Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-lnqnp Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T12:10:36.197Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Some stochastic comparisons of lower records and lower record spacings

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 January 2022

Narayanaswamy Balakrishnan
Affiliation:
Department of Mathematics and Statistics, McMaster University, Hamilton, Canada
Antonia Castaño-Martínez
Affiliation:
Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Cádiz, Cádiz, Spain
Miguel A. Sordo
Affiliation:
Department of Statistics and Operations Research, University of Cádiz, Cádiz, Spain. E-mail: mangel.sordo@uca.es
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We obtain here sufficient conditions for increasing concave order and location independent more riskier order of lower record values based on stochastic comparisons of minimum order statistics. We further discuss stochastic orderings of lower record spacings. In particular, we show that increasing convex order of adjacent spacings between minimum order statistics is a sufficient condition for increasing convex order of adjacent spacings of their lower records.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

Let $X$ be a continuous random variable with distribution function $F,$ survival function $\bar {F}=1-F$ and quantile function $F^{-1}(p)=\inf \{x\in \mathbb {R} \,| \, F(x)\ge p\}, p\in (0,1)$. For $k=1,\ldots,n,$ let $X_{k:n}$ be the $k$th order statistic from an independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) random sample $X_1,X_2,\ldots,X_n,$ drawn from $X$. A large body of literature has been devoted to the study of order statistics, which includes numerous characterizations of probability distributions and applications to a wide range of problems, such as statistical estimation, inferential procedures and analysis of censored samples. Order statistics are also important in the context of life testing and reliability models, where they describe lifetimes of $k$-out-of-$n$ systems. Reviews on theoretical results and applications can be found in the books by Arnold et al. [Reference Arnold, Balakrishnan and Nagaraja3], David and Nagaraja [Reference David and Nagaraja23], and the two volume by Balakrishnan and Rao [Reference Balakrishnan and Rao8,Reference Balakrishnan and Rao9].

Let $X_1,X_2,\ldots$ be a sequence of independent random variables having the same distribution as $X$. Then, we say that $X_j$ is a lower record value if it is less than all the previous values of the sequence. Lower record values appear in a natural way in many practical situations. In meteorological analysis, for example, they describe sequences of successive coldest temperatures. In portfolio management, lower record values describe sequences of successive lowest stock market figures, which is of great interest to investors and financial institutions. Similar applications can be given in industrial stress testing, seismology or sporting events. Some important references on records include the books by Ahsanullah [Reference Ahsanullah2], Arnold et al. [Reference Arnold, Balakrishnan and Nagaraja4] and Nevzorov [Reference Nevzorov32]. The indices at which the lower record values occur are given by the record times $\{L_n\}_{n\ge 1}$, where $L_1=1$ and

$$L_n=\min\{j: \; j>L_{n-1}, \; X_j< X_{L_{n-1}}\}, \quad n\ge 2.$$

We denote $R_j=X_{L_j}$ as the $j$th lower record value of the sequence. As the record times of the sequence $\{X_i\}_{i\ge 1}$ are the same as those for the sequence $\{F(X_i)\}_{i\ge 1}$ and that $F(X)$ has a uniform distribution, it is clear that the distribution of $L_n$, $n\ge 1$, does not depend on $F$.

It has been observed in the literature (see CharalambidesFootnote 1, [Reference Charalambides22]) that $R_j$ can be represented as a minimum order statistic from a sequence of i.i.d. random variables whose sample size is random, that is, $R_j=X_{1:L_{j}}$. Because $X_{1:n}$ is independent of the event $\{L_j=n\}$, for $n\ge j$ [Reference Nevzorov32] p. 114, the distribution of $R_j=X_{1:L_j}$ can be represented as a countable mixture, mixing the distribution of the $j$th record time with the distribution of minimum order statistic. One purpose of this paper is to use this mixture representation to provide sufficient conditions for stochastic orderings of records based on stochastic orderings of minimum order statistics. Some other results on stochastic comparisons of record values can be found in Kochar [Reference Kochar28,Reference Kochar29], Ahmadi and Arghami [Reference Ahmadi and Arghami1], Khaledi and Shojaei [Reference Khaledi and Shojaei26], Khaledi et al. [Reference Khaledi, Amiripour, Hu and Shojaei27] and Zhao and Balakrishnan [Reference Zhao and Balakrishnan37]. As record values are particular cases of generalized order statistics (GOS), some results on stochastic comparisons of GOS are valid for record values as well (see, e.g., [Reference Balakrishnan, Belzunce, Sordo and Suárez-Llorens11,Reference Belzunce, Mercader and Ruiz15]).

We first briefly introduce the stochastic orders that are pertinent to the work in this paper.

Definition 1. Let $X$ and $Y$ be two random variables with respective distribution functions $F$ and $G$, and let $\bar {F}=1-F$ and $\bar {G}=1-G,$ be the corresponding survival functions. We say that $X$ is smaller than $Y$

  1. (a) in stochastic order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm st}}Y,$ if $\bar {F}(x)\le \bar {G}(x),$ for all $x$;

  2. (b) in increasing concave order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm icv}}Y,$ if

    $$\int_{-\infty}^{t}F(x)\,dx \geq \int_{-\infty}^{t}G(x)\,dx,\quad \text{for all }t;$$
  3. (c) in increasing convex order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm icx}}Y,$ if

    $$\int_{\mathrm{t}}^{+\infty} \bar{F}(x) \,d x \leq \int_{\mathrm{t}}^{+\infty} \bar{G}(x) \,d x, \quad \text{for all } t ;$$
  4. (d) in dispersive order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm disp}}Y,$ if

    $$F^{{-}1}(p)-F^{{-}1}(q)\le G^{{-}1}(p)-G^{{-}1}(q), \quad \text{for all } 0< q< p<1;$$
  5. (e) in location independent riskier order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y,$ if

    $$\int_{-\infty}^{F^{{-}1}(p) }F(x)\,dx \leq \int_{-\infty}^{G^{{-}1}(p) }G(x)\,dx, \quad \text{for all }p\in (0,1).$$

For various properties and applications of these orders, we refer the readers to the books by Shaked and Shanthikumar [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33], Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Martínez-Riquelme and Mulero17] and Müller and Stoyan [Reference Müller and Stoyan31]. It is well-known that $X\le _{{\rm st}}Y$ implies $X\le _{{\rm icx}}Y$ and $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ and that $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ if and only if $-X\ge _{{\rm icx}}-Y$. It is also well-known that $X\le _{{\rm disp}}Y$ implies $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$. When the random variables $X$ and $Y$ have a common left endpoint of their supports, then $X\le _{{\rm disp}}Y$ implies $X\le _{{\rm st}}Y$, and $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ implies $X\le _{{\rm st}}Y$ (see [Reference Sordo36]). It will be useful in the sequel to note (see [Reference Jewitt25]) that $X\le _{{\rm lir}} Y$ if and only if

(1) \begin{equation} H(u)=\frac{1}{u}\int_0^{u} (F^{{-}1}(t)-G^{{-}1}(t))\,dt \text{ is non-increasing in } u\in (0,1). \end{equation}

Using (3.B.6) in Shaked and Shanthikumar [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33], it is easy to see that

(2) \begin{equation} X\le_{{\rm disp}}Y\Longleftrightarrow(F^{{-}1}(p)-X)^{+}\le_{{\rm st}} (G^{{-}1}(p)-Y)^{+}, \quad \text{for all } p\in (0,1), \end{equation}

where $(x)^{+}=\max \{x,0\}$. Moreover, since $X \le _{{\rm lir}} Y \Leftrightarrow -X\le _{\rm ew} -Y,$ where $\le _{\rm ew}$ denotes the excess wealth order (see Section 3.C.1 of [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33]), it follows from Theorem 4.A.43 in [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33] that

(3) \begin{equation} X\le_{{\rm lir}} Y \Longleftrightarrow (F^{{-}1}(p)-X)^{+}\le_{{\rm icx}} (G^{{-}1}(p)-Y)^{+}, \quad \text{for all }p\in (0,1). \end{equation}

Using the same argument, it follows from Proposition 3 in Belzunce [Reference Belzunce13] that when the random variables $X$ and $Y$ have a common right endpoint of their supports, then $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ implies $X\ge _{{\rm icv}}Y$. In particular, if $u_X$ and $u_Y$ denote the right endpoints of the supports of $X$ and $Y,$ it follows that

(4) \begin{equation} X\le_{{\rm lir}} Y \quad \text{and}\quad u_X=u_Y \Longrightarrow E[Y]\le E[X], \end{equation}

a result that will be used in Example 3.

Let $X_1,X_2,\ldots$ be a sequence of independent random variables having the same distribution as $X$ and let $Y_1,Y_2,\ldots$ be another sequence of independent random variables having the same distribution as $Y$. Let $R_s(X)$ and $R_s(Y),\ s\ge 1,$ be the corresponding $s$th lower record values of the two sequences. Sufficient conditions on $X$ and $Y$ under which $R_s(X)$ and $R_s(Y)$ are ordered by the orders $\le _{{\rm st}}, \le _{{\rm icv}},\le _{{\rm disp}}$ and $\le _{{\rm lir}}$ can be immediately derived from well-known results for generalized order statistics and for upper records (see Section 3.7.2 in the book by Belzunce et al., [Reference Belzunce, Martínez-Riquelme and Mulero17], for a review). In particular, it follows from Theorem 4.14 in Balakrishnan et al. [Reference Balakrishnan, Belzunce, Sordo and Suárez-Llorens11] that $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ implies $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm icv}} R_s(Y)$, and from Theorem 5.2(a) in Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Hu and Khaledi14] that $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ implies $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_s(Y)$ for $s\ge 1$. Note, however, that when the conditions $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ and/or $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ do not hold, the orderings $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm icv}} R_s(Y)$ and/or $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_s(Y)$ are still possible. This motivates us to study new sufficient conditions (weaker than $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ and $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$) under which the lower record values $R_s(X)$ and $R_s(Y)$ are ordered for a certain range of values of $s$. The new sufficient conditions, which are stated in Section 2, are given in terms of comparisons of minimum order statistics. As $X\le _{{\rm icv}}Y$ (respectively, $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$) implies $X_{1:n}\le _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:n}$ (respectively, $X_{1:n}\le _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n}$), for $n=1,2,\ldots,$ and the reverse implications do not hold, our results can be useful for comparing lower records in terms of $\le _{{\rm icv}}$ and $\le _{{\rm lir}}$ when $X$ and $Y$ fail to be ordered. Let us now present an example of two random variables $X$ and $Y$ such that $X\nleq _{{\rm icv}}Y$ and $X_{1:2}\le _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:2}$.

Example 2. For $i=1,2,$ let $Z_i\sim W(\alpha _i, \beta _i), \alpha _i>0, \beta _i>0,$ be two Weibull random variables with survival functions $\overline {F_i}(t)=e^{- ({t}/{\alpha _i})^{\beta _i}}$, $t>0,$ and expectations $E[Z_i]=\alpha _i \Gamma (1+{1}/{\beta _i})$. It is well-known (see Table 1.1 in [Reference Müller and Stoyan31]) that

(5) \begin{equation} \beta_1 \leq \beta_2 \text{ and } E[Z_1]\le E[Z_2] \text{ implies } Z_1\le_{{\rm icv}}Z_2. \end{equation}

Consider, in particular, $X\sim W(1, \frac {1}{3})$ and $Y\sim W(2,1)$. Because

$$\int_{0}^{100}[1-e^{{-}x^{{1}/{3}}}]\,d x=94,95$$

and

$$\int_{0}^{100}[1-e^{-{x}/{2}}]\,d x=98,$$

it follows that $X\nleq _{{\rm icv}}Y$. Moreover, it is easy to see that $X_{1:2}\sim W(\frac {1}{8},\frac {1}{3})$ and $Y_{1:2}\sim W(1, 1)$ with expectations $E[X_{1:2}]=\frac {3}{4}$ and $E[Y_{1:2}]=1.$ Thus, it follows from (5) that $X_{1:2}\le _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:2}$.

Next, we provide an example of two random variables $X$ and $Y$ such that $X\nleq _{{\rm lir}}Y$ and $X_{1:2}\le _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:2}$.

Example 3. Let $X_1$ and $X_2$ be uniform random variables, $X_1\sim U(\frac {1}{4},\frac {1}{2})$ and $X_2\sim U(\frac {1}{2},1),$ with distribution functions $F_1(x)$ and $F_2(x),$ respectively. Now, let $X$ be a random variable with distribution function $F(x)=\frac {3}{4}F_1(x)+\frac {1}{4}F_2(x)$ and $Y$ be a standard uniform random variable, $Y\sim U(0,1)$. Because $X$ and $Y$ have a common right endpoint of their supports and $E(X)=\frac {15}{32}< E(Y)=\frac {1}{2}$, it follows from (4) that $X\nleq _{{\rm lir}} Y$. The distribution function $F_{1:2}$ of $X_{1:2}$ is

$$F_{1:2}(x)=\left\{\begin{array}{ll} 0, & x<1/4 \\ 1- (\dfrac{7}{4}-3x)^{2}, & 1/4\le x <1/2 \\ 1-\dfrac{1}{4}(1-x)^{2}, & 1/2\le x <1 \\ 1, & x\ge 1. \end{array}\right.$$

Figure 1 shows that the function

$$H_{1:2}(u)=\frac{1}{u}\int_0^{u} (F_{1:2}^{{-}1}(t)-G_{1:2}^{{-}1}(t))\,d t$$

decreases in $u\in (0,1),$ which implies from (1) that $X_{1:2}\leq _{{\rm lir}} Y_{1:2}$.

FIGURE 1. $H_{1:2}(u)$ as a function of $u$ for Example 3.

Another purpose of this paper is to provide sufficient conditions for the comparison of spacings between minimum order statistics drawn from samples of different sizes and for the comparison of spacings of lower records. The time elapsed between two consecutive records is sometimes as important as the record itself and it is related to the variability of the random variable. Given two i.i.d. samples of $X$ of sizes $n$ and $n+k,$ $k\ge 1,$ the number $\Delta _{1,n,k}=E[X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}]$ is a measure of variability of the left-tail of $X$. As

$$\Delta_{1,n,k}=E[X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}]=\int_{0}^{1}F^{{-}1}(t)\,d(A(t)-B(t)),$$

where $A(t)=1-(1-t)^{n},$ $B(t)=1-(1-t)^{n+k}$ and $AB^{-1}(t)$ is convex, $\Delta _{1,n,k}$ belongs to the class $C_1$ of risk measures studied by Sordo [Reference Sordo35]. As these measures are consistent with dispersive order of $X$ and $Y$ (Theorem 8 in [Reference Sordo35]), a natural question that arises is under what conditions $X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}$ and $Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+k}$ are stochastically ordered? We address this question in Section 3, where it is also established that increasing convex order (respectively, increasing concave order) of adjacent spacings of $X$ and $Y$ is a sufficient condition for increasing convex order (respectively, increasing concave order) of adjacent spacings of their records. Some other works dealing with stochastic comparisons of spacings of GOS and records are due to Hu and Zhuang [Reference Hu and Zhuang24], Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Lillo, Ruiz and Shaked16,Reference Belzunce, Martínez-Riquelme, Ruiz and Sordo18] , Zhao et al. [Reference Zhao, Li, Li and Xu38] and Zhuang and Hu [Reference Zhuang and Hu39]. Stochastic comparisons of relative spacings have also been discussed in the literature by Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Martínez-Riquelme, Ruiz and Sordo19] and Castaño-Martínez et al. [Reference Castaño-Martínez, Pigueiras and Sordo21]. Applications of stochastic comparisons of minimum order statistics in welfare theory have been illustrated recently by Castaño-Martínez et al. [Reference Castaño-Martínez, Pigueiras, Psarrakos and Sordo20].

2. Sufficient conditions for orderings of lower records

In this section, we use the fact that $R_s$ can be represented as a mixture of minima to provide sufficient conditions for the stochastic comparison of lower records. The first result shows that the increasing concave order of $X_{1:n}$ and $Y_{1:n}$ implies the increasing concave order of the lower records $R_s(X)$ and $R_s(Y)$, for $s =n, n+1,\ldots$.

Theorem 4. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. If $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:n},$ then $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm icv}} R_s(Y)$, for $s =n, n+1,\ldots$

Proof. From Lemma 5 in Castaño-Martínez et al. [Reference Castaño-Martínez, Pigueiras, Psarrakos and Sordo20], if $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:n}$, then $X_{1:s}\leq _{{\rm icv}}Y_{1:s,}$ for $s\geq n$. The result follows from the fact that $R_s(X)=X_{1:L_s}$, where $L_s$ is a random variable with support $\{s,s+1,s+2,\ldots \},$ and the known property that increasing concave order is closed under mixtures (Theorem 4.A.8.b in [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33]).

Remark 5. By applying Theorem 4 to $-X$ and $-Y$ instead of to $X$ and $Y$, which transforms lower records to upper records and increasing concave order to increasing convex order, it follows that $X_{n:n}\leq _{{\rm icx}}Y_{n:n}$ implies $\tilde {R}_s(X)\leq _{{\rm icx}} \tilde {R}_s(Y)$, for $s=n,n+1, \ldots$ where $\tilde {R}_s$ denotes the $s$th upper record value. This result strengthens Theorem 4.14 in Balakrishnan et al. [Reference Balakrishnan, Belzunce, Sordo and Suárez-Llorens11] which is for the case $n=1$.

Next, to provide sufficient conditions for comparisons of lower records in location independent riskier order, we need the following lemma.

Lemma 6. Let $n\geq 1$ and $1\le k\le n$. If $X_{k:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:n}$, then $X_{k:n+r}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:n+r}$, for all $r\geq 1$.

Proof. The condition $X_{k:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:n}$ is equivalent (see, e.g., Eq. (6) in [Reference Sordo36]) to

(6) \begin{equation} \int_{0}^{p}( F^{{-}1}_{k:n}(p)-F^{{-}1}_{k:n}(t) )\, dt\le \int_{0}^{p}(G^{{-}1}_{k:n}(p)- G^{{-}1}_{k:n}(t) )\,dt,\quad p\in (0,1), \end{equation}

where $F^{-1}_{k:n}(t)$ and $G^{-1}_{k:n}(t)$ are the quantile functions of $X_{k:n}$ and $Y_{k:n},$ respectively. As

$$F^{{-}1}_{k:n}(t)=F^{{-}1}( \beta^{{-}1}_{k,n-k+1}(t),\quad t \in (0,1),$$

where $\beta _{i,j}$ is Pearson's incomplete beta function (and similarly for $G^{-1}_{k:n}(t)$), we see, by change of variable $x=\beta ^{-1}_{k,n-k+1}(t)$, that (6) is equivalent to

\begin{align*} & \int_{0}^{ \beta^{{-}1}_{k,n-k+1}(p) } ( F^{{-}1}( \beta^{{-}1}_{k,n-k+1}(p) ) - F^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d \beta_{k,n-k+1}(x) \\ & \quad \leq \int_{0}^{\beta^{{-}1}_{k,n-k+1}(p) } (G^{{-}1}( \beta^{{-}1}_{k,n-k+1}(p) ) -G^{{-}1}(x) )\,d \beta_{k,n-k+1}(x), \ p\in ( 0,1). \end{align*}

This shows that $X_{k:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:n}$ is equivalent to

(7) \begin{align} & \int_{0}^{ p }(F^{{-}1}(p) - F^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d \beta_{k,n-k+1}(x) \nonumber\\ & \quad \leq \int_{0}^{p} (G^{{-}1}(p) -G^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d \beta_{k,n-k+1}(x), \ p\in ( 0,1) \end{align}

or, equivalently,

$$\int_{0}^{p} ( G^{{-}1}(p) -G^{{-}1}(x) - F^{{-}1}(p) + F^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d \beta_{k,n-k+1}(x) \ge 0, \quad p\in ( 0,1).$$

Given $r=1,2,\ldots$, the function

$$h(x)=\left\{\begin{array}{ll} \dfrac{(n+r)! (n-k)!}{n!(n+r-k)!}(1-x)^{r}, & t\in (0,p], \\ 0, & t\in (p,1), \end{array}\right.$$

is non-negative and decreasing. It then follows from Lemma 7.1(b) in Chapter 4 of Barlow and Proschan [Reference Barlow and Proschan12] that

$$\int_{0}^{p} ( G^{{-}1}(p) -G^{{-}1}(x) - F^{{-}1}(p) + F^{{-}1}(x) ) h(x) \,d\beta_{k,n-k+1}(x)\geq 0, \quad p\in (0,1).$$

As $({d\beta _{k,n+r-k+1}}/{d\beta _{k,n-k+1}})(x)=h(x)$, we obtain

\begin{align*} & \int_{0}^{p}(F^{{-}1}(p) - F^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d\beta_{k,n+r-k+1}(x) \\ & \quad \leq \int_{0}^{p} (G^{{-}1}(p) - G^{{-}1}(x) ) \,d \beta_{k,n+r-k+1}(x),\quad \text{for all }p\in (0,1), \end{align*}

which, using (7) again, is the same as $X_{k:n+r}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:n+r}$.

The next result shows that location independent riskier order of $X_{1:n}$ and $Y_{1:n}$ is a sufficient condition for location independent riskier order of lower records $R_s(X)$ and $R_s(Y),$ for $s =n, n+1,\ldots$. Observe, however, that as location independent riskier order is not, in general, closed under mixtures, we cannot use the same argument as in Theorem 4 for establishing this result.

Theorem 7. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G.$ If $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n},$ then $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_s(Y)$, for $s =n, n+1,\ldots$

Proof. Let $F_{1:n}(x)$ be the distribution function of $X_{1:n}$. Then, we can express

$$F_{1:n+r}(x)=h_r ( F_{1:n}(x)), \quad r=1,2,\ldots,$$

where $h_r(t)=1-(1-t)^{{(n+r)}/{n}}, \ 0\le t \le 1,$ is an increasing concave function such that $h_r:[0,1]\rightarrow [0,1],$ $h_r(0)=0$ and $h_r(1)=1$. Now, let $s=n,n+1,\ldots$. As $R_s(X)=X_{1:L_s},$ where $L_s$ is a random variable with support $\{s,s+1,s+2,\ldots \},$ the distribution function $F_{R_s}(x)$ of $R_s(X)$ can be expressed as

(8) \begin{align} F_{R_s}(x)& = \sum_{r=0}^{\infty} F_{1:s+r}(x)P[L_s=s+r] \nonumber\\ & =\sum_{r=0}^{\infty} h_r(F_{1:s}(x) )P[L_s=s+r] \nonumber\\ & = H_s ( F_{1:s}(x)), \end{align}

where

(9) \begin{equation} H_s(t)=\sum_{r=0}^{\infty} h_r (t)P[L_s=s+r], \quad s=n,n+1,\ldots, \end{equation}

is an increasing concave function such that $H_s:[0,1]\rightarrow [0,1],$ $H_s(0)=0$ and $H_s(1)=1$. Moreover, since $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n}$, it follows from Lemma 6 that $X_{1:s}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:s},$ for $s=n,n+1,\ldots$. Now, by applying Theorem 2.1(ii) in Shaked et al. [Reference Shaked, Sordo and Suárez-Llorens34], it follows that

$$\int_{-\infty}^{F_{1:s}^{{-}1}(p) }H_s(F_{1:s}(x))\,dx \leq \int_{-\infty}^{G_{1:s}^{{-}1}(p) }H_s(G_{1:s}(x))\,dx, \quad p\in (0,1),\ s=n,n+1,\ldots,$$

which can be rewritten as

\begin{align*} & \int_{-\infty}^{F_{1:s}^{{-}1}(H_s^{{-}1}(p))}H_s(F_{1:s}(x))\,dx \\ & \quad \leq \int_{-\infty}^{G_{1:s}^{{-}1}(H_s^{{-}1}(p))}H_s(G_{1:s} (x))\,dx, \quad p\in (0,1), s=n,n+1,\ldots. \end{align*}

Using (8), this is equivalent to

$$\int_{-\infty}^{F_{R_s}^{{-}1}(p) }F_{R_s}(x)\,dx \leq \int_{-\infty}^{G_{R_s}^{{-}1}(p)}G_{R_s} (x)\,dx, \quad \forall p\in (0,1), \ s=n,n+1,\ldots,$$

which implies $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_s(Y), \ s=n,n+1,\ldots$, as required.

Remark 8. In particular, by taking $n=1$ in Theorem 7, we have that $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ implies $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_s(Y)$, for $s\ge 1$. This also follows, by using the same argument as in Remark 5, from Theorem 5.2.(a) in Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Hu and Khaledi14].

3. Increasing convex ordering of spacings of partial minima and lower records

In this section, we provide sufficient conditions for stochastic comparisons of spacings of partial minima and lower records. For establishing the main results, we need the following lemma.

Lemma 9. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$. Then, for $1\le j< m$ and $p\in (0,1),$

$$[F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:m}\mid X_{1:j}=F^{{-}1}(p)]\, \stackrel{d}{=} \, (F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:m-j})^{+},$$

where $\stackrel {d}{=}$ denotes “equal in distribution”.

Proof. Given $y\ge 0,$ we have

\begin{align*} P(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:m}\le y\mid X_{1:j}=F^{{-}1}(p)) & = P(X_{1:m}\ge F^{{-}1}(p)- y\mid X_{1:j}=F^{{-}1}(p))\\ & = (\bar{F}(F^{{-}1}(p)-y))^{m-j}\\ & = P((F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:m-j})^{+}\le y), \end{align*}

where the second equality follows from the fact that

$$P(X_{1:m}>x\,|\,X_{1:j}=F^{{-}1}(p)) = \left\{\begin{array}{ll} (\bar{F}(x))^{m-j}, & x< F^{{-}1}(p)\\ 0, & x\ge F^{{-}1}(p). \end{array}\right.$$

Now, we show that if $X$ and $Y$ are ordered in dispersive order, then $X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}$ and $Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+k}$ are ordered in the usual stochastic order.

Theorem 10. Let $X_1,X_2,\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_1,Y_2,\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. If $X\le _{{\rm disp}} Y$, then

$$X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}\le_{{\rm st}} Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+k}, \quad \text{for } n\ge 1 \text{ and } k\ge 1.$$

Proof. It is easy to see that $X\le _{{\rm disp}} Y$ holds if and only if $X_{1:k}\le _{{\rm disp}} Y_{1:k}$, for $k=1,2,\ldots$. From (2), it follows that

$$(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k})^{+}\le_{{\rm st}} (G^{{-}1}(p)-Y_{1:k})^{+}, \quad \text{for all } p\in (0,1) \text{ and } k\ge 1,$$

where we have used the fact that $F_{1:k}^{-1}(p)=F^{-1}(1-(1-p)^{1/k})$. Let $y>0$, $n\ge 1$ and $k\ge 1$. Then, by using Lemma 9, we see that

\begin{align*} P(X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+k}\le y) & = \int_0^{1} P(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:n+k} \le y\mid X_{1:n}=F^{{-}1}(p))\,d\beta_{1,n}(p) \\ & = \int_0^{1} P((F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k})^{+} \le y)\,d\beta_{1,n}(p)\\ & \ge \int_0^{1} P((G^{{-}1}(p)-Y_{1:k})^{+} \le y)\,d\beta_{1,n}(p) \\ & =P(Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+k}\le y), \end{align*}

where the inequality follows from (2). This proves the required result.

Remark 11. For random variables with equal left-end support points, the dispersive order implies the usual stochastic order (see Theorem 3.B.13 in [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33]). Therefore, a natural question that arises is whether the assumption $X\le _{{\rm disp}}Y$ in Theorem 10 can be replaced by $X\le _{{\rm st}}Y$. In general, the answer is no. To see this, let us consider two Power random variables $X \sim {\rm Pow}(1)$ and $Y \sim {\rm Pow}(2),$ with respective survival functions $\bar {F}(x)=1-x$ and $\bar {G}(x)=1-x^{2}, \ x\in (0,1)$. Then, $X\leq _{{\rm st}}Y$ but $X\nleq _{{\rm disp}}Y$ (see Theorem 3.B.14 in [Reference Shaked and Shanthikumar33]). Straightforward calculations show that

(10) \begin{equation} E[X_{1:1}-X_{1:2}]=\tfrac{1}{6}>E[Y_{1:1}-Y_{1:2}]=\tfrac{2}{15}. \end{equation}

Therefore, $X_{1:1}-X_{1:2}\nleq _{{\rm st}} Y_{1:1}-Y_{1:2}$.

Next, we provide sufficient conditions for increasing convex ordering of spacings of partial minima and lower records. The following theorem shows that location independent riskier order of $X_{1:n}$ and $Y_{1:n}$ is a sufficient condition for increasing convex order of the spacings $X_{1:j}-X_{1:k}$ and $Y_{1:j}-Y_{1:k},$ whenever $k-j\ge n$.

Theorem 12. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. Furthermore, let $n\ge 1$. If $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n},$ then

$$X_{1:j}-X_{1:k} \leq_{{\rm icx}} Y_{1:j}-Y_{1:k}, \quad \text{for } j\ge 1 \text{ and } k-j\ge n.$$

Proof. Let $1\le j < k$. Using Lemma 9, we can write

\begin{align*} P(X_{1:j}-X_{1:k}>y) & = \int_0^{1} P(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k} > y\mid X_{1:j}=F^{{-}1}(p))\,d\beta_{1,j}(p)\\ & = \int_0^{1} P[(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k-j})^{+}> y]\,d\beta_{1,j}(p)\\ & = \int_0^{1} \bar{F}_{{(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k-j})^{+}}}(y)\,d\beta_{1,j}(p),\quad y>0. \end{align*}

The assumption $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n}$ implies, via Lemma 6, that $X_{1:r}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:r},$ for $r\ge n$. By (3), this is equivalent to

$$(F_{1:r}^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:r})^{+}\le_{{\rm icx}} (G_{1:r}^{{-}1}(p)-Y_{1:r})^{+}, \quad \text{for all }p\in (0,1).$$

Upon using the fact that $F_{1:r}^{-1}(p)=F^{-1}(1-(1-p)^{1/r}),$ we see that $X_{1:r}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:r}$ is equivalent to $(F^{-1}(p)-X_{1:r})^{+}\le _{{\rm icx}} (G^{-1}(p)-Y_{1:r})^{+}$, for all $p\in (0,1)$ and $r\ge n$. This implies that

$$\int_s^{+\infty}\bar{F}_{{(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:r})^{+}}}(y)\,dy \le \int_s^{+\infty}\bar{G}_{{(G^{{-}1}(p)-Y_{1:r})^{+}}}(y)\,dy,\quad \text{for all }s > 0.$$

Therefore,

$$\int_{0}^{1} \int_s^{+\infty}\bar{F}_{{(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:k-j})^{+}}}(y)\,dy \,d\beta_{1,j}(p) \le \int_0 ^{1}\int_s^{+\infty}\bar{G}_{{(G^{{-}1}(p)-Y_{1:k-j})^{+}}}(y)\,dy \,d\beta_{1,j}(p),$$

for all $s>0$ and $p\in (0,1)$, which implies $X_{1:j}-X_{1:k} \leq _{{\rm icx}} Y_{1:j}-Y_{1:k}$, for $k-j\ge n$.

Remark 13. For random variables with equal left-end support points, the location independent riskier order implies the usual stochastic order (see Theorem 6 in [Reference Sordo36]). It is natural to wonder whether the assumption $X_{1:n}\le _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n}$ in Theorem 12 can be replaced by $X_{1:n}\le _{{\rm st}}Y_{1:n}$. The same counterexample as in Remark 11 can be used to show that the answer is no. Recall that $X \sim {\rm Pow}(1)$ and $Y \sim {\rm Pow}(2)$. Clearly $X_{1:n}\le _{{\rm st}}Y_{1:n}$. However, since $X_{1:n}$ and $Y_{1:n}$ have the same finite support, $X_{1:n}\nleq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{1:n}$ (see Corollary 7 in [Reference Sordo36]). Moreover, it follows from (10) that $X_{1:1}-X_{1:2}\nleq _{{\rm icx}} Y_{1:1}-Y_{1:2}$.

The following theorem shows that increasing convex order (respectively, the increasing concave order) of adjacent spacings between minimum order statistics is a sufficient condition for increasing convex order (respectively, the increasing concave order) of adjacent spacings of their records.

Theorem 14. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. If

(11) \begin{equation} X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+1}\le_{{\rm icx}} Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+1}, \quad \text{for all } n\ge i, \end{equation}

then

(12) \begin{equation} R_j(X)-R_{j+1}(X)\le_{{\rm icx}} R_j(Y)-R_{j+1}(Y), \quad \text{for all } j\ge i. \end{equation}

The result remains true if $\le _{{\rm icx}}$ is replaced by $\le _{{\rm icv}}$ in both (11) and (12).

Proof. First, we prove the result for the increasing convex order. Let us rewrite (11) and (12) in a more convenient form. Let $n\ge i$ and denote by $\bar {F}_{X^{*}_{1:n}}(y)$ the survival function of $X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+1}$. Then, condition (11) is equivalent to

(13) \begin{equation} \int_s^{\infty} (\bar{G}_{{Y^{*}_{1:n}}}(y) - \bar{F}_{{X^{*}_{1:n}}}(y))\,dy \ge 0, \quad \text{for all } s. \end{equation}

Using Lemma 9, we see that

(14) \begin{align} \bar{F}_{{X^{*}_{1:n}}}(y) & = \int_0^{1} P(F^{{-}1}(p)-X_{1:n+1}>y\mid X_{1:n}=F^{{-}1}(p))n(1-p)^{n-1}\,dp\nonumber\\ & = \int_0^{1} P((F^{{-}1}(p)-X)^{+}>y)n(1-p)^{n-1}\,dp \nonumber\\ & =\int_0^{1} F(F^{{-}1}(p)-y) n(1-p)^{n-1}\,dp, \quad y\ge 0. \end{align}

Similarly,

(15) \begin{equation} \bar{G}_{{Y^{*}_{1:n}}}(y)=\int_0^{1} G(G^{{-}1}(p)-y) n(1-p)^{n-1}\,dp, \quad y\ge 0. \end{equation}

Substituting (14) and (15) in (13) and changing the order of integration by Fubini's theorem, we see that (11) is equivalent to

(16) \begin{equation} I(s,n)\ge 0, \quad \text{for all } n\ge i, \ \text{for all } s, \end{equation}

where we have denoted

$$I(s,n)=\int_0^{1} \left(\int_s^{\infty}( G(G^{{-}1}(p)-y)- F(F^{{-}1}(p)-y))\,dy\right) (1-p)^{n-1}\,dp.$$

Now, let $j\ge i$ and denote by $\bar {F}_{R^{*}_j}(y)$ the survival function of $R_j(X)-R_{j+1}(X)$. Then, condition (12) is equivalent to

(17) \begin{equation} \int_s^{\infty} (\bar{G}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y) - \bar{F}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y))\,dy \ge 0, \quad \text{for all } s. \end{equation}

Now, upong using the fact that $[R_{j+1}(X)\mid R_{j}(X)=F^{-1}(p)]\stackrel {d}{=}[X\mid X< F^{-1}(p)]$, we have

(18) \begin{align} \bar{F}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y) & =\int_0^{1} P( F^{{-}1}(p)-R_{j+1}(X)>y\mid R_{j}(X)=F^{{-}1}(p))\,d(1-\gamma_j(-\log(p))) \nonumber\\ & =\int_0^{1}\frac{F(F^{{-}1}(p)-y)}{p}\,d(1-\gamma_j(-\log(p))),\quad y\ge 0, \end{align}

where we have used the fact that the distribution function of $R_j$ is given by

$$F_{R_j}(x)=1-\gamma_j(-\log(F(x))),\quad x\in \mathbb{R}, \ j\ge 1,$$

with

$$\gamma_j(x)=\int_0^{x} \frac{t^{j-1}}{(j-1)!}e^{{-}t}\, dt,\quad x\ge 0;$$

see Arnold et al. [Reference Arnold, Balakrishnan and Nagaraja4]. As $R_j(U)=U_{1:L_j}$, where $U\sim U(0,1)$, the density of $R_j(U)$ can be expressed as

\begin{align*} f_{{R_j(U)}}(p) & = d(1-\gamma_j(-\log(p))) \\ & = \sum_{m\ge j}f_{{U_{1:m}}}(p)P(L_j=m)\\ & = \sum_{m\ge j} m(1-p)^{m-1}P(L_j=m), \end{align*}

and so

$$\frac{d(1-\gamma_j(-\log(p)))}{p}=\sum_{m\ge j}\sum_{r\ge m} m(1-p)^{r-1}P(L_j=m).$$

Substituting this expression in (18) and then changing sums to integral (justified by dominated convergence theorem), we have

(19) \begin{equation} \bar{F}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y) =\sum_{m\ge j}\sum_{r\ge m} mP(L_j=m) \int_0^{1}F(F^{{-}1}(p)-y)(1-p)^{r-1}\,dp. \end{equation}

Similarly, we have

(20) \begin{equation} \bar{G}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y) = \sum_{m\ge j}\sum_{r\ge m} mP(L_j=m) \int_0^{1}G(G^{{-}1}(p)-y)(1-p)^{r-1}\,dp. \end{equation}

Now, upon substituting (19) and (20) in (17) and changing the order of integration by Fubini's theorem, we see that (12) is equivalent to

(21) \begin{equation} \sum_{m\ge j}\sum_{r\ge m} mP(L_j=m) I(s,r) \ge 0, \quad \text{for all } s. \end{equation}

As $j\ge i,$ it is clear that (16) implies (21), which proves the required result for the increasing convex order.

To prove that the result remains true if $\le _{{\rm icx}}$ is replaced by $\le _{{\rm icv}}$ in both (11) and (12), note that

$$X_{1:n}-X_{1:n+1}\le_{{\rm icv}} Y_{1:n}-Y_{1:n+1}, \quad \text{for all } n\ge i,$$

is equivalent to

$$\int_{-\infty}^{s} (\bar{G}_{{Y^{*}_{1:n}}}(y) - \bar{F}_{{X^{*}_{1:n}}}(y))\,dy \ge 0, \quad \text{for all } s,$$

whereas

$$R_j(X)-R_{j+1}(X)\le_{{\rm icv}} R_j(Y)-R_{j+1}(Y), \quad\text{for all } j\ge i,$$

is equivalent to

$$\int_{-\infty}^{s} (\bar{G}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y) - \bar{F}_{{R^{*}_j}}(y))\,dy \ge 0, \quad \text{for all } s.$$

The proof for the increasing concave order follows upong replacing the integral between $s$ and $\infty$ by the integral between $-\infty$ and $s$ along the proof for the increasing convex order.

Remark 15. In particular, from Theorems 12 (with $n=1$) and 14 (with $i=1$), we see that $X\le _{{\rm lir}}Y$ implies $R_j(X)-R_{j+1}(X)\le _{{\rm icx}} R_j(Y)-R_{j+1}(Y)$, for $j\ge 1$. This also follows by applying Corollary 4.1 in Belzunce et al. [Reference Belzunce, Martínez-Riquelme, Ruiz and Sordo18] to $-X$ and $-Y$ instead of to $X$ and $Y$, which transforms upper records to lower records and excess wealth order to location independent riskier order.

Using arguments similar to those used in the proofs of Theorems 12 and 14, we can obtain the following result, for which we omit the proof for the sake of conciseness.

Theorem 16. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. Let $j\ge 1$. If $R_j(X)\le _{{\rm lir}} R_j(Y)$, then

$$R_s(X)-R_{m}(X)\le_{{\rm icx}} R_s(Y)-R_{m}(Y), \quad \text{for } s\ge 1\text{ and } m-s\ge j.$$

Remark 17. We use the same counterexample as in Remarks 11 and 13 to show that the assumption $R_j(X)\le _{{\rm lir}} R_j(Y)$ cannot be replaced, in general, by $R_j(X)\le _{{\rm st}} R_j(Y)$. It is well-known that if $V\sim {\rm Pow}(\alpha )$, with $\alpha >0$, their corresponding lower records can be expressed as $R_n(V)=\prod _{i=1}^{n} V_i$, with $\{V_i\}_{i\ge 1}$ being independent random variables with the same distribution as $V$ (see [Reference Arnold, Balakrishnan and Nagaraja4]). Then, $E[R_n(V)]=(E[V])^{n}=({\alpha }/{(\alpha +1)})^{n}$ and

$$E[R_1(V)-R_2(V)]=\frac{\alpha}{(\alpha + 1)^{2}}.$$

Now, let $X \sim {\rm Pow}(1)$, $Y \sim {\rm Pow}(2)$ and $j=1$. It is then easy to check that $R_1(X)\leq _{{\rm st}} R_1(Y)$, but

$$E[R_1(X)-R_2(X)]=\tfrac{1}{4}>E[R_1(Y)-R_2(Y)]=\tfrac{2}{9},$$

which implies that $R_1(X)-R_2(X)\nleq _{{\rm icx}} R_1(Y)-R_2(Y)$.

4. Further remarks

In the proof of Theorem 7, we have used the property that the distribution function of $R_s(X)$ can be expressed as an increasing and concave distortion of the distribution function of $X_{1:s}$. This fact can also be utilized to establish ordering conditions for lower record values in terms of some other stochastic orderings. For illustrating this point, for example, we present the following results.

Definition 18. Let $X$ and $Y$ be two non-negative random variables with respective distribution functions $F$ and $G$, and let $\bar {F}=1-F$ and $\bar {G}=1-G,$ respectively, be their survival functions. We say that $X$ is smaller than $Y$

  1. (a) in total time on test transform order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm ttt}}Y,$ if

    $$\int_0^{F^{{-}1}(p)}\bar{F}(x)\,dx \leq \int_ 0^{G^{{-}1}(p)}\overline{ G}(x)\,dx, \quad \text{for all }p\in (0,1);$$
  2. (b) in quantile mean inactivity time order, denoted by $X\leq _{{\rm qmit}}Y$, if

    $$\frac{\int_{0}^{F^{{-}1}(p) }F(x)\,dx}{\int_{0}^{G^{{-}1}( p) }G(x)\,dx}\quad \text{decreases in }p \in (0,1).$$

For references on these orders, see Kochar et al. [Reference Kochar, Li and Shaked30] and Arriaza et al. [Reference Arriaza, Sordo and Suárez-Llorens6]. We then have the following result.

Theorem 19. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be non-negative i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$. Similarly, let $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be non-negative i.i.d. as $Y$ with distribution function $G$. Furthermore, let $n\ge 1$.

  1. (a) If $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm ttt}}Y_{1:n},$ then $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm ttt}} R_s(Y)$, for $s=n,n+1,\ldots$;

  2. (b) If $X_{1:n}\leq _{{\rm qmit}}Y_{1:n},$ then $R_s(X) \leq _{{\rm qmit}} R_s(Y)$, for $s=n,n+1,\ldots$.

Proof. First, we observe that $\bar {F}_{1:s}(x)=h_s^{*}(\bar {F}_{1:n}(x))$, with $h_s^{*}(t)=t^{s/n}$ being an increasing convex function for $s\ge n$, such that $h_s^{*}:[0,1]\rightarrow [0,1]$, $h_s^{*}(0)=0$ and $h_s^{*}(1)=1$. Then, using Theorem 1 and Remark 2 in [Reference Arriaza and Sordo5], we have $X_{1:s}\leq _{{\rm ttt}}Y_{1:s}$ and $X_{1:s}\leq _{{\rm qmit}}Y_{1:s}$, for $s\ge n$, respectively.

On the other hand, let $s\ge n$. It then follows from (8) that

$$\bar{F}_{R_s}(x)=H^{*}_s ( \bar{F}_{1:s}(x)),$$

with $H^{*}_s(t)=1-H_s(1-t)$ (where $H_s$ is as in (9)) is an increasing convex function such that $H^{*}_s:[0,1]\rightarrow [0,1],$ $H^{*}_s(0)=0$ and $H^{*}_s(1)=1$. Then, the required results follow from Theorem 1 and Remark 2 of Arriaza and Sordo [Reference Arriaza and Sordo5].

A further observation regarding $k$th lower records is the following. In the continuous case, $k$th lower record values obtained from $X\sim F$, denoted by $R_j^{(k)}(X)$ (or $R_j^{(k)} (F)$), are distributed exactly as a sequence of ordinary lower records from the distribution $F_{k:k}(x)= (F(x))^{k}$, $R_j(F_{k:k})$. Using similar arguments as those used in the proofs of Lemma 6, Remark 8 and Theorem 16, we can then state the following results.

Theorem 20. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. If $X_{k:k}\leq _{{\rm lir}}Y_{k:k},$ then $R_j^{(k')}(X) \leq _{{\rm lir}} R_j^{(k')}(Y),$ for $j\ge 1$ and $1\le k'\le k$.

Theorem 21. Let $X_{1},X_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $X$ with continuous distribution function $F$, and $Y_{1},Y_{2},\ldots$ be i.i.d. as $Y$ with continuous distribution function $G$. Let $j\ge 1$ and $k\ge 1$. If $R^{(k)}_j(X)\le _{{\rm lir}} R^{(k)}_j(Y),$ then

$$R^{(k')}_s(X)-R^{(k')}_{m}(X)\le_{{\rm icx}} R^{(k')}_s(Y)-R^{(k')}_{m}(Y), \quad \text{for } s\ge 1, \ m-s\ge j, \ 1\le k'\le k.$$

One more remark before ending this work. Balakrishnan and Mi [Reference Balakrishnan and Mi7] and Balakrishnan et al. [Reference Balakrishnan, Brain and Mi10] have shown that the ordering satisfied by the two underlying distributions implies the ordering of the maximum likelihood estimates of the parameters arising from samples from the two distributions. A similar question can be asked in the present context about the estimation of distributional parameters based on lower record values having been observed from the two distributions. This is an open problem that we plan to consider as our future work.

Acknowledgments

We are thankful to the anonymous referees for their helpful comments. N.B. thanks the support received from the Natural Sciences and Engineering Research Council of Canada through an individual discovery grant. A.C.M. and M.A.S acknowledge support received from the Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación (Spain) under grant PID2020-116216GB-I00 and from the 2014–2020 ERDF Operational Programme and the Department of Economy, Knowledge, Business and University of the Regional Government of Andalusia under grant FEDER-UCA18-107519.

Conflicts of interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Footnotes

1 Charalambides, in fact, represents the distribution of the $k$th upper record value as a countable mixture, mixing the distribution of the $k$th record time with the distribution of the maximum order statistics.

References

Ahmadi, J. & Arghami, N.R. (2001). Some univariate stochastic orders on record values. Communications in Statistics – Theory and Methods 30: 6974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahsanullah, M. (1995). Record statistics. New York: Nova Science Publishers.Google Scholar
Arnold, B.C., Balakrishnan, N., & Nagaraja, H.N. (1992). A first course in order statistics. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Arnold, B.C., Balakrishnan, N., & Nagaraja, H.N. (1998). Records. New York: John Wiley & Sons.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriaza, A. & Sordo, M.A. (2021). Preservation of some stochastic orders by distortion functions with application to coherent systems with exchangeable components. Applied Stochastic Models in Business and Industry 37: 303317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arriaza, A., Sordo, M.A., & Suárez-Llorens, A. (2017). Comparing residual lives and inactivity times by transform stochastic orders. IEEE Transactions on Reliability 66: 366372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balakrishnan, N. & Mi, J. (2001). Order-preserving properties of maximum likelihood estimator. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 98: 8999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balakrishnan, N. & Rao, C.R. (Eds.) (1998). Handbook of statistics 16-order statistics: Theory and methods. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Balakrishnan, N. & Rao, C.R. (Eds.) (1998). Handbook of statistics 17-order statistics: Applications. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Balakrishnan, N., Brain, C., & Mi, J. (2002). Stochastic order and MLE of the mean of the exponential distribution. Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 4: 8393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balakrishnan, N., Belzunce, F., Sordo, M.A., & Suárez-Llorens, A. (2012). Increasing directionally convex orderings of random vectors having the same copula and their use in comparing ordered data. Journal of Multivariate Analysis 105: 4554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlow, R.E. & Proschan, F. (1975). Statistical theory of reliability and life testing. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Belzunce, F. (1999). On a characterization of right spread order by the increasing convex order. Statistics & Probability Letters 45: 103110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belzunce, F., Hu, T., & Khaledi, B.-E. (2003). Dispersion-type variability orders. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences 17: 305334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belzunce, F., Mercader, A., & Ruiz, J.M. (2005). Stochastic comparisons of generalized order statistics. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences 19: 99120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belzunce, F., Lillo, R.E., Ruiz, J.M., & Shaked, M. (2007). Stochastic ordering of record and inter-record values. In M. Ahsanullah and M. Raqab (eds.), Recent developments in ordered random variables. New York: Nova Science Publishers, pp. 119–137.Google Scholar
Belzunce, F., Martínez-Riquelme, C., & Mulero, J. (2016). An introduction to stochastic orders. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Belzunce, F., Martínez-Riquelme, C., Ruiz, J.M., & Sordo, M.A. (2016). On sufficient conditions for the comparison in the excess wealth order and spacings. Journal of Applied Probability 53: 3346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belzunce, F., Martínez-Riquelme, C., Ruiz, J.M., & Sordo, M.A. (2017). On the comparison of relative spacings with applications. Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 19: 357376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castaño-Martínez, A., Pigueiras, G., Psarrakos, G., & Sordo, M.A. (2020). Increasing concave orderings of linear combinations of order statistics with applications to social welfare. Metrika 83: 699712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castaño-Martínez, A., Pigueiras, G., & Sordo, M.A. (2021). On the increasing convex order of relative spacings of order statistics. Mathematics 9: 618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charalambides, Ch.A. (2007). On the distribution and moments of record values in increasing populations. Journal of the Iranian Statistical Society (JIRSS) 6: 4760.Google Scholar
David, H.A. & Nagaraja, H.N. (2003). Order statistics, 3rd ed. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hu, T. & Zhuang, W. (2006). Stochastic orderings between p-spacings of generalized order statistics from two samples. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences 20: 465479.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jewitt, I. (1989). Choosing between risky prospects: The characterization of comparative statics results, and location independent risk. Management Science 35: 6070.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khaledi, B-E. & Shojaei, S.R. (2007). On stochastic orderings between residual record values. Statistics & Probability Letters 77: 14671472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khaledi, B.-E., Amiripour, F., Hu, T., & Shojaei, S.R. (2009). Some new results on stochastic comparisons of record values. Communications in Statistics – Theory and Methods 38: 20562066.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kochar, S.C. (1990). Some partial ordering results on record values. Communications in Statistics – Theory and Methods 19: 299306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kochar, S.C. (1996). A note on dispersive ordering of record values. Calcutta Statistical Association Bulletin 46: 6367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kochar, S.C., Li, X., & Shaked, M. (2002). The total time on test transform and the excess wealth stochastic orders of distributions. Advances in Applied Probability 34: 826845.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, A. & Stoyan, D. (2002). Comparison methods for stochastic models and risks. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Nevzorov, V.B. (2001). Records: Mathematical theory. Providence, RI: American Mathematical Society.Google Scholar
Shaked, M. & Shanthikumar, J.G. (2007). Stochastic orders. New York: Springer-Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaked, M., Sordo, M.A., & Suárez-Llorens, A. (2010). A class of location-independent variability order with applications. Journal of Applied Probability 47: 407425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sordo, M.A. (2008). Characterizations of classes of risk measures by dispersive orders. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 42: 10281034.Google Scholar
Sordo, M.A. (2009). On the relationship of location-independent riskier order to the usual stochastic order. Statistics & Probability Letters 79: 155157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, P. & Balakrishnan, N. (2009). Stochastic comparison and monotonicity of inactive record values. Statistics & Probability Letters 79: 566572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhao, P., Li, X., Li, Z., & Xu, M. (2008). Stochastic comparisons of spacings of record values from one or two sample sequences. Statistics 42: 167177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhuang, W. & Hu, T. (2009). Multivariate dispersive ordering of spacings of generalized order statistics. Applied Mathematics Letters 22: 968974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

FIGURE 1. $H_{1:2}(u)$ as a function of $u$ for Example 3.