Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T23:02:15.037Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Participatory Mechanisms in Bolivia, Ecuador and Venezuela: Deepening or Undermining Democracy?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 November 2015

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Through the comparative analysis of the participatory mechanisms established in Bolivia, Ecuador and Venezuela, this study explores under which conditions such mechanisms are more likely to deepen or undermine democracy. While the informal participatory mechanisms established in Bolivia have produced, though imperfectly, significant democratic benefits, in Ecuador and Venezuela crucial participatory mechanisms have appeared to favour the concentration of power in the executive, contributing to the strangulation of representative institutions, the erosion of the separation of powers and the development of government-dominated social groups. By shedding light on the undemocratic manipulation of participatory mechanisms, an area still largely unexplored, this study contributes to a better understanding of the risks and opportunities associated with the deepening of democracy.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s). Published by Government and Opposition Limited and Cambridge University Press 2015 

one of the most interesting political phenomena in the recent history of Latin America has been the emergence in Bolivia, Ecuador and Venezuela of radical leftist governments committed to deepening democracy. To this end, these governments have established a variety of participatory mechanisms, including the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control (CPCCS) in Ecuador, the Communal Councils (CCs) in Venezuela, and more informal mechanisms such as the National Coordination for Change (CONALCAM) in Bolivia. Based on fieldwork and interviews with a variety of actors, including government officials and leaders of social movements, this study explores the conditions under which participatory mechanisms are more likely to deepen or undermine democracy. Has the establishment of participatory mechanisms favoured autonomous popular participation in public decision-making? Have these mechanisms been used to concentrate power in the executive? Is there variation between the cases considered? What explains this variation? Participatory mechanisms deepen democracy if they favour autonomous participation in public decision-making, thus promoting what Roberts (Reference Roberts1998: 30), in his definition of the deepening of democracy, describes as ‘moving from hierarchical forms of elitist or bureaucratic control to forms of popular self-determination’.

While the informal participatory mechanisms established in Bolivia have favoured, though imperfectly, autonomous popular participation in public decision-making, in Ecuador and Venezuela participatory mechanisms such as the Communal Councils and the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control have appeared to favour the concentration of power in the executive, contributing to the strangulation of democratic representative institutions, the erosion of the separation of powers and the development of government-dominated social groups. I argue that two factors are crucial during the foundational moment to explain the emergence of democratic rather than manipulative participatory mechanisms able to resist democratic pressures from below: (1) the presence (or absence) of demands for participation originating from civil society;Footnote 1 and (2) the government’s vulnerability to the defection or mobilization of civil society actors formulating demands for participation.Footnote 2

Unlike other participatory programmes, these cases provide a valuable opportunity to examine the functioning of participatory institutions within constitutionally sanctioned, centralized and comprehensive attempts to deepen democracy. Because of differences in terms of scale and functions, the participatory mechanisms considered in this study are not perfectly comparable. However, these institutions have represented central mechanisms in these countries’ participatory projects, characterizing each of these experiences. Accordingly, their comparison is appropriate to shed light on the more general democratic, rather than undemocratic, features of the Bolivian, Ecuadorian and Venezuelan participatory projects. In the last decade in Venezuela, the Communal Councils, the latest Bolivarian participatory experiment, have constituted the primary instruments towards a communal, participatory democracy. In Ecuador, the implementation of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control, whose establishment is defined in the council’s official website (Consejo de Participación Ciudadana y Control Social n.d.) as the Constitution’s ‘most important advance in the field of participation’,Footnote 3 has represented the priority and the most tangible outcome of the participatory policy of the government. Finally, in Bolivia, in a context characterized by the predominantly informal character of popular participation and an imperfect implementation of the constitution (see Wolff Reference Wolff2013), the National Coordination for Change has represented a crucial venue to realize the constitutionally sanctioned participation of civil society organizations in public decision-making.

Models of Democracy and the Risks of Participatory Mechanisms

The analysis of the participatory processes in these countries contributes to important areas of research, including the Latin American left and its reforms, alternative models of democracy and the undemocratic use of democratic institutions.Footnote 4 As noted by Levitsky and Roberts (Reference Levitsky and Roberts2011), and Madrid (Reference Madrid2011: 240–2), while each of these governments has been characterized by plebiscitarian tendencies, thus failing to fully respect liberal democratic institutions, the coexistence of radical democratic tendencies as well as the dispersal of power between Bolivian president Evo Morales and popular movements have distinguished the Bolivian from the Ecuadorian and Venezuelan cases. The analysis of the participatory mechanisms considered in this study sheds further light on these differences and show that, unlike in Venezuela and Ecuador – and despite Morales’s plebiscitarian tendencies – in Bolivia participatory mechanisms such as the National Coordination for Change have increased autonomous popular participation in public decision-making. In particular, the analysis of these participatory processes contributes to the debate on new forms of democracy, including what scholars such as Wolff (Reference Wolff2013) and Arditi (Reference Arditi2008) describe as Latin America’s possible movement towards less liberal, more participatory (‘post-liberal’) forms of democracy.

Moreover, the analysis of mechanisms such as the Communal Councils and the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control sheds light on the undemocratic potential of participatory mechanisms and on how they may contribute to the consolidation of hybrid regimes, an area still largely unexplored. Recently, authors such as Levitsky and Roberts (Reference Levitsky and Roberts2011) and Cameron et al. (Reference Cameron, Hershberg and Sharpe2012) have recognized the possible manipulation of participatory mechanisms, including the dangers such manipulation may pose to other democratic institutions.Footnote 5

Finally, this study contributes to the identification of the conditions influencing participatory mechanisms’ outcomes. Comparative studies of both locally and nationally initiated participatory reforms have examined the conditions influencing participatory mechanisms’ ambiguous outcomes, focusing on the importance of civil society, leadership and political parties (see Baiocchi et al. Reference Baiocchi, Heller and Silva2011; Goldfrank Reference Goldfrank2007, Reference Goldfrank2011; McNulty Reference McNulty2011; Montecinos Reference Montecinos2012; van Cott Reference Van Cott2008; Wampler Reference Wampler2007; Zaremberg Reference Zaremberg2012). Though contributing to a better understanding of participatory mechanisms’ outcomes, this literature has tended to ignore the fact that participatory mechanisms can be deliberately designed to effectively resist the democratizing effects of autonomous, active or contentious civil societies.Footnote 6 For example, Wampler’s (Reference Wampler2007: 272) emphasis on the role of contentious politics against ‘extensive co-optation of CSOS [civil society organizations] and citizens by governments’ has advanced our understanding of participatory mechanisms’ outcomes. However, as demonstrated by the Communal Councils in Venezuela (see below), when properly designed and implemented, manipulated participatory mechanisms can prove impermeable to contentious politics by limiting the contentiousness of their participants both within and outside the participatory arena and preventing the participation of likely contentious participants.

Similar to my study, Schneider and Welp (Reference Schneider and Welp2011: 24) identify, among other factors, demands and power from below as elements that can positively influence the nature of participatory mechanisms. These authors, however, seem to equate the institutionalization of participatory mechanisms with citizens’ ability to participate in significant decision-making. As we will see, this finding is disconfirmed by the Bolivian, Ecuadorian and Venezuelan cases, where highly institutionalized mechanisms have served the strategic goals of the government (e.g. Venezuela) while less institutionalized mechanisms (e.g. Bolivia) have instead promoted autonomous popular participation in public decision-making.

The Argument

I argue that: (1) the presence (or absence) of demands for participation originating from civil society;Footnote 7 and (2) the government’s vulnerability to the defection or mobilization of civil society actors formulating demands for participationFootnote 8 are crucial factors, during the foundational moment, to explain the democratic (or undemocratic) character of participatory mechanisms. The second variable refers to the ability of civil society actors to harm the government and pose credible threats to its survival through defection or mobilization. Defections and mobilizations against the government may jeopardize the survival of the executive by undermining its legitimacy, pressuring its members to leave office, or weakening its re-election prospects.

Social actors demanding participation will be eager to use participatory mechanisms meaningfully to advance their own claims. Hence, they are likely to monitor and try to influence the design and establishment of participatory mechanisms. If the government is vulnerable to the defection or mobilization of these actors, its room to manipulate and shape participatory mechanisms on the basis of strategic, potentially undemocratic, interests is limited. In Venezuela and Ecuador, where the establishment of mechanisms for participation occurred in the absence of similar societal constraints, ruling elites had more room to shape and manipulate participatory institutions on the basis of illiberal interests and to concentrate power in the executive.Footnote 9 While in Venezuela on the eve of Hugo Chávez’s election existing demands for participation were unable to shape autonomously the national political debate, in Ecuador active and contentious civil society actors, including the so-called forajidos (outlaws), were able to take centre-stage in Ecuadorian politics and construct the political debate around their demands for participation before Rafael Correa’s rise to power. However, Correa’s low vulnerability to these groups provided the executive with the opportunity to dismiss these demands during the creation of manipulative participatory mechanisms. The Ecuadorian case shows that, however important, the presence of an intense participatory discourse is not sufficient, in itself, to produce democratic participatory mechanisms. In Bolivia, the existence of demands for participation originating from social actors able to determine the fate of the Morales government and hence constrain the action of the government has instead prevented the emergence of manipulative participatory institutions, leading to mechanisms that, though imperfectly, have favoured autonomous popular participation in public decision-making.

As witnessed by a controversial police rebellion in 2010 in Ecuador and, in particular, by the 2002 attempted coup in Venezuela and the autonomist claims of the departments controlled by the opposition in Bolivia in 2008, in each of these countries part of the opposition has demonstrated open hostility to the government’s process of change, providing incentives for the creation of government-dominated participatory mechanisms. However, the societal conditions examined above have distinguished the Bolivian from the Ecuadorian and Venezuelan participatory outcomes.

Venezuela

The Communal Councils

The Bolivarian participatory project is based today on the Communal Councils, participatory institutions designed to identify and satisfy the needs of the local community. Promoted under Chávez, the Communal Councils remain central mechanisms in the participatory project of the Maduro government as evidenced, for example, by the reform of the Organic Law for the Communitarian Management of Functions, Services and Other Attributions (hereafter the Transfer Law, see below). Functioning through a variety of institutions, including a Citizen Assembly and an Executive Unit, the Communal Councils, composed of between 150 and 400 families in the cities and a minimum of 10 and 20, respectively, in indigenous communities and rural areas (Organic Law of Communal Councils, Art. 4), typically identify the most urgent needs of the community through the elaboration of projects. If approved, the projects (for example, renovation of houses or road making) are generally financed by central government funds. As of September 2013, 40,035 Communal Councils had been created in Venezuela (Radio Nacional de Venezuela 2013). Following the 2010 Law of the Communes, the Communal Councils can group together into Communes. Composed of all the members of the community aged over 15, the Citizen Assembly represents the most important decision-making body of the Communal Councils, with decisions made on a simple majority basis. It approves the projects that are then typically funded by the central government, approves ‘normas de convivencia’ – community rules subject to the existing legal system – and appoints the members of the executive unit, the body in charge of implementing decisions of the Citizen Assembly.

Rather than neutral participatory mechanisms, the Communal Councils are, as stated in the 2009 Law of the Communal Councils, the basic units of the in fieri socialist state and society. The Communal Councils have been accused of being used to mobilize supporters of the government in conjunction with electoral tests (Ellner Reference Ellner2009: 4; Hidalgo Reference Hidalgo2009: 88) and of being prone to clientelistic practices because of their dependence on the government and its financial resources (Canache Reference Canache2007: 19). Similarly, Lovera (Reference Lovera2008), García-Guadilla (Reference García-Guadilla2008) and López Maya and Lander (Reference López Maya and Lander2011: 77) have raised concerns about the question of the Communal Councils’ autonomy from the government.Footnote 10

Besides ensuring a considerable source of social support through the distribution of material resources, the government has also pursued the indoctrination of the members of the Communal Councils to socialist values, for example through the constant presence of the Venezuelan United Socialist Party (PSUV) in the Communal Councils’ events and meetings. The distribution of material resources and the diffusion of socialist values have represented powerful instruments to limit the contentiousnessFootnote 11 of the participants in the Communal Councils, contributing to the development of government-dominated civil society groups. The Communal Councils have also proved impermeable to what could be defined as likely contentious participants, such as groups close to the opposition or critical of the executive. The strategy of the government has consisted of preventing likely contentious participants from legally creating new Communal Councils through the registration requirement. To acquire legal personhood – that is, legal recognition and the right to receive funds from the central government – each Communal Council is required to be registered by the Ministry for the Communes and Social Movements. While Álvarez and García-Guadilla (Reference Álvarez and García-Guadilla2011: 199–201) note that interviews conducted in different Communal Councils have provided evidence of the political use of the certification requirement as well as of clientelistic practices, the human rights organization Provea (2010: 376, cited also in Álvarez and García-Guadilla Reference Álvarez and García-Guadilla2011) describes the number of ‘denouncements and cases’ of political discriminations during the certification process as ‘considerable’.Footnote 12

In an interview I conducted in Caracas, two members of an unregistered Communal Council observed that the strategies to deny the registration to non-Chavista Communal Councils have been various, ranging from the identification of formal procedural errors to the strategy of simply not attending to the non-Chavista Communal Councils’ request of being legally recognized.Footnote 13 The opposition has even denounced that to achieve registration, groups of citizens were required to present various proofs of socialist commitment, including their membership of the Venezuelan United Socialist Party (El Universal 2011).Footnote 14

The denial of the registration to Communal Councils perceived as antagonistic has often led to discriminatory results. The National Front of Excluded Communal Councils, an organization created to denounce the discrimination of non-Chavista Communal Councils, maintains, for instance, that 2,400 Communal Councils were not officially recognized, leading to scenarios such as that in Baruta, Caracas, a municipality controlled by the opposition, where only around 25 per cent of the existing Communal Councils were able to register (Meneses Reference Meneses2011). According to Hawkins (Reference Hawkins2010), the disproportionate presence of Chavistas in the government’s participatory initiatives has to do with non-Chavistas’ reluctance to participate in initiatives characterized by a Chavista discourse. However, in the Communal Councils exclusionary practices have increasingly accompanied this self-screening, especially since non-Chavistas have increasingly attempted to penetrate the Communal Councils. It should also be noted that the existence of a strongly partisan discourse in supposedly neutral and publicly funded state institutions is in itself dubiously democratic.Footnote 15

Besides being aimed at the development of government-dominated social groups, the creation of the Communal Councils along with the recently created Communes has also responded to the objective of suffocating democratic representative institutions such as states and municipalities (see also Smilde Reference Smilde2009: 5). The government has pursued a double strategy. First, it has undermined the resources devoted to the state and municipal levels (see Armas Reference Armas2010; Blyde Reference Blyde2010). Second, it has progressively attempted to undermine the responsibilities of the municipalities and the states to the benefit of government-dominated participatory mechanisms. The establishment of Communes resulting from the unification of several Communal Councils is functional to ‘the construction of the socialist society’ (Organic Law of the Communes, Art. 7),Footnote 16 representing a direct challenge to the very existence of municipalities. Explicitly defined in the Organic Law of the Communes as a ‘socialist space’Footnote 17 (Art. 5), like the Communal Councils, the Communes are organized in different bodies, including a legislative and an executive unit. While the recently amended Transfer Law prescribes the transfer of functions and assets from states and municipalities to the Communal Councils and the Communes, Article 5 of the Organic Law of the Municipal Public Power excludes the Communes from municipal regulations’ scope of application. The result is the creation of independent, government-dominated, socialist enclaves within the municipalities.

It should be noted that underlining the exclusionary and manipulative strategy of the government is not to say that the majority of the Communal Councils are entirely composed of pro-government groups. Existing surveys seem to undermine this conclusion (see Hawkins et al. Reference Hawkins, Patch, Anguiano and Seligson2008: 119; Machado Reference Machado2009: 60). However, what emerges from one of these studies is also that 34 per cent of the Communal Councils are entirely composed of pro-government groups versus only 2 per cent entirely composed of opposition groups (Machado Reference Machado2009: 60). While these figures are in themselves alarming, it is important to note that the strategy of replacing independent representative institutions with government-controlled Communal Councils does not require the creation of exclusively Chavista Communal Councils. As noted above, the decisions of the Communal Councils’ Citizen Assemblies are made on a simple majority basis. Accordingly, the majoritarian presence of pro-government groups – which, in turn, can be ensured through a strategic use of the registration requirement – is sufficient to attain the control of a Communal Council.

Civil Society and Demands for Participation in Venezuela

The nature of the Venezuelan participatory experience can be better understood through the analysis of civil society before Chávez’s rise to power. According to Salamanca (Reference Salamanca2004), a ‘new’ civil society emerged in the 1970s and 1980s from the spontaneous mobilizations of grassroot organizations such as the neighbourhood movement and human rights associations. Marking a rupture with the past, this ‘new’ civil society characterized itself for its participatory impetus, including, as noted by Salamanca (Reference Salamanca2004: 97), ‘the participation of the population in the solution of its own problems’. Levine and Crisp (Reference Levine and Crisp1999: 152) observe, in particular, that in the 1980s the neighbourhood movement put pressure on the government to open important channels of participation, such as ‘the election of governors, the election of mayors, the creation of parish councils, and the possibility of recalling officials’.

The participatory impetus of the neighbourhood movement, however, did not prove immune to the cooptation attempts of political parties given that, as observed by Levine and Crisp (Reference Levine and Crisp1999: 153): ‘Party efforts met with considerable success, and as a result, the banner of political reform to some extent passed out of the hands of community organizations. The reformulation of goals happened in other popular movements as well. For example, the cooperative movement assumed a lower profile, leaving the fight for political reform to concentrate instead on its own organizational growth.’

The participatory involution of the ‘new’ civil society was not only a result of the successful cooptation operated by political parties. First, the demands for participation elaborated by the ‘new’ civil society in the 1980s were eventually met by the national government through the creation of new channels of participation, including the direct election of mayors and governors. Because the participatory demands of the ‘new’ civil society had been met, since the early 1990s the participatory impetus of the ‘new’ civil society lost its raison d’être. As witnessed by demands aiming at the direct election of local representatives, the participatory demands of the neighbourhood movement were intended in the framework of representative democracy.Footnote 18 More generally, as observed by Lander (Reference Lander2007: 24), far from formulating and proposing radical demands, the neighbourhood movement had a ‘conservative idea of democracy’. As a consequence, once the direct election of mayors and governors was achieved, the neighbourhood movement did not proceed to the elaboration of new, more radical participatory demands.

Second, the declining participatory impetus of the ‘new’ civil society may have also resulted from the increasing collaboration of the new civil society with the state, a collaboration that, according to Salamanca (Reference Salamanca2004: 96–100), led various civil society organizations to become ‘modest providers of social services’ on behalf of the state.Footnote 19 While Salamanca (Reference Salamanca2004) underlines the ‘new’ civil society organizations’ intention to bypass the intermediation of political parties, Paley (Reference Paley2001) highlights the inherent dangers associated with similar forms of cooperation. In her analysis of the post-Pinochet Chile, where the neoliberal cuts to social spending had made civil society organizations new providers of social services, Paley (Reference Paley2001) observes how a similar state–society relationship may lead to a civil society that, demobilized and closely cooperating with the state, proves unable to direct demands to the state and keep it accountable.

The participatory involution of the ‘new’ civil society was matched by the limitations affecting more radical demands for participation. While recognizing the growing interest for participation as a common trait of civil society organizations in the 1970s, García-Guadilla (Reference García-Guadilla2007: 143) questions the notion of a homogeneous civil society, underlining the existence of ‘conflicting projects and interpretations of democracy’, including more radical notions of democracy. Recently, Ciccariello-Maher (Reference Ciccariello-Maher2013) has stressed the importance of popular movements pre-dating Chávez’s rise to power and their progressive unification within the revolutionary process. However, these groups represented marginal groups in the context of the Punto Fijo democracy. In the words of a high-ranking official of what is now the Ministry for the Communes and Social Movements, ‘popular organizations during representative democracy were nothing more than resistance organizations’.Footnote 20

Though highlighting the existence of progressive actors and community organizations before the establishment of the Bolivarian republic, Wilpert (Reference Wilpert2007: 186–7) underlines, for example, the fragmented nature of these groups and Chávez’s crucial role in providing a point of reference. As observed by Fernandes (Reference Fernandes2010: 237), lower classes did organize in Venezuela’s poor barrios but, despite some recent coalition-building efforts, their fragmentation has affected their ability to sustain ‘a common agenda to represent their own interests before the state’. Similarly, López Maya and Lander (Reference López Maya and Lander2011: 75) note that the popular movement ‘lacked an organic base, tradition, and networks which might have given it the strength and autonomy to take action vis-à-vis the state’. In short, fragmentation muffled more radical demands for participation and contributed to making Chávez largely invulnerable to pre-existing social movements.

This scenario, combined with the participatory involution of what Salamanca (Reference Salamanca2004) defines as the ‘new’ civil society, provided Chávez with the control of the participatory discourse and the unconstrained opportunity to create manipulative participatory mechanisms.

Ecuador

The Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control

The Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control has represented the most tangible outcome of Correa’s participatory policy. It is composed of various bodies, secretariats and commissions. The members of the plenum, its governing body, are selected through a public competition (concurso), consisting of a written test and the evaluation of the candidates’ professional resumés. The Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control was created to meet three primary objectives: to promote citizen participation, to increase state accountability through the establishment of a social control, and to involve citizens in the appointment of important state institutions.

Besides proving, in fact, to be the primary activity of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control, the appointment of some of these institutions, namely the fiscal general (prosecutor general), the National Electoral Council, the people’s defender and the Tribunal Contencioso Electoral, has also proved to be its most controversial function. Once a prerogative of the legislative body, these authorities are now appointed through public competitions (organized by the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control) aimed at selecting the most deserving candidates and involving ordinary citizens in the selection process.Footnote 21 Similar to the selection of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s plenum, candidates are selected on the basis of a written test and their professional resumé, under the supervision of a Citizen Committee. The Citizen Committee organizes the selection process and submits a final, binding report, including the outcome of the competition, to the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s plenum. Despite their name, the Citizen Commissions are only partially composed of ordinary citizens. Five members, elected through public competitions, represent the citizenry and social organizations while the other five members are appointed by various state institutions, including the executive. The five representatives of the citizenry and social organizations are selected on a random basis from the 30 candidates whose professional resumés reach the highest scores. The plenum selects these 30 top candidates after receiving a report from a technical committee.Footnote 22 Citizen oversight committees (veedurías), institutions entirely composed of volunteers without significant decision-making power, oversee the correct and fair functioning of the public competition. Interestingly, unlike the Venezuelan Communal Councils, the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control does not involve the participation of a large number of citizens. According to De la Torre (Reference De la Torre2013b: 45), Correa’s decision not to create mobilization mechanisms such as the Communal Councils has been related to the absence of a strong opposition in Ecuador.Footnote 23

Although the participation of ordinary citizens in the selection process should guarantee more transparent procedures and respond to the imperative of increasing popular participation in public decision-making, the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s selection procedures seem to have served the strategic objectives of the government. First of all, the significant presence of officials with ties to the executive has raised concerns about the autonomy and independence of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control. According to Montalvo (Reference Montalvo2010), the majority of the plenum – composed of seven members selected through supposedly impartial public competitions – emerging from the 2010 selection process had ties to the government or shared similar political tendencies. Three members, in particular, Montalvo (Reference Montalvo2010) reports, held important roles in institutions chaired or created by Patiño, Correa’s foreign minister.

Corroborating the concerns surrounding the appointment of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s plenum, the participatory selection procedures organized under the supervision of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control have often led to the appointment of candidates apparently close to the government. One of the most controversial cases is that of Chiriboga Zambrano, an ex-minister of the Correa government and then Ecuadorian ambassador to Spain recently appointed as the country’s fiscal general through the participatory selection procedures organized by the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control. The fiscal general is a very important office, given that its responsibilities include the investigation of crimes committed by the president and other important state officials (see Fiscalia General del Estado n.d.). From the start of the selection procedure, El Comercio (2011a), a popular newspaper generally critical of the government, underlined Chiriboga Zambrano’s ties to the government. During the selection process, some candidates, the coordinator of the oversight committee and even a member of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s plenum, Luis Pachala, openly criticized the procedure, questioning, in particular, the Citizen Committee’s ranking and grading procedures (El Comercio 2011b, 2011c; Ecuadorinmediato.com 2011). As well as criticizing the lack of transparency within the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control and raising concerns over the irrelevance of the oversight committees (veedurias), Pachala observed that some members of the Citizen Committee worked for Correa’s party Alianza Pais (El Comercio 2011d). Of particular concern were the revisions to a ranking elaborated by a technical committee (an institution advising the Citizen Committee), raising Chiriboga Zambrano’s score to first place (El Comercio 2011b; Hoy 2011). Interestingly, before the official conclusion of the selection procedures, the then-minister of internal affairs intervened to advocate on behalf of Chiroboga Zambrano’s candidacy, observing, as quoted by Villarruel (Reference Villarruel2011), that ‘if there is justice in our society, it would be correct that [Chiriboga Zambrano] becomes the fiscal’,Footnote 24 thereby exerting significant pressure on the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control, an institution formally independent from the government. Similarly, Correa bluntly dismissed the criticisms about the selection process, pointing to Chiriboga Zambrano as the unquestionable winner of the public competition (Hoy 2011).

Besides the appointment of Chiriboga Zambrano, concerns surrounding the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s selection procedures have focused on the appointment of other important offices selected through the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control. According to the newspaper El Universo (2011), the National Electoral Council emerging from the 2011 concurso was almost entirely composed of former officials of ministries and governmental agencies. Similarly, Rivadeneira, the new defensor del pueblo, was adviser and under-secretary to Jalkh – Correa’s former private secretary (secretario particular) – during Jalkh’s stints as minister of justice and interior minister under Correa. Finally, concerns have been raised about the ties existing between the government and the members of the Tribunal Contencioso Electoral (El Comercio 2012).

In light of these outcomes, the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control – so far immune to the participation of disaffected citizens in its ‘participatory’ selection procedures thanks to an effective institutional design – has appeared as an instrument to extend the power of the government over other functions of the state, and hence to erode the Ecuadorian system of checks and balances.

Correa, the Forajidos and the Indigenous Movement

The election of Correa and the creation of participatory institutions took place amid considerable demands for participation formulated first by the indigenous movement and, on the eve of Correa’s election, by those same social actors that were involved in the mobilization responsible for the fall of Gutiérrez in 2005, the so-called forajidos (outlaws).

Under the direction of the Confederation of Indigenous Nationalities of Ecuador (CONAIE), throughout the 1990s and the first half of the 2000s, the indigenous movement played a central role in the Ecuadorian sociopolitical arena. After various mobilizations in the 1990s, in 2000 the indigenous movement participated, along with future president Colonel Lucio Gutiérrez, in an action that forced President Jamil Mahuad out of office. After an unsuccessful attempt to establish a Junta of National Salvation, together with segments of the army, in 2003 the indigenous movement won power democratically by supporting the presidential bid of Gutiérrez. Throughout this phase, as demonstrated by its demands during the 1990 mobilization – characterized, as observed by Becker (Reference Becker2012: 30), by the determination to establish ‘Indigenous control over their own affairs’ – and the attempt to win power, both undemocratically and through elections, the indigenous movement formulated significant demands for participation. Interestingly, as outlined below, rather than providing a definitive response to these demands, the indigenous movement’s rise to power in 2003 may be viewed as the beginning of a severe crisis that has since then severely affected the indigenous movement.

Undermined by Gutiérrez’s commitment to the establishment of fiscal austerity policies (Lucero Reference Lucero2008: 128–9), the alliance between Gutiérrez and the indigenous movement proved ephemeral, resulting in a rupture a few months after Gutiérrez’s election. Like Bucaram and Mahuad, Gutiérrez could not conclude his presidential tenure because of a popular mobilization, known as the forajidos revolt and the Congress’s decision to vote for his removal. A loosely organized popular mobilization, the rebellion of the forajidos can be viewed as the intervention of ordinary citizens in national politics to divest discredited institutional actors of their leading role. In 2005, following Gutiérrez’s manipulation of the Supreme Court, thousands of citizens staged protests against his government and, more generally, a largely discredited political class. The forajidos revolt was characterized by its spontaneity and the absence of traditional political actors (Acosta Reference Acosta2005; Ramírez Gallegos Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010; Unda Reference Unda2005). It is notable that, in line with a more general critique of existing institutions, the revolt also developed demands for significant political reforms (Acosta Reference Acosta2005; Ramírez Gallegos Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010). In particular, while underlining the existence of undemocratic tendencies, Burbano de Lara (Reference Burbano de Lara2010: 214) highlights the determination of the forajidos, as well as of the indigenous mobilization against Mahuad in 2000, to go beyond representative democracy, towards a more direct form of democracy. Similarly, according to Pazmiño (Reference Pazmiño2005: 38), citizens participating in the forajidos revolt demanded a more active role in the country’s politics and the establishment of a ‘truly representative and participatory democracy’.Footnote 25 In short, the forajidos articulated clear demands for citizen participation as an alternative to a political system that was seen as unresponsive and undemocratic.

In this context, Correa became president in 2006 after serving as minister of finance under the successor of Gutiérrez, Palacio, and after espousing the forajidos cause.Footnote 26 Despite the existence of actors eager to participate in public decision-making and hence take advantage of potential participatory institutions, Correa was able to establish and implement an undemocratic participatory mechanism in the form of the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control thanks to his low vulnerability to those pushing for participation. With its spontaneous character and initial autonomy from traditional political actors (Acosta Reference Acosta2005; Ramírez Gallegos Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010; Unda Reference Unda2005), the forajidos revolt may be viewed as a vivid exercise of democracy. Citizens advanced proposals and exchanged ideas on the protest through a local radio (Radio Luna) in a typical movement ‘from below’ (Unda Reference Unda2005: 133–4).Footnote 27 However, associated with the forajidos’ rejection of any involvement of traditional institutional actors, the revolt displayed significant weaknesses, including, as observed by Ramírez Gallegos (Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010), the lack of a coherent organizational structure or a political programme. Accordingly, Correa faced a relatively uncoordinated movement during his presidential campaign and after his election. As noted by Burbano de Lara (Reference Burbano de Lara2010: 208–9), the forajidos’ organizational shortcomings were key elements in Correa’s ability to supplant the movement, contributing, along with the decline of the indigenous movement, to the emergence of a civil society unable to check the power of the president. Members of the forajidos were given important roles within the Country Alliance (AP) and the government, but their inability to mobilize powerful organizations and hence jeopardize the executive relegated them to a subordinate role vis-à-vis Correa. Conaghan (Reference Conaghan2008: 57) noted that Correa has exerted great control on a party that was largely disconnected from organized civil society.

The indigenous movement did not present the organizational weaknesses affecting the forajidos. However, as demonstrated by the mere 2 per cent of votes won by the Pachakutik (the indigenous movement’s electoral vehicle) candidate in the first round of the 2006 presidential election, the indigenous movement experienced one of its worst crises during Correa’s rise to power. Related to the unsuccessful alliance with Gutiérrez, important factors in Pachakutik’s decline included an increasingly disaffected indigenous base and the rejection of both electoral alliances and its previously inclusive approach (Madrid Reference Madrid2012: Ch. 3; Mijeski and Beck Reference Mijeski and Beck2008). For example, Becker (Reference Becker2012: 89) notes, ‘Excluding mestizos in favor of Indigenous candidates meant that Pachakutik lost electoral strength in urban areas’.Footnote 28

The electoral weakness of the indigenous movement made Correa largely invulnerable to indigenous organizations. In 2006, Correa won the opportunity to challenge Alvaro Noboa in the run-off by winning 22.84 per cent of the vote with a 5.42 per cent margin over Gilmar Gutiérrez, who finished third.Footnote 29 In the run-off, Correa won the presidency with a margin of 13.34 percentage points over Noboa.Footnote 30 This means that Pachakutik, whose presidential candidate Macas won 2.19 per cent, was not a decisive force in the 2006 elections.Footnote 31 In the following presidential elections in 2009, Correa was re-elected in the first round with 51.99 per cent and a margin of 23.75 percentage points over his closest opponent Lucio Gutiérrez,Footnote 32 while the Confederation of Indigenous Nationalities of Ecuador did not support any candidate. In 2013, Correa consolidated his power, triumphing again in the first round with 57.17 per cent.Footnote 33

Moreover, affected by Gutiérrez’s attempts to divide the indigenous movement, the Confederation of Indigenous Nationalities of Ecuador failed to replicate the successful uprising of the 1990s, as highlighted by the low levels of participation in mobilizations organized after the end of the alliance with Gutiérrez (Lucero Reference Lucero2008: 129; Mijeski and Beck Reference Mijeski and Beck2008: 45; Zamosc Reference Zamosc2007: 15). In a further sign of its decline, the indigenous movement was not at the centre of the forajidos revolt (Becker Reference Becker2012: 94; Burbano de Lara Reference Burbano de Lara2010: 205; Lucero Reference Lucero2008: 129–30; Mijeski and Beck Reference Mijeski and Beck2008: 43; Ramírez Gallegos Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010: 27; Zamosc Reference Zamosc2007: 15).

For different reasons, the forajidos and the indigenous movement had minimal opportunities to jeopardize the government. Taking advantage of his low vulnerability to civil society actors, Correa has been able to dismiss existing demands for participation and to construct manipulative participatory mechanisms.

Bolivia

The National Coordination for Change

Since Morales’s rise to power, the constitutionally sanctioned participation of civil society organizations in public decision-making has been based on more informal participatory mechanisms such as the National Coordination for Change and the informal relationship existing between the government and the Unity Pact, an alliance composed of the most important indigenous-peasant organizations of the country.Footnote 34 Initially created to defend the revolutionary process, over time the National Coordination for Change has become an important mechanism to involve the social organizations supporting the government in the administration of the country. The National Coordination for Change includes representatives of the government, the Movement Towards Socialism (MAS), and the social organizations supporting the government. Besides indigenous-peasant organizations such as the Sole Syndical Confederation of Peasant Workers of Bolivia (CSUTCB), the Bartolinas and the Syndical Confederation of Intercultural Communities of Bolivia (CSCIB), the National Coordination for Change includes a number of non-indigenous organizations representing various sectors of Bolivian society. Representatives of the social organizations, the Movement Towards Socialism and the government meet periodically in the National Coordination for Change to examine the most important political questions of the moment and to coordinate their short-term political agenda. Besides its periodical meetings, the National Coordination for Change can also meet to debate specific important questions or to define long-term political objectives. Ad hoc meetings may be functional, for example, to the redefinition of the government’s political programme.

The National Coordination for Change represents a crucial mechanism for finding consensus on specific laws. Before being examined by the legislature, the elaboration and discussion of important laws such as the Autonomy and Decentralisation LawFootnote 35 occurs within the National Coordination for Change. Once a proposed law receives the support of the National Coordination for Change and its social organizations, it is sent to the National Assembly, where the Movement Towards Socialism representatives pursue its approval. The considerable presence of indigenous-peasant organizations within the Movement Towards Socialism and the National Assembly guarantees that the proposals of the National Coordination for Change will be taken into account by the legislative body. The National Coordination for Change can thus be viewed as an unofficial parallel legislative assembly, bridging the gap between state and civil society, where both laws and the most important sociopolitical events of the moment are discussed and examined.

Another crucial mechanism ensuring coordination between the government and social organizations are the periodic meetings between the government and the Unity Pact, an alliance of the most important indigenous-peasant organizations of the country, including the CSUTCB, Bartolinas and the CSCIB (the Confederation of the Indigenous Peoples of Bolivia – CIDOB – and the National Council of Ayllus and Markas of Qullasuyu – CONAMAQ – left the pact following the conflict over the Isiboro-Secure Indigenous Territory and National Park – TIPNIS). The pact typically proposes laws in areas of particular interest to its member organizations, such as the agricultural sector. The organizations of the Unity Pact are also members of the National Coordination for Change, playing a crucial role in this organization in light of their organizational strength.

The participation of various social organizations in the formulation, discussion and approval of important laws through the National Coordination for Change and the Unity Pact ensures the inclusion of significant demands of social movements in the agenda of the government. However, these mechanisms are not efficient ways of involving large segments of the population in public decision-making if they do not have the support of the organizational structure of the social organizations included in the National Coordination for Change and in the Unity Pact. Indigenous-peasant organizations such as the CSUTCB, Bartolinas, CSICB and Cocaleros (coca growers) are typically organized in different levels of government. The decisions elaborated at the national level of these organizations, in turn expressed within the National Coordination for Change and the Unity Pact, are typically the result of national meetings including, as observed by a leading member of the Bartolinas, the participation of representatives of subnational units.Footnote 36

The involvement of subnational units (las bases) in the decisions of the organization is remarkable. National or departmental leaders often travel to subnational levels,Footnote 37 thus ensuring a constant involvement of subnational units in the major decisions of the organizations. Referring to the meetings of the Morales-led sindicatos (trade unions) of coca growers, Harten (Reference Harten2011: 59) notes that ‘Their main aims are the facilitation of communication between leaders and the grassroots, the sharing of information, and consensual decision-making by the bases after extensive discussion. In the same way Morales tries as president to visit grassroots organizations weekly, communication between leaders and the grassroots is considered in the sindicatos an essential prerequisite of making informed decisions.’

Similarly, a leading member of the CSCIB describes the periodic visits to the meetings organized by subnational units as one of the obligations of national leaders.Footnote 38 It is this constant interaction between leaders and subnational units that makes the relationship between leaders and the organization’s base ‘structural and continuous’, thus contributing to the organization’s unity.Footnote 39 The constant involvement of subnational units in decision-making at the national level is not only the consequence of the culture of these organizations but also the result of strategic considerations. National leaders are aware that their organization’s sociopolitical relevance is dependent on their ability to mobilize the grassroots when needed. By contributing to the unity of the organization, the meetings between national leaders and subnational units represent crucial mechanisms to maintain the organization’s mobilization strength and, in turn, its sociopolitical relevance. As observed by Harten (Reference Harten2011: 60) in his study of coca growers’ unions, besides favouring the emergence of a ‘shared identity’, ‘the meetings constitute central nodes of the network of coca producers. If Morales and Movement Towards Socialism need resources, for instance for a campaign, this network can be activated to mobilise people.’

It can be argued that the participatory advances of the Morales era have been achieved through a synergy between state institutions and the structure of civil society organizations. The demands emerging from the grassroots are channelled to the government through the organizational structure of indigenous-peasant organizations and the National Coordination for Change. Here, on the basis of a clear mandate from the grassroots, the national representatives of the social movements participate in the government along with members of the executive and the legislature.

Certainly, the National Coordination for Change is not without limitations. First, as noted by Wolff (Reference Wolff2013: 46), in Bolivia the absence of more formal procedures represents an obstacle to the consolidation of existing participatory advances. Moreover, the relatively informal character of the National Coordination for Change, the composition and functioning of which are not determined by any law, has limited participation in this mechanism to social forces supporting the revolutionary process. However, unlike the Ecuadorian and Venezuelan cases – where governments have exerted a firm control over participatory mechanisms’ outcomes – in Bolivia participatory mechanisms such as the National Coordination for Change have provided large social groups with a venue where they can freely convey their demands and have not been used to undermine other democratic institutions, erode checks and balances and hence violate the democratic rights of the excluded.

Morales and Social Movements

The triumph in the 2014 presidential elections demonstrated, once again, the electoral strength of Morales. However, the indigenous-peasant movement’s rise to power is first and foremost a story of social mobilizations and protests. The years preceding Morales’s 2005 election were marked by intense mobilizations of those same indigenous-peasant groups supporting the Movement Towards Socialism, particularly the Morales-led Cocaleros and the CSUTCB. These mobilizations, following the often-discussed water ‘war’ of 2000, were decisive in giving visibility to the indigenous-peasant movement.

As well as supporting the Movement Towards Socialism’s electoral growth, as observed by Mayorga (Reference Mayorga2005: 97–9), through their mobilizations organizations such as the CSUTCB, the Cocaleros and indigenous groups from the lowlands have played a crucial role in shaping the political discourse, formulating significant demands for participation aimed at the opening of important participatory spaces, including a referendum on the management of natural resources and a constituent assembly. Unlike in Ecuador, where Correa was able to gain control of the participatory discourse originating from civil society, in Bolivia, Morales, because of his vulnerability to the mobilization and defection of indigenous-peasant organizations, has not been able to diverge considerably from the demands of the indigenous-peasant movement.

The importance of Morales should not be underestimated. As noted by Madrid (Reference Madrid2012: Ch. 2), his charisma played an important role in the Movement Towards Socialism’s rise to power, contributing, for example, to the efforts of attracting non-indigenous voters. However, if Correa’s and Chávez’s election should be primarily ascribed, along with other contextual factors, to their personal abilities to convince the electorate, in Bolivia the 2005 election of Morales is instead unequivocally linked to the constant rapid strengthening of the indigenous-peasant social movement. Cameron (Reference Cameron2009: 334) observes, for example, that ‘Whereas Chávez won office before mobilising his supporters, and his success has been largely based on promising to improve the lot of the poor within a resource-rich society, Morales was swept into power by indigenous social movements.’ As noted by a member of the Bartolinas on the relationship between Morales and social movements, ‘all alone the president cannot do anything’.Footnote 40 Morales can thus be viewed as the representative of social forces able to determine, in any moment, the fate of his government and presidency.

The survival of the government is, in particular, closely associated with the support of four indigenous-peasant organizations: the CSUTCB, the Cocaleros, the Bartolinas and the CSCIB. The crucial role of these social organizations is evident if we consider that the Movement Towards Socialism and these organizations are not two separate entities. The Movement Towards Socialism is the result of the social movements’ decision in 1995 to create a ‘political instrument’ to compete in electoral contests. Various members of these organizations play leading roles in the party and are present in the national assembly, primarily as representatives of the social organizations supporting the government. Rather than an autonomous party, the Movement Towards Socialism can be viewed as the electoral ‘instrument’ of social movements, an instrument that loses its raison d’être without their support. More generally, it is possible to argue that the entire political project that culminated with the election of Morales – an election posing a symbolic end to centuries of indigenous exploitation – would become meaningless without the support of the aforementioned indigenous-peasant organizations. For Morales it would be highly problematic to justify a rupture with these organizations and, at the same time, maintain his image as the champion of indigenous and popular sectors.

It should also be noted that since the 1990s these highly organized and structured organizations have demonstrated a significant mobilization capacity, as demonstrated by their involvement in highly consequential mobilizations, leading, for example, to the fall of two presidents. The vulnerability of the government to the mobilization and defection of indigenous-peasant organizations has translated into the social movements’ ability to influence the agenda of the government. The facts influencing the government’s decision to terminate fuel subsidies (gasolinazo) in December 2010 are indicative. Initially determined to cut fuel subsidies by a governmental decree, the government was forced to repeal this measure following days of popular protests resulting from a significant increase in petrol prices. As well as the opposition of several other organizations, of particular relevance was the fact that discontent and ambiguous reactions involved even the social core of the Morales government, including the coca growers and leaders of the CSUTCB, jeopardizing the survival of the government (Mayorga Reference Mayorga2011). A crucial factor behind the protests was the government’s decision not to involve social organizations in the decision-making process, as had occurred on previous occasions (Mayorga Reference Mayorga2011). Interestingly, rather than curbing their autonomy, the links with the executive, combined with their importance in the government coalition, have provided social movements with an instrument to effectively challenge the government.

Undoubtedly, Morales does not merely receive demands from below without trying to influence them. As noted by Anria (Reference Anria2010), though accountable to social organizations, Morales enjoys significant power within the Movement Towards Socialism, a party, Anria (Reference Anria2010) argues, where bottom-up mobilization and cooptation attempts have coexisted. More generally, as suggested by Wolff (Reference Wolff2013: 45–6), limitations have marked social movements’ participation in decision-making. However, the firm intention of the indigenous-peasant organizations to participate in the most important decisions, combined with the vulnerability of the government to their defection and mobilization, has drastically reduced the government’s room for manoeuvre in the creation of participatory mechanisms, thus favouring a more democratic participatory outcome.

Conclusions

This study has identified crucial conditions influencing the democratic qualities of participatory mechanisms and has shown how participatory mechanisms may contribute to the concentration of power and hence to the consolidation of hybrid political regimes. The findings of this study have important implications for theories of participatory democracy, for a further understanding of the left in Latin America, and for a better appreciation of the risks and opportunities of the deepening of democracy.

What emerges from this analysis is that when properly designed and implemented, participatory mechanisms can effectively resist the democratizing effects of autonomous, active or contentious civil societies. The recognition of these largely neglected properties is important in the elaboration of a theory able to explain participatory mechanisms’ ambiguous outcomes. In particular, significant attention needs to be devoted to the foundational moment and the relationship between those demanding participation and those creating participatory mechanisms.

Moreover, this study sheds further light on the differences within the Latin American radical left and on the prospects of alternative forms of democracy in Latin America. In particular, it shows that, unlike the Bolivian case and despite important progress in the area of socioeconomic rights, in Ecuador and Venezuela participatory mechanisms have not favoured the goals of the deepening of democracy, thus undermining the idea that these countries are possibly transitioning from liberal towards alternative, participatory forms of democracy.

Finally, the identification of the conditions favouring the manipulation of participatory mechanisms contributes to the recent strand of literature examining the undemocratic use of democratic institutions. The subtle ability of apparently democratic, participatory instruments to accumulate power in the executive is particularly worrisome because it seems to fit perfectly what Levitsky and Way (Reference Levitsky and Way2010: 16–19) describe as an international environment increasingly unfavourable to openly autocratic practices. As observed by Mainwaring (Reference Mainwaring2012: 963–4), the supposedly democratic character of participatory mechanisms can help governments ‘skirt international pressures for democracy’. By shedding light on the undemocratic manipulation of participatory mechanisms, an area still largely unexplored, this study contributes to a better understanding of the risks and opportunities of the deepening of democracy.

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Philip J. Williams, Michael Bernhard and the anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments. Any mistakes or omissions are mine.

Footnotes

*

Claudio Balderaccchi served as Adjunct Lecturer at the University of Florida Center for Latin American Studies. Contact email: balderacchic@gmail.com.

1 The presence/absence of demands for participation should be distinguished from what Wampler (Reference Wampler2007: 256) defines as the ‘willingness of CSOS [civil society organizations] to engage in contentious politics’. Civil society organizations can be contentious, for example to obtain material benefits (e.g. salary increases), without claiming a more general, consistent participation in public decision-making.

2 The concept of government’s vulnerability considered in this article refers to the government’s vulnerability vis-à-vis domestic civil society actors. It is hence different from Levitsky and Way’s (Reference Levitsky and Way2010: 40–1) concept of ‘governments’ vulnerability to external democratizing pressure’ (‘western leverage’) – a variable these authors use to explain the trajectory of ‘competitive authoritarian’ regimes – referring, instead, to the external pressure originating from international actors.

3 Author’s translation of ‘avance más importante en materia de participación’.

4 On this last topic, see Schedler (Reference Schedler2010) and Levitsky and Way (Reference Levitsky and Way2010).

5 On the potentially negative impact of PB on municipal councils, see Wampler (Reference Wampler2004).

6 An exception is Zaremberg (Reference Zaremberg2012).

7 See note 1 above.

8 See note 2 above.

9 For an analysis of participation in Bolivia, Ecuador and Venezuela, see also De la Torre (Reference De la Torre2013a). According to De la Torre (Reference De la Torre2013a), the ‘strength of subaltern organizations’ at the beginning of Chávez’s, Correa’s and Morales’s era is an important factor to explain the top-down (Ecuador and Venezuela) rather than predominantly bottom-up (Bolivia) nature of participation in these countries.

10 García-Guadilla (Reference García-Guadilla2008: 141) argues that the autonomy of the Communal Councils is the result of different factors including the ‘vulnerability of the members of the CC to the political pressures to join the PSUV or the reserves’ and the ‘dependence on state resources’. In reality, as noted below, the features of the Communal Councils and their members are not random given the government’s ability to select likely passive and less autonomous Communal Councils through the registration requirement. Author’s translation of ‘vulnerabilidad de los miembros que componen el CC a las presiones políticas para que se inscriban, en el PSUV o en las reservas’ and ‘dependencia de los recursos del Estado’.

11 According to Wampler (Reference Wampler2007: 258, Fig. 2), ‘CSOS’ [civil society organizations] willingness to use contentious politics’ is an important factor to explain participatory budgeting’s democratic performance.

12 Author’s translation of ‘denuncias y casos’ and ‘considerable’.

13 Interview with two members of an unregistered Communal Council, Caracas, Venezuela, February 2011.

14 García-Guadilla (Reference García-Guadilla2008: 141–2) presents evidence that pressures to join the Venezuelan United Socialist Party and discriminations under the guise of bureaucratic pretexts have also characterized the distribution of resources.

15 On this point, particularly in connection with the certification issue, see also Álvarez and García-Guadilla (Reference Álvarez and García-Guadilla2011: 190–1).

16 Author’s translation of ‘la construcción de la sociedad socialista’. Law available at: www.mpcomunas.gob.ve/publicaciones/ley_comunas_2010.pdf (accessed 7 March 2012).

17 Author’s translation of ‘espacio socialista’.

18 On different notions of democracy existing within civil society groups before Chávez’s rise to power, including the neighbourhood movement, see also García-Guadilla (Reference García-Guadilla2007: 143).

19 For the transfer of functions from the state to CSOS during the neoliberal era in Venezuela, see also Fernandes (Reference Fernandes2010: 70–1).

20 Interview with a high-ranking official of the Ministry for the Communes and Social Movements, Caracas, Venezuela, March 2011. Author’s translation of ‘La organización popular en la democracia representativa no eran mas que organizaciones de resistencia’.

21 Under the 1998 constitution the legislative body appointed the predecessor of the National Electoral Council (CNE) and Tribunal Contencioso Electoral (TCE) – that is, the Electoral Supreme Court. Following the 2008 constitution, in the electoral function the National Electoral Council and the Tribunal Contencioso Electoral – whose members are appointed through the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control selection procedures – replaced the Electoral Supreme Court.

22 The technical committee is appointed by the Council of Citizen Participation and Social Control’s plenum.

23 On the weakness of the opposition to explain the absence of mobilization mechanisms similar to those in Venezuela and Bolivia, see also De la Torre (Reference De la Torre2013a).

24 Author’s translation of ‘si hay justicia en nuestra sociedad lo correcto sería que [Chiriboga Zambrano] nos acompañe como fiscal’.

25 Author’s translation of ‘una democracia verdaderamente representativa y participativa’.

26 As noted in Página12 (2005), Correa explicitly proclaimed himself a forajido during his tenure as minister.

27 Author’s translation of ‘desde abajo’.

28 On the loss of organizational capacity resulting from the rupture between PK and some urban leading members in December 2005, see Ramírez Gallegos (Reference Ramírez Gallegos2010: 27–8).

29 Electoral data available at: http://cne.gob.ec/es/institucion/procesos-electorales/elecciones (accessed 21 February 2015).

30 See note 29.

31 For an opposite reasoning on the 2002 election, see Zamosc (Reference Zamosc2007: 20).

32 See note 29.

33 See note 29.

34 These mechanisms are defined as informal because they were not created by any law, resulting instead from the government’s participatory practices.

35 Interview with a member of the Bolivian government, La Paz, Bolivia, May 2011.

36 Interview with leading member of the Bartolinas, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011.

37 Interview with leading member of the Bartolinas, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011. Interview with leading member of the CSCIB, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011.

38 Interview with leading member of the CSCIB, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011.

39 Interview with leading member of the CSCIB, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011. Author’s translation of ‘estructural y continua’.

40 Interview with member of the Bartolinas, La Paz, Bolivia, April 2011. Author’s translation of ‘solito no va a poder hacer nada el presidente’.

References

Acosta, A. (2005), ‘Ecuador: ecos de la rebellion de los forajidos’, Nueva Sociedad, 198: 4254.Google Scholar
Álvarez, R. and García-Guadilla, M. (2011), ‘Contraloría social y clientelismo: la praxis de los Consejos Comunales en Venezuela’, Politeia, 34(46): 175207.Google Scholar
Anria, S. (2010), ‘Bolivia’s MAS: Between Party and Movement’, in M. Cameron and E. Hershberg (eds), Latin America’s Left Turns: Politics, Policies, and Trajectories of Change (Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner): 101125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arditi, B. (2008), ‘Arguments about the Left Turns in Latin America: A Post-Liberal Politics?’, Latin American Research Review, 43(3): 5981.Google Scholar
Armas, M. (2010), ‘Presupuesto de las regiones se reducirá el proximo año’, El Universal, 28 August, www.eluniversal.com/2010/08/28/eco_art_presupuesto-de-las-r_2020316.shtml (accessed 7 March 2012).Google Scholar
Baiocchi, G., Heller, P. and Silva, M. (2011), Bootstrapping Democracy: Transforming Local Governance and Civil Society in Brazil (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).Google Scholar
Becker, M. (2012), ¡Pachakutik! Indigenous Movements and Electoral Politics in Ecuador, updated edn (Plymouth: Rowman & Littlefield).Google Scholar
Blyde, G. (2010), ‘Dónde están los reales?’, El Universal, 29 October, www.eluniversal.com/opinion/101029/donde-estan-los-reales (accessed 7 March 2012).Google Scholar
Burbano de Lara, F. (2010), ‘La ciudadania en la “revolucion ciudadana”: tensiones y contradicciones del proceso ecuatoriano’, in I. Cheresky (ed.), Ciudadanos y politica en los albores del siglo XXI (Buenos Aires: Manantial): 199221.Google Scholar
Cameron, M. (2009), ‘Latin America’s Left Turns: Beyond Good and Bad’, Third World Quarterly, 30(2): 331348.Google Scholar
Cameron, M., Hershberg, E. and Sharpe, K. (2012), ‘Voice and Consequence: Direct Participation and Democracy in Latin America’, in M. Cameron, E. Hershberg and K. Sharpe (eds), New Institutions for Participatory Democracy in Latin America: Voice and Consequence (New York: Palgrave Macmillan): 120.Google Scholar
Canache, D. (2007), ‘Chavismo and Democracy in Venezuela’, paper presented at the Symposium on ‘Prospects for Democracy in Latin America’, University of North Texas, April 5–6, 2007, www.psci.unt.edu/canache.doc (accessed 13 August 2012).Google Scholar
Ciccariello-Maher, G. (2013), We Created Chávez (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
El Comercio (2011a), ‘3 aspirantes a fiscal, cercanos al oficialismo’, 8 February, www.elcomercio.com/politica/aspirantes-Fiscal-cercanos-oficialismo_0_423557784.html (accessed 17 February 2012).Google Scholar
El Comercio (2011b), ‘Dudas sobre la calificación de Chiriboga’, 17 April, www.elcomercio.com/politica/Dudas-calificacion-Chiriboga_0_464353594.html (accessed 18 July 2012).Google Scholar
El Comercio (2011c), ‘Los veedores también criticaron el concurso’, 20 April, www.elcomercio.com/politica/veedores-criticaron-concurso_0_466153418.html (accessed 18 July 2012).Google Scholar
El Comercio (2011d), ‘La Participación Ciudadana es un Proyecto en Riesgo’, 4 July, www.elcomercio.com/politica/participacion-ciudadana-proyecto-riesgo_0_510549017.html (accessed 18 July 2012).Google Scholar
El Comercio (2012), ‘Tribunal afín al régimen juzgará los comicios’, 11 June, www.elcomercio.com/politica/Contencioso-Electoral-Regimen-juzgara-infracciones_0_715728476.html (accessed 23 July 2012).Google Scholar
Conaghan, C. (2008), ‘Ecuador: Correa’s Plebiscitary Presidency’, Journal of Democracy, 19(2): 4660.Google Scholar
Consejo de Participación Ciudadana y Control Social (n.d.), ‘Nuestra institución’, www.cpccs.gob.ec/?mod=somos (accessed 4 October 2014).Google Scholar
De la Torre, C. (2013a), ‘In the Name of the People: Democratization, Popular Organizations, and Populism in Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador’, European Review of Latin American and Caribbean Studies, 95: 2748.Google Scholar
De la Torre, C. (2013b), ‘Technocratic Populism in Ecuador’, Journal of Democracy, 24(3): 3346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ecuadorinmediato.com (2011), ‘Karina Guerrero insiste en cuestionar capacidad de comision para elegir al fiscal’, 18 May, www.ecuadorinmediato.com/index.php?module=Noticias&func=news_user_view&id=149972&umt=karina_guerrero_insiste_en_cuestionar_capacidad_comision_para_elegir_al_fiscal (accessed 26 July 2012).Google Scholar
Ellner, S. (2009), ‘The “Top-Down” and “Bottom-Up” Approach of the Chávez Movement and Government’, paper presented at the 2009 Meeting of the Latin American Studies Association, http://lasa.international.pitt.edu/members/congress-papers/lasa2009/files/EllnerSteve.pdf (accessed 13 August 2012).Google Scholar
Fernandes, S. (2010), Who Can Stop the Drums? Urban Social Movements in Chávez’s Venezuela (Durham, NC: Duke University Press).Google Scholar
Fiscalia General del Estado (n.d.), ‘Competencias de los Fiscales de acuerdo a su jerarquía’, www.fiscalia.gob.ec/index.php/quienes-somos/competencias-de-los-fiscales.html (accessed 17 July 2013).Google Scholar
García-Guadilla, M. (2007), ‘Social Movements in a Polarized Setting: Myths of Venezuelan Civil Society’, in S. Ellner and M. Tinker Salas (eds), Venezuela: Hugo Chávez and the Decline of an ‘Exceptional Democracy’ (Plymouth: Rowman & Littlefield): 140154.Google Scholar
García-Guadilla, M. (2008), ‘La praxis de los consejos comunales en Venezuela: ¿Poder Popular o Instancia Clientelar?’, Revista Venezolana de Economía y Ciencias Sociales, 14(1): 125151.Google Scholar
Goldfrank, B. (2007), ‘Lessons from Latin America’s Experience with Participatory Budgeting’, in A. Shah (ed.), Participatory Budgeting, World Bank Public Sector Governance and Accountability Series (Washington, DC: World Bank): 91126.Google Scholar
Goldfrank, B. (2011), Deepening Local Democracy in Latin America: Participation, Decentralization, and the Left (University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press).Google Scholar
Harten, S. (2011), The Rise of Evo Morales and the MAS (London: Zed Books).Google Scholar
Hawkins, K. (2010), ‘Who Mobilizes? Participatory Democracy in Chávez’s Bolivarian Revolution’, Latin American Politics and Society, 52(3): 3166.Google Scholar
Hawkins, K., Patch, J., Anguiano, A. and Seligson, M. (2008), ‘Political Culture of Democracy in Venezuela: 2007’, www.vanderbilt.edu/lapop/venezuela/2007-politicalculture.pdf (accessed 4 April 2014).Google Scholar
Hidalgo, M. (2009), ‘Hugo Chávez’s “Petro-Socialism”’, Journal of Democracy, 20(2): 7892.Google Scholar
Hoy (2011), ‘Preocupa injerencia de Rafael Correa a favor de G. Chiriboga’, 26 April, http://ecuadorinmediato.com/index.php?module=Noticias&func=news_user_view&id=148412&umt=hoy_28quito29_preocupa_injerencia_de_rafael_correa_a_favor_de_g_chiriboga (accessed 4 September 2015).Google Scholar
Lander, E. (2007), ‘Venezuelan Social Conflict in a Global Context’, in S. Ellner and M. Tinker Salas (eds), Venezuela: Hugo Chávez and the Decline of an Exceptional Democracy (Plymouth: Rowman & Littlefield): 1632.Google Scholar
Levine, D. and Crisp, B. (1999), ‘Venezuela: The Character, Crisis, and Possible Future of Democracy’, World Affairs, 161(3): 123165.Google Scholar
Levitsky, S. and Roberts, K. (2011), ‘Introduction: Latin America’s “Left Turn”: A Framework for Analysis’, in S. Levitsky and K. Roberts (eds), The Resurgence of the Latin American Left (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press): 128.Google Scholar
Levitsky, S. and Way, L. (2010), Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes after the Cold War (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
López Maya, M. and Lander, L. (2011), ‘Participatory Democracy in Venezuela: Origins, Ideas, and Implementation’, in D. Smilde and D. Hellinger (eds), Venezuela’s Bolivarian Democracy: Participation, Politics, and Culture under Chávez (Durham, NC: Duke University Press): 5879.Google Scholar
Lovera, A. (2008), ‘Los Consejos Comunales en Venezuela: ¿Democracia participativa o delegativa?’, Revista Venezolana de Economía y Ciencias Sociales, 14(1): 107124.Google Scholar
Lucero, J. (2008), Struggles of Voice: The Politics of Indigenous Representation in the Andes (Pittsburgh: Pittsburgh University Press).Google Scholar
Madrid, R. (2011), ‘Bolivia: Origins and Policies of the Movimiento al Socialismo’, in S. Levitsky and K. Roberts (eds), The Resurgence of the Latin American Left (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press): 239259.Google Scholar
Madrid, R. (2012), The Rise of Ethnic Politics in Latin America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Mainwaring, S. (2012), ‘From Representative Democracy to Participatory Competitive Authoritarianism: Hugo Chávez and Venezuelan Politics’, Perspectives on Politics, 10(4): 955967.Google Scholar
Mayorga, F. (2005), ‘La izquierda campesina e indigena en bolivia: el Movimiento al Socialismo (MAS)’, Revista Venezolana de Ciencia Politica, 28 (July–December): 91119.Google Scholar
Mayorga, F. (2011), ‘Escenarios políticos post gasolinazo’, Conversatorio de análisis politico, PNUD Bolivia and FBDM, Santa Cruz, 4 April, http://www.gobernabilidad.org.bo/images/stories/documentos/analisis_politico/escenarios_politico_post_gasolinazo_fernando_mayorga.pdf (accessed 11 November 2012).Google Scholar
McNulty, S. (2011), Voice and Vote: Decentralization and Participation in Post-Fujimori Peru (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meneses, D. (2011), ‘A 2.400 Consejos Comunales se les Niega el Registro Formal’, El Universal, 1 August, www.eluniversal.com/2011/08/01/a-2400-consejos-comunales-se-les-niega-el-registro-formal.shtml (accessed 9 June 2012).Google Scholar
Mijeski, K. and Beck, S. (2008), ‘The Electoral Fortunes of Ecuador’s Pachakutik Party: The Fracaso of the 2006 Presidential Elections’, The Latin Americanist, 52(2): 4159.Google Scholar
Montalvo, E. (2010), ‘La politica marcó la hoja de ruta del consejo . . .’, El Comercio, 14 March, www.elcomercio.com/noticias/politica-marco-hoja-ruta-Consejo_0_224977666.html (accessed 28 July 2012).Google Scholar
Montecinos, E. (2012), ‘Democracia y presupuesto participativo en América Latina: La mutación del presupuesto participativo fuera de Brasil’, Revista del CLAD Reforma y Democracia, 53: 121.Google Scholar
Página12 (2005), ‘Un asilo que se consumó entre gallos y medianoche’, 25 April, www.pagina12.com.ar/diario/elmundo/4-50183-2005-04-25.html (accessed 15 July 2013).Google Scholar
Paley, J. (2001), Marketing Democracy: Power and Social Movements in Post-Dictatorship Chile (Berkeley: University of California Press).Google Scholar
Pazmiño, C. (2005), ‘La frágil legitimidad del príncipe democrático’, Iconos, 23: 2736.Google Scholar
Provea (2010), Situación de los derechos humanos en Venezuela: informe anual Octubre 2009/Septiembre 2010 (Caracas: Provea).Google Scholar
Radio Nacional de Venezuela (2013), ‘Estas Son las Cifras Oficiales del Censo Comunal 2013’, 17 September, www.rnv.gob.ve/index.php/estas-son-las-cifras-oficiales-del-censo-comunal-2013 (accessed 7 February 2015).Google Scholar
Ramírez Gallegos, F. (2010), ‘Fragmentación, reflujo, y desconcierto. Movimientos sociales y cambio político en el Ecuador (2000–2010)’, OSAL, 11(28): 1747.Google Scholar
Roberts, K. (1998), Deepening Democracy? The Modern Left and Social Movements in Chile and Peru (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press).Google Scholar
Salamanca, L. (2004), ‘Civil Society: Late Bloomers’, in J. McCoy and D. Myers (eds), The Unraveling of Representative Democracy in Venezuela (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press): 93114.Google Scholar
Schedler, A. (2010), ‘Authoritarianism’s Last Line of Defense’, Journal of Democracy, 21(1): 6980.Google Scholar
Schneider, C. and Welp, Y. (2011), ‘Transformación Democrática o Control Politico? Análisis Comparado de la participación ciudadana institucional en America del Sur’, Iconos: Revista de Ciencias Sociales, 40: 2139.Google Scholar
Smilde, D. (2009), ‘Three Stages in the Chávez Government’s Approach to Participation’, in A. Stubis (ed.), Understanding Populism and Political Participation, Woodrow Wilson Center Update on the Americas No. 3, www.wilsoncenter.org/sites/default/files/Venezuela.pdf (accessed 4 September 2015).Google Scholar
Unda, M. (2005), ‘Región Andina: Quito en abril: los forajidos derrotan al coronel’, OSAL, 6(16): 129139.Google Scholar
El Universal (2011), ‘Ojeda Denuncia Exclusion de Consejos Comunales’, Caracas, 29 January, www.eluniversal.com/2011/01/29/pol_art_ojeda-denuncia-exclu_2176258.shtml (accessed 4 June 2012).Google Scholar
El Universo (2011), ‘Allegados al oficialismo, al frente del máximo organismo electoral’, 20 November, www.eluniverso.com/2011/11/20/1/1355/allegados-oficialismo-frente-maximo-organismo-electoral.html (accessed 18 July 2012).Google Scholar
Van Cott, D. (2008), Radical Democracy in the Andes (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Villarruel, P. (2011), ‘Ministro Vera respalda a Chiriboga para fiscalia’, El Universo, 14 March, www.eluniverso.com/2011/03/04/1/1355/ministro-vera-respalda-chiriboga-fiscalia.html (accessed 7 March 2012).Google Scholar
Wampler, B. (2004), ‘Expanding Accountability through Participatory Institutions: Mayors, Citizens, and Budgeting in Three Brazilian Municipalities’, Latin American Politics and Society, 46(2): 7399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wampler, B. (2007), Participatory Budgeting in Brazil: Contestation, Cooperation, and Accountability (University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press).Google Scholar
Wilpert, G. (2007), Changing Venezuela by Taking Power: The Histories and Policies of the Chávez Government (London: Verso).Google Scholar
Wolff, J. (2013), ‘Towards Post-Liberal Democracy in Latin America? A Conceptual Framework Applied to Bolivia’, Journal of Latin American Studies, 45(1): 3159.Google Scholar
Zamosc, L. (2007), ‘The Indian Movement and Political Democracy in Ecuador’, Latin American Politics and Society, 49(3): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaremberg, G. (2012), ‘“We’re Either Burned or Frozen Out”: Society and Party Systems in Latin American Municipal Development Councils (Nicaragua, Venezuela, Mexico, and Brazil)’, in M. Cameron, E. Hershberg and K. Sharpe (eds), New Institutions for Participatory Democracy in Latin America: Voice and Consequence (New York: Palgrave Macmillan): 2151.Google Scholar