Reference Handel2013): once enrolled in an insurance plan, individuals are often very unlikely to change it, even if that plan is not the optimal choice (Baicker et al., Reference Baicker, Congdon and Mullainathan2012). Complexity of information, considerable uncertainty around health outcomes, severity of the risks involved, and the lag time between choice and outcome can all magnify this effect. This comes with private costs in terms of needlessly high premiums and collective costs as it leads to a less efficient insurance market.

Attempting to increase the uptake of optimal plans, Ericson et al. (Reference Ericson, Kingsdale, Layton and Sacarny2017) sent three different e-mails (control, generic, and personalized) to marketplace consumers in Colorado, excluding the most price-sensitive individuals enrolled in the lowest-cost plans. In spite of salient messaging about the savings that could be realized through better insurance choices, the intervention had only a minimal impact: participants were more likely to click on the link for the behaviorally designed emails, but there was no effect on actual change in plan selection.

Drug prescription

Overprescription is a major threat to public health and the sustainability of health care systems (Sacarny et al., Reference Sacarny, Yokum, Finkelstein and Agrawal2016). As thorough investigations on prescription behavior are time-consuming and expensive to carry out (Sacarny et al., Reference Sacarny, Yokum, Finkelstein and Agrawal2016), low-cost alternatives, such as nudges and boosts, are increasingly being utilized. One intervention that has shown some promise in relation to antibiotics is the use of a descriptive social norm, which informs overprescribers of the (lower) base rate of prescription and how their own behavior deviates from it. However, when Sacarny et al. (Reference Sacarny, Yokum, Finkelstein and Agrawal2016) applied this to the top 0.2% of opioid prescribers, no significant impact was found. While targeting was used in terms of focusing on the population of high opioid prescribers, no immediate context was integrated into the letters.

Opportunities to adapt

Not all behavioral interventions work (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2017), yet lessons from the unsuccessful trials as presented here are invaluable for improving the application of behavioral insights. The key take-away from these examples is the need to align behaviorally informed interventions with personal circumstances, needs, and the immediate environment (Chaiyachati et al., Reference Chaiyachati2018; Ruggeri et al., Reference Ruggeri, Folke, Benzerga, Verra, Büttner, Steinbeck, Yee and Chaiyachati2020a). In other words, in order to optimize behavioral interventions, they may need to be personalized. This is an important development, given that policy has classically focused on either high-risk strategies (i.e., an emphasis on where issues exist or are likely) or population strategies (i.e., no specific target group).

Population-based interventions can be successful when the problem targeted affects everyone in the community where the policy is implemented, such as regulations that ensure drinking water quality (Rose, Reference Rose2001), apply a sugar tax on soft drinks (Roberto et al., Reference Roberto2019) or enforce noise thresholds near airports (Zafari et al., Reference Zafari, Jiao, Will, Li and Muenning2018). These can have widespread benefits for health equity: whereas unhealthy individuals may benefit the most from cleaner drinking water, healthy individuals also benefit. However, even when generally successful, these interventions can backfire: not every home can insulate against noise, and some individuals can drive to another town to purchase soda at a lower cost. Similarly, a flat charge on plastic bags – or even an outright ban on single-use plastics – can drastically reduce the number of bags used while also creating uneven effects for those who genuinely need them for survival, or they can simply be offset by using another form of plastic (Taylor, Reference Taylor2019).

These hypothetical illustrations are intended to present extremes, though the most common outcome is the absence of any noteworthy impact, as indicated in the three case examples of no-shows, insurance choice, and drug prescription. Such null effects might be avoided by adopting and adapting more context-aware interventions. Consider features of insurance choices (Baicker et al., Reference Baicker, Congdon and Mullainathan2012): each plan has a different form of coverage, deductibles, and co-payments that will eventually sum up as total household health care spending. There is considerable heterogeneity for each of those factors within a population. There is also temporal heterogeneity (i.e., individual circumstances can improve, worsen or remain the same, all at differing levels), as well as uncertainty regarding future health care needs. While choice algorithms offer major benefits for avoiding suboptimal choice (Sunstein, Reference Sunstein2019), algorithms naive to individual circumstances lack the flexibility to incorporate all of the relevant variability (i.e., a measure such as body mass index, which applies population-level assumptions about the link between body mass and health, can be very misleading at the individual level).

Based on underwhelming findings for the intervention aimed at reducing unnecessary prescriptions, Sacarny et al. (Reference Sacarny, Barnett, Le Pharm, Tetkoski, Yokum and Agrawal2018) recommended a different approach. Rather than assume a single norm would have a common utility, they recommend targeting norms toward those who actually needed information, such as providers who had less training on opioids. Taking this approach, Sacarny et al. (Reference Sacarny, Barnett, Le Pharm, Tetkoski, Yokum and Agrawal2018) found an 11% decrease in prescriptions. Similarly, the authors of the Philadelphia trial for attendance noted that they could have more specifically focused on those who needed transportation, and then focused on effects at the margins (critical for many nudges), rather than at the means. By applying their approach to the full population, this limited the chance of showing an overall effect, given that the full population may not have missed their appointments due to transportation issues.

The state of Maine attempted to implement intelligent targeting techniques to assign dual-eligible Medicare–Medicaid individuals to optimal prescription drug insurance plans. This replaced assigning random defaults, which was done in a few states (Medicare Rights Center, 2006). In this trial, the default option assigned to each individual was designed to match their individual health care and medication needs. Through tailoring, this increased individual coverage of necessary medications to 90–100% across all plans in Maine (Medicare Rights Center, 2006). By contrast, in states that suggested random defaults, one in five dual-eligible individuals ended up with plans that did not cover one or more of their prescriptions and therefore discontinued medication (West et al., Reference West2007).

Effective personalization requires better understanding of the barriers and levers to changes in optimal behaviors. Drivers of behavior are multifaceted, involving individual factors such as dispositions, abilities, and preferences, as well as external factors that are more or less stable over time. For example, in the case of no-shows, the most frequently referenced factors involve miscommunication (Kaplan-Lewis & Perac-Lima, Reference Kaplan-Lewis and Perac-Lima2013), forgetting (Kaplan-Lewis & Perac-Lima, Reference Kaplan-Lewis and Perac-Lima2013), and logistic and financial barriers (such as transportation issues and childcare; Starbird et al., Reference Starbird, DiMaina, Sun and Han2019). These are also compounded by emotional barriers such as anxiety, depression, and fear (Cook et al., Reference Cook, Selig, Wedge and Gohn-Baube1999; DuMontier et al., Reference DuMontier, Rindfleisch, Pruszynski and Frey2013). On top of this, a lack of perceived respect in primary care (DuMontier et al., Reference DuMontier, Rindfleisch, Pruszynski and Frey2013) may play a part. The examples provided here, which largely rely on informational features, may be sensitive to individual differences in literacy and numeracy, as well as in state and trait variability in executive function. These create additional barriers for vulnerable people because of how the challenges they face increase their baseline cognitive load (Moffitt et al., Reference Moffitt, Arseneault, Belsky, Dickson, Hancox, Harrington, Houts, Poulton, Roberts, Ross and Sears2011; Marteau et al., Reference Marteau, Hollands and Fletcher2012). Any number of these factors may be present for a given case; knowing which to target is a key challenge, which is even more complex in a disadvantaged population (Bellucci, Reference Bellucci, Dharmasena, Nguyen and Calache2017).

Combination is key

When it comes to complex behavioral problems, particularly among disadvantaged populations, the most effective interventions should combine population approaches that target general causes with personalization that targets individualized, context-dependent factors (Pence et al., Reference Pence2018). In many cases, this is in direct response to the rule that those doing best in a population are more similar and those at greatest risk are more varied (King et al., Reference King, Greaves, Vlaev and Darzi2013; Ruggeri et al., Reference Ruggeri, Garcia-Garzon, Maguire, Matz and Huppert2020b). To be absolutely explicit, we do not make any argument that one approach should replace another. On the contrary: personalization in this context means to capitalize on the most effective aspects of each approach, but in a realistic way, with incremental improvements.

Consider interventions that influence choices about health insurance plans. First, there is substantial legislation in place, particularly regarding enrollment periods. Next, there are many forms of communication that encourage individuals and families to evaluate options and nudge them to assess whether their current or default plan is appropriate. These typically involve salient messages along with norms such as average costs or savings, combined with simplification and chunking features. Moving beyond such standardized approaches, there is the option to calculate direct costs and probabilities relative to income, residence, and employment. This is a form of boosting that is inherently personal and goes beyond a generic algorithm. At this stage, we have mandated some behavior with legislation, encouraged engagement in the process through nudging and enhanced context-specific deliberation with boosting, all without adding substantial effort on the part of the decision-maker. It would even be possible to incorporate a default at this stage, which might require opting out of an optimal plan to return to the current one.

But how ‘smart’ can policies be? Addressing this challenge requires three features: first, better data collection methods that can effectively gather information relating to the presence of barriers and levers for behavior; second, stronger analytic techniques that can effectively link each behavior profile with the intervention that is most likely to work for them; and third, and perhaps most challenging, an appropriate platform for implementation, as not every intervention has an available medium to reach its intended audience.

To illustrate, an adaptive, personalized intervention for no-shows fundamentally requires data beyond clinical attendance rates. Extensive information is necessary about the nature of each appointment (e.g., patient, provider, location, context, costs), barriers to attendance, and, ideally, information about previous no-shows (e.g., through surveys). This wealth of data provides a perfect use case for machine learning classification methods, as these methods have the potential to improve predictive accuracy given sufficiently large datasets. Rather than only looking at mean or modal behaviors (such as the most common patient groups to no-show), more intensive models consider combinations of factors that can be used to allocate individuals to interventions, as depicted in Figure 1. But this is also not an end point; as demonstrated, even ideally placed interventions can have limited or no effects.

Figure 1. Personalizing nudges as a more efficient lever for behavior change. Top pathway: generic intervention (reminders) effective for the majority of individuals within and between groups. Further intervention (transportation) offered to those who did not attend, but minimal benefit is visible apart from one group (older individuals), for whom the method addresses a need or barrier. Bottom pathway: those who did not attend after the generic intervention receive personalized nudges, increasing efficacy within each group as well as in aggregate.

Note: The figure has been created by the authors of this article. It has been posted on a website introducing this research topic: https://datascience.columbia.edu/nudging-new-york-using-data-science-increase-healthcare-access-underserved-communities.

Machine learning methods can be applied to make interventions more adaptive: where seemingly optimal interventions fail, individuals can be reallocated to other interventions to test for greater effectiveness, improving model accuracy and utility over time. To consolidate, we recommend testing the value of personalized approaches using four discrete steps:

  1. (1) Identify primary barriers for the desired behavior.

  2. (2) Develop interventions targeting specific barriers.

  3. (3) Stratify interventions and combinations of interventions by applying directly to those groups with relevant barriers.

  4. (4) Where relevant, incorporate personalization features, such as calculators or algorithms that utilize user data.

The biggest challenge involves how and where to implement. For insurance choices, web portals where individuals make choices are natural platforms. As is increasingly common, these can include multiple behaviorally informed features on the path from portal entry to final selection. Back-end, adaptive algorithms that incorporate various data entered by users are relatively simple to implement. Similar techniques can be applied in many financial contexts, given the prevalence of online banking.

Less obvious is how to implement adaptive attendance interventions at individual clinic levels, where it is impractical to allocate these functions to administrative staff on a perpetual basis. Such complex targeting schemes may primarily be relevant to larger institutions, where small increases in the preferred behavior offer a clear return on investment, as well as the resources that already include patient communication platforms. Smaller clinics or provider networks that lack capacity may find that their datasets are too small and that the cost of entry is too high, with too little return. For those providers, it may be more efficient to focus on generic interventions or to design special interventions for those patients at greatest risk of negative health outcomes.

Personalization in the extreme sense of customized interventions for each individual is not always feasible. Our argument is for a relative increase in personalization that increases the likelihood of benefit for disadvantaged populations, leading to greater impact of interventions that are continuously improved. This is possible in an era of low-cost computing power and massive self-generating datasets. Combined, these two factors have led to rapid decreases in the cost of effective intervention targeting and evaluation, to the point where it might now be cost-efficient for policymakers in most developed countries. Adding to this momentum is the fact that the political will currently exists to pilot these types of approaches.

Platforms that incorporate machine learning can enable stronger personalization while concurrently providing methods to learn more effectively from previous trials, generating a positive-feedback loop (e.g., the success of targeted health insurance defaults in Maine could be further amplified if outcomes from previous years would feed into future recommendations). This would allow for a direct assessment of the heavily speculated value of machine learning in public health.

Intelligent targeting should also offer equity in social challenges, as the examples used allude to how the most vulnerable individuals often do not benefit from generic or population-focused interventions. By ensuring intervention relevance for the majority as well as relevant subpopulations, greater effects can be seen across diverse communities. Ultimately, this facilitates behavioral interventions to make impacts in the margins as well as at the means. Doing so results in entire population shifts toward the positive end, which is the ultimate goal of policy.

In the context of health care, personalization would allow disadvantaged individuals to access a set of interventions that address each of their core barriers to entry, without necessitating resources being offered to everyone or reducing those in place more generally. In simpler terms, personalized approaches take nothing away from anyone, and only seek to offer policy equity to diverse populations.

Limitations

Personalization is not always possible or appropriate. The extent to which the effectiveness of behavioral interventions generalizes differs widely between interventions. For example, electronically delivered nudges and boosts are much easier to personalize than interventions that require actions directly in a physical environment (e.g., recycling, wearing a facemask). In Table 1, we present a simple classification tool for when personalization may be more or less valuable or feasible for complementing behavioral interventions.

Table 1. Differentiating interventions based on value and feasibility of personalization.

Recent taxonomies of behavioral interventions may help to determine when personalization is feasible and appropriate (Johnson et al., Reference Johnson, Shu, Dellaert, Fox, Goldstein, Häubl, Larrick, Payne, Peters, Schkade and Wansink2012; Münscher et al., Reference Münscher, Vetter and Scheuerle2016; Hollands et al., Reference Hollands, Bignardi, Johnston, Kelly, Ogilvie, Petticrew, Prestwich, Shemilt, Sutton and Marteau2017). As the field has not yet converged on a common standard, these framework examples provide a promising starting point, and it may become worthwhile to explicitly include a dimension relating to the necessity and feasibility of personalization. In any case, personalization should not be a class on its own, but rather a complementary tool, in the sense that the interventions are the actions and personalization is the adverb.

Conclusion

There is sufficient evidence to support behaviorally informed interventions such as nudges and boosts as low-cost options for addressing a number of challenges. It is now critical to improve methods of implementation in the form of adaptive, personalized models, which may very well be the next frontier in behavioral research. This offers potential to go from isolated marginal effects to meaningful cumulative impacts by ensuring value directly to the individuals and communities that benefit most. By expanding the benefits to a wider number of individuals, this results in more substantial impacts on population health and well-being.

Acknowledgment

The authors acknowledge indirect support from the Data Science Institute at Columbia University as well as Dr Susan Yee at Community Healthcare Network.

Disclaimer

The authors received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

References

Aggarwal, A., Davies, J. and Sullivan, R. (2016), ‘“Nudge” and the epidemic of missed appointments: Can behavioural policies provide a solution for missed appointments in the health service?J Health Organ Manag, 30(4): 558564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allmark, P. and Tod, A. M. (2014), ‘Can a nudge keep you warm? Using nudges to reduce excess winter deaths: insight from the Keeping Warm in Later Life Project (KWILLT)’, Journal of Public Health, 36(1): 111116.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Alyass, A., Turcotte, M. and Meyre, D. (2015), ‘From big data to personalized medicine for all: challenges and opportunities’, BMC Med Genomics, 8: 33.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baicker, K., Congdon, W. J. and Mullainathan, S. (2012), ‘Health insurance coverage and take-up: Lessons from behavioral economics’, The Milbank Quarterly, 90(1): 107134.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bellucci, E., Dharmasena, L., Nguyen, L. and Calache, H. (2017), ‘The effectiveness of SMS Reminders and the impact of patient characteristics on missed appointments in a public dental outpatient clinic’, Australasian Journal of Information Systems 21: 121,CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaiyachati, K. H. et al. (2018), ‘Association of rideshare-based transportation services and missed primary care appointments: a clinical trial’, JAMA Int Med, 178(3), 383389.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cook, C. A. L., Selig, K. L., Wedge, B. J. and Gohn-Baube, E. A. (1999), ‘Access Barriers and the Use of Prenatal Care by Low-Income, Inner-City Women’, Social Work, 44(2): 129129.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cruz, H. E., Gawrys, J., Thompson, D., Mejia, J., Rosul, L. and Lazar, D. (2018), ‘A Multipronged Initiative to Improve Productivity and Patient Access in a Federally Qualified Health Center Network’, Journal of Ambulatory Care Management, 41(3): 225–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dantas, L. F., Fleck, J. L., Cyrino Oliveira, F. L. and Hamacher, S. (2018), ‘No-shows in appointment scheduling - a systematic literature review’, Health Policy, 122(4): 412421.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
DuMontier, C., Rindfleisch, K., Pruszynski, J. and Frey, J. (2013), ‘A multi-method intervention to reduce no-shows in an urban residency clinic’, Fam Med, 45(9): 634641.Google Scholar
Ericson, K. M. M., Kingsdale, J., Layton, T. and Sacarny, A. (2017), ‘Nudging Leads Consumers in Colorado To Shop But Not Switch ACA Marketplace Plans’, Health Affairs, 36(2).Google Scholar
Franklin, M., Folke, T. and Ruggeri, K. (2019), ‘Optimising nudges and boosts for financial decisions under uncertainty’, Palgrave Communications, 5(113).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handel, B. R. (2013), ‘Adverse selection and inertia in health insurance markets: When nudging hurts’, American Economic Review, 103(7): 2643–82.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hasvold, P. E., and Wootton, R. (2011), ‘Use of telephone and SMS reminders to improve attendance at hospital appointments: a systematic review’, Journal of telemedicine and telecare, 17(7): 358364.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hertwig, R., and Grüne-Yanoff, T. (2017), ‘Nudging and Boosting: Steering or Empowering Good Decisions’, Perspectives on Psychological Science, 12(6): 973986.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hollands, G. J., Bignardi, G., Johnston, M., Kelly, M. P., Ogilvie, D., Petticrew, M., Prestwich, A., Shemilt, I., Sutton, S. and Marteau, T. M. (2017), ‘The TIPPME intervention typology for changing environments to change behaviour’, Nature Human Behaviour, 1(8): 19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, E. J., Shu, S. B., Dellaert, B. G., Fox, C., Goldstein, D. G., Häubl, G., Larrick, R. P., Payne, J. W., Peters, E., Schkade, D. and Wansink, B. (2012), ‘Beyond nudges: Tools of a choice architecture’, Marketing Letters, 23(2): 487504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kangovi, S., Barg, F. K., Carter, T., Long, J. A., Shannon, R. and Grande, D. (2013), ‘Understanding Why Patients of Low Socioeconomic Status Prefer Hospitals Over Ambulatory Care’, Health Affairs, 32(7): 11961203.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kaplan-Lewis, E. and Perac-Lima, S. (2013), ‘No-Show to Primary Care Appointments: Why Patients Do Not Come’, Journal of Primary Care & Community Health, 4(4): 251255.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
King, D., Greaves, F., Vlaev, I. and Darzi, I. (2013), ‘Approaches based on behavioral economics could help nudge patients and providers toward lower health spending growth’, Health Affairs, 32(4): 661–8.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kuhnen, C. M. (2015), ‘Asymmetric learning from financial information’, The Journal of Finance, 70(5): 20292062.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marteau, T. M., Hollands, G. J. and Fletcher, P. C. (2012), ‘Changing human behavior to prevent disease: the importance of targeting automatic processes’, Science, 337(6101): 14921495.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Medicare Rights Center (2006), Part D 2007: Addressing Access Problems for Low Income People with Medicare. Retrieved from: https://www.medicarerights.org/pdf/Part_D_2007.pdf (accessed: 18 November 2019).Google Scholar
Moffitt, T. E., Arseneault, L., Belsky, D., Dickson, N., Hancox, R. J., Harrington, H., Houts, R., Poulton, R., Roberts, B. W., Ross, S. and Sears, M. R. (2011), ‘A gradient of childhood self-control predicts health, wealth, and public safety’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(7): 26932698.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mullainathan, S. and Shafir, E. (2013), Scarcity: Why having too little means so much, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Münscher, R., Vetter, M. and Scheuerle, T. (2016), ‘A review and taxonomy of choice architecture techniques’, Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 29(5): 511524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patel, M. S., Volpp, K. G. and Asch, D. A. (2018), ‘Nudge Units to Improve the Delivery of Health Care’, N Engl J Med, 378(3): 214.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pence, B. W. et al. (2018), ‘Association of Increased Chronicity of Depression With HIV Appointment Attendance, Treatment Failure, and Mortality Among HIV-Infected Adults in the United States’, JAMA Psych, 75(4): 379385.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Roberto, C. A. et al. (2019), ‘Association of a beverage tax on sugar-sweetened and artificially sweetened beverages with changes in beverage prices and sales at chain retailers in a large urban setting’, JAMA, 321(18): 17991810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, G. (2001), ‘Sick individuals and populations (reiteration)’, International Journal of Epidemiology, 30(3): 427432.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggeri, K., Folke, T., Benzerga, A., Verra, S., Büttner, C., Steinbeck, V., Yee, S. and Chaiyachati, K. (2020a), ‘Nudging New York: Adaptive models and the limits of behavioral interventions to reduce no-show and health inequalities’, BMC Health Services Research, 20: 363.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ruggeri, K., Garcia-Garzon, E., Maguire, A., Matz, S. C. and Huppert, F. A. (2020b), ‘Well-being is more than happiness and life satisfaction: A multidimensional analysis of 21 countries.’ Health & Quality of Life Outcomes.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sacarny, A., Barnett, M. L., Le Pharm, J., Tetkoski, F., Yokum, D. and Agrawal, S. (2018), ‘Effect of Peer Comparison Letters for High Volume Primary Care Prescribers of Quetiapine in Older and Disabled Adults. A Randomized Clinical Trial’, JAMA Psychiatry, 75(10): 10031011.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sacarny, A., Yokum, D., Finkelstein, A. and Agrawal, S. (2016), ‘Medicare Letters To Curb Overprescribing Of Controlled Substances Had No Detectable Effect On Providers’, Health Affairs, 35(3).CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Starbird, L. E., DiMaina, C., Sun, C. and Han, H. (2019), ‘A Systematic Review of Interventions to Minimize Transportation Barriers Among People with Chronic Diseases’, Journal of Community Health, 44(2): 400411.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sunstein, C. R. (2017), ‘Nudges that fail’, Behavioural Public Policy, 1(1): 425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2019), ‘Algorithms, correcting biases’, Social Research: An International Quarterly, 86(2): 499511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, R. L. (2019), ‘Bag leakage: The effect of disposable carryout bag regulations on unregulated bags’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 93: 254271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, J. C. et al. (2007), ‘Medication access and continuity: The experiences of dual-eligible psychiatric patients during the first 4 months of the Medicare prescription drug benefit’, American Journal of Psychiatry, 164(5): 789796.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zafari, Z., Jiao, B., Will, B., Li, S. and Muenning, P. A. (2018), ‘The trade-off between optimizing flight patterns and human health: a case study on aircraft noise in Queens, NY, USA’, Int. J. Res. Public Health, 15: 1753.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Personalizing nudges as a more efficient lever for behavior change. Top pathway: generic intervention (reminders) effective for the majority of individuals within and between groups. Further intervention (transportation) offered to those who did not attend, but minimal benefit is visible apart from one group (older individuals), for whom the method addresses a need or barrier. Bottom pathway: those who did not attend after the generic intervention receive personalized nudges, increasing efficacy within each group as well as in aggregate.Note: The figure has been created by the authors of this article. It has been posted on a website introducing this research topic: https://datascience.columbia.edu/nudging-new-york-using-data-science-increase-healthcare-access-underserved-communities.

Figure 1

Table 1. Differentiating interventions based on value and feasibility of personalization.