Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T00:36:08.073Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Robotic capital - skill complementarity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 November 2024

Michele Battisti
Affiliation:
RCEA, University of Palermo, Palermo, Italy
Massimo Del Gatto
Affiliation:
G. d'Annunzio, University of Chieti-Pescara, Pescara, Italy; LUISS, Rome, Italy and CRENoS, Cagliari, Italy
Antonio Francesco Gravina
Affiliation:
University of Palermo, Palermo, Italy
Christopher F. Parmeter*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Miami, Carol Gables, USA
*
Corresponding author: Christopher F. Parmeter; Email: c.parmeter@bus.miami.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Relying upon an original (country-sector-year) measure of robotic capital ($RK$), we investigate the degree of complementarity/substitutability between robots and workers at different skill levels. We employ nonparametric methods to estimate elasticity of substitution patterns between $RK$ and skilled/unskilled labor over the period 1995–2009. We show that: i) on average, $RK$ exhibits less substitutability with skilled workers compared to unskilled workers, indicating a phenomenon of “RK-Skill complementarity”. This pattern holds in a global context characterized by significant heterogeneity; ii) the dynamic of “RK-Skill complementarity” has increased since the early 2000s; iii) the observed strengthening is more prominent in OECD countries, as opposed to non-OECD countries, and in the Manufacturing sector, compared to non-Manufacturing industries.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The rapid proliferation of robotization and automation over the past two decades is considered one of the most pressing challenges for the future of workers and their societal integration (e.g., Ford, Reference Ford2015; West, Reference West2018; Susskind, Reference Susskind2020). Among the major concerns voiced at academic, policy, and political levels is the potential escalation of income inequality among various types of workers.

While this concern echoes the computerization process of the late twentieth century, the advent of artificial intelligence, digital technologies, and robotics in the labor market introduces unique features. This has prompted expressions such as “Is this time different?” (e.g., Mokyr et al. 2015; Furman, Reference Furman2016; Estlund, Reference Estlund2021). Some scholars even advocate for robot taxation (Costinot & Werning, Reference Costinot and Werning2020; Guerreiro et al. Reference Guerreiro, Rebelo and Teles2022).Footnote 1

In general, the widespread increase in the utilization of skilled labor/workers (hereinafter referred to as $S$ ), relative to unskilled labor/workers (hereinafter referred to as $U$ ), is well documented. For instance, the average hours worked by $S$ increased by 6% in OECD countries during the 1995–2005 period, while hours worked by $U$ in the same period dropped by 7%. Moreover, the skilled-to-unskilled labor ratio has been growing in the World Input-Output Database, WIOD, (Timmer et al. Reference Timmer, Dietzenbacher, Los, Stehrer and De Vries2015) countries according to Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Gatto and Parmeter2022).

From a theoretical perspective, various frameworks have addressed this phenomenon. The “race between technology and education” framework, pioneered by Tinbergen, (Reference Tinbergen1974) and further explored by Goldin & Katz (Reference Goldin and Katz2009), Acemoglu & Autor (Reference Acemoglu and Autor2011), Autor et al. (2020), among many others, highlights the natural replacement of routine and repetitive tasks by technology, while more abstract duties requiring higher education are inherently more complementary. Griliches (Reference Griliches1969) discusses how the introduction of new technologies in production could lead to adjustments in the relative demand for different labor skills, which, in turn, are reflected in their relative wages. In a dynamic general equilibrium model incorporating investments in both robots and traditional capital, Berg et al. (Reference Berg, Buffie and Zanna2018) state that automation can have positive effects on growth while increasing income inequality. Similarly, Moll et al. (2021) argue that automation may exacerbate inequality in a model linking technology to personal income and wealth distribution. In the same vein, the growth model of “directed technical change”Footnote 2 proposed by Hémous & Olsen (Reference Hémous and Olsen2022) suggests that machines complement $S$ and replace $U$ , thereby intensifying wage disparities through stagnating wages for $U$ .

The contributions to understanding the divergent impact of technological progress on different types of workers have been primarily focused on two strands of literature, driven by the well-known challenge of jointly identifying technological progress and the elasticity of substitution (EoS) in production functions with both technical progress and possibility of substitution among inputs, like the generalized constant elasticity of substitution (CES) of David & Van de Klundert (Reference David and Van de Klundert1965) — a problem pioneered by Diamond et al. (Reference Diamond, McFadden and Rodriguez1978).

A substantial body of work centers on skill-biased technical change, SBTC, (Katz & Murphy, Reference Katz and Murphy1992) and the more recent routine-biased technical change, RBTC, (Autor et al. 2003). In the latter framework, the “hollowing out” effect of automation leads to the disappearance of jobs requiring a well-defined set of repetitive tasks, typically assigned to middle-skilled workers.Footnote 3 A documented “polarization process” from the 1980s reveals employment gradually clustering at the tails of the occupational skill distribution (see, for instance, Acemoglu & Autor, Reference Acemoglu and Autor2011). For instance, Jaimovich et al. (2021) illustrate how the likelihood of working in routine occupations decreased by roughly 16% between the pre-polarization and post-polarization eras.

Within the broader literature on the asymmetric effects of technological progress, this paper hones in on the specific aspect of robotization, examining the extent of complementarity/substitutability between an original measure of robotic capital (hereinafter referred to as $RK$ ), derived from data on installed industrial robots, and workers at different skill levels.

The alternative approach investigates varying degrees of substitutability of skills with (general) capital, as seen in works such as Griliches (Reference Griliches1969), Fallon & Layard (Reference Fallon and Layard1975), Duffy et al. (Reference Duffy, Papageorgiou and Perez-Sebastian2004), and Henderson (Reference Henderson2009).Footnote 4 In this respect, empirical analysis generally supports the “capital-skill complementarity” hypothesis (i.e., between capital and $S$ ).

However, a further body of literature has emerged investigating the complementarity hypothesis with specific types of capital. For instance, Krusell et al. (Reference Krusell, Ohanian, Ríos-Rull and Violante2000) disaggregate capital into structures and equipment, finding the latter to be less substitutable with $S$ . In a similar vein, focusing on developing economies, Raveh & Reshef (Reference Raveh and Reshef2016) find that only R&D capital is complementary to $S$ , while less innovative capital is complementary to $U$ . Likewise, Taniguchi & Yamada (Reference Taniguchi and Yamada2022) and Eden & Gaggl (Reference Eden and Gaggl2018) report similar results for ICT capital in a panel of OECD countries and the US, respectively. Moreover, Caselli & Manning (Reference Caselli and Manning2019) demonstrate how, under the assumption of a reduction in the relative price of investment goods driven by technological progress, capital return can drop, thereby generating higher returns for labor.

Our study aligns with the aforementioned literature strand by focusing on industrial robotization. While the extant contributions typically emphasize “robot density” (often measured as the ratio of the number of robots to hours worked or employment) and its differential impact on various workers, our paper engages in a formal analysis of the EoS. Specifically, this study represents the first attempt, to the best of our knowledge, to measure the extent of complementarity/substitutability between an original measure of $RK$ and workers at different skill levels. By focusing on this aspect, we contribute to understanding how different types of labor interact with advanced forms of capital in the production process. Consequently, our work falls within the strand of literature that examines the substitutability between production factors, specifically robotic capital versus skilled and unskilled workers.

Our empirical approach enables us to estimate EoS patterns between RK and S on one hand (denoted as $\sigma _{RK,S}$ ), and between RK and U on the other (denoted as $\sigma _{RK,U}$ ). This provides us with the capacity to draw conclusions regarding the impact of the robotization process on the $\frac{S}{U}$ . In addition, it sheds light on whether the sign of such impact aligns with the previously documented country-sector tendency of increasing the $\frac{S}{U}$ or deviates from it.

The primary analysis leverages information on installed industrial robots, sourced from the International Federation of Robotics (IFR), which is integrated with WIOD data. This integration allows us to construct a country-sector-year measure of $RK$ covering 35 countries and 17 industries over the period 1995–2009. According to this measure, the share of $RK$ has increased by approximately 40% during the years under investigation.

The country-sector-year measure of $RK$ is then utilized, in conjunction with corresponding WIOD information on labor skills, to estimate the dynamics of the country-sector patterns of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ from 1995 to 2009. While this would be a challenging task in a parametric setup, we rely on recent advances in nonparametric analysis, particularly using local polynomial estimation. Such an approach allows for direct pairwise comparison between the two elasticities at the country-sector level throughout the entire period under consideration. This provides us with the ability to study the extent to which the “RK-Skill complementarity” hypothesis, positing that robotization is more complementary (less substitutive) to $S$ (i.e., $\sigma _{RK,U} \gt \sigma _{RK,S}$ ) is supported by the data. In so doing, we add to the ongoing debate on whether robotization contributes to or opposes the documented upward dynamics in $\frac{S}{U}$ over the last decades.

Overall, our results support the “RK-Skill complementarity” hypothesis.Footnote 5 Specifically, we demonstrate that: i) robotic capital exhibits $\sigma _{RK,S} \lt \sigma _{RK,U}$ on average; ii) this tendency strengthened over the first decade of the 2000s; iii) the increase has been more pronounced in OECD than in Non-OECD countries (where the increase mainly occurred through a reduction in $\sigma _{RK,S}$ ), and in Manufacturing compared to Non-Manufacturing industries. In general, the dynamics of complementarity appears heterogeneous throughout the period under consideration. At the end of the ’00s, evidence against “RK-Skill complementarity” is still found in 28% of cases (down from 50% in the second half of the ’90s). This indicates a consistent pattern of greater relative substitutability of $U$ with respect to $RK$ .

The exposition unfolds as follows. Section 2 briefly illustrates the data and our $RK$ measure. Section 3 sets up the empirical framework. Section 4 reports our analysis and discusses the main results. Section 5 presents robustness checks and a broad validation exercise, mainly focused on comparisons with parametric estimates, also addressing the role played by price and productivity dimensions in determining the estimated EoS patterns. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

2. Data

Our analysis builds upon an integration of data on robots, sourced from International Federation of Robotics (2005, 2019), with information on worker types, capital assets and value-added, provided by WIOD (2015).Footnote 6 The IFR-WIOD merged dataset is used to obtain a measure of $RK$ (total capital is decomposed into its robotic and non-robotic components) covering 35 countries and 17 industries spanning the period 1995–2009 (8,217 observations), due to the missing information and/or coverage at 2-digit level on skill groups in the new WIOD releases, as well as the unavailability of original industrial robot prices for a number of economies (i.e., different from the US).

For data consistency, we also merge International Federation of Robotics (2019) with information collected from EU KLEMS (2009), obtaining a smaller dataset of 2,843 observations (15 countries, 17 industries, 1994–2005) which, however, allows us to decompose capital accumulation into four, instead of two, components: robotic, non-robotic, ICT, and other capital (the detailed coverage is reported in Section C of the Appendix).

Differently from the past automation/robotization literature that uses a “robot density” variable, relying on crude stocks of robots (weighted by workers), our main indicator of interest is a novel $RK$ value, which is specifically designed to be used within the framework of production function estimations, and built upon two main elements: the prices and stock of industrial robots. It is obtained as follows (see Graetz & Michaels (Reference Graetz and Michaels2018), for a similar methodology). As for the industrial robots, information on the number of operating robots and deliveries (i.e., newly installed robots in the year) is retrieved from “World Robotics: Industrial Robots and Service Robots” (International Federation of Robotics, 2019), and used to compute the robot stock at time $t$ , for each country-sector pair, through the perpetual inventory method assuming a depreciation rate of 10 percent.Footnote 7 Specifically, we calculate $R^{S}_{ci,t}=R^{D}_{ci,t}+(1-\delta )R^{S}_{ci,t-1}$ , where $c$ , $i$ , and $t$ represent country, industry, and year, respectively; $R^{S}$ and $R^{D}$ denote, respectively, the stock and deliveries of robots, whereas $\delta$ is the depreciation rate. Consequently, $RK$ , is obtained as:

\begin{equation*} RK_{ci,t}= \frac {R^{P}_{c,t}*R^{S}_{ci,t}}{D^{K}_{ci,t}}, \end{equation*}

where $D^K$ is the (total) capital deflator, drawn from WIOD (2015) or EU KLEMS (2009), and $R^{P}$ represents the (country-specific) average unit price of industrial robots, which has been manually collected from several annual IFR reports.Footnote 8 It is worth noting that IFR provides robot prices (in current thousand dollars) only for Japan, US, Germany, Italy, Republic of Korea, United Kingdom and France for a limited number of years. The procedure to define and assign the most appropriate robot price for the other economies in our samples follows a criterion of geographical and economic proximity. Specifically, robot prices for economies with missing data are imputed relying on the average available price of countries within the same continent. The detailed description of this procedure is reported in Section A of the Appendix. While this approach may be more suitable for OECD countries, it is important to acknowledge that: i) these countries constitute the majority of our sample, and ii) the nonparametric estimation framework employs the ratio of production function derivatives, effectively smoothing the potential measurement errors by weighting the EoS numerator (i.e., the $S$ set) in relation to the denominator (i.e., the $U$ set).

Furthermore, from WIOD (2015), we draw data on: Total capital ( $TotK$ ), allowing us to obtain non- $RK$ as $NRK_{ci,t}=TotK_{ci,t}-RK_{ci,t}$ , as well as information on high- (i.e., $S$ ), medium- and low-skilled workers (i.e., $U$ ), expressed in terms of hours worked, hourly wages, hours and income shares, depending on the specific estimated models.Footnote 9 Ultimately, from EU KLEMS (2009), we also collect information on ICT capital, $IK$ , which allows us to calculate the “other” capital stock as $OK_{ci,t}=TotK_{ci,t}-RK_{ci,t}-IK_{ci,t}$ . $RK$ and all variables used throughout the empirical analysis are expressed in real terms, as PPP-adjusted 2005 international dollars, using the PPP conversion factor from Inklaar & Timmer (Reference Inklaar and Timmer2014). Detailed descriptive statistics are reported in Section D of the Appendix.

2.1 Robotic capital penetration

Similarly to what happened for the diffusion of computers in the ’80s and early ’90s (see, for instance, Brynjolfsson, Reference Brynjolfsson1993), the spread of robots occurs through increasing quantities and decreasing prices. This is evident in Figure 1, which reports the evolution of number of robots (panel (a)) and robot prices (panel (b)) in the US (the only country for which IFR provides a longer time-series on prices), also in relative terms with respect to employees (panel (c)) and wages (panel (d)), respectively. In particular, the measure reported in panel (b) of Figure 1, basically an indicator of “robot density,” points to a 90% increase, alongside with a decrease of approximately 80% in the unit price of robots, relative to the price of labor (i.e., average wages, in panel (d)), during the years 1995–2009.

Figure 1. Robot diffusion, 1995–2009 and 1995–2018, USA.

Elaboration on IFR and WIOD data.

In Figure 2, we compare the time evolution of our $RK$ variable with that of other forms of capital (including $IK$ , $OK$ and $TotK$ ), provided by EU KLEMS (2009) for a subset of countries and up to year 2005. With the exception of ICT capital ( $IK$ , which does not include robots),Footnote 10 the trend of $RK$ has been much more pronounced than $OK$ and $TotK$ .Footnote 11 This provides a clear picture about the strength of penetration of automation and digital technologies within the production process. However, Figure 3 shows how the average share of $RK$ (with respect to total capital) in the period is in general quite low: about 2.5–3% in Japan, Spain, Italy and Germany, and particularly in wood products, electronics, and transport equipment industries (labeled as $Wo$ , $El$ and $Tr$ , respectively).Footnote 12 In any case, this does not diminish the relevance our analysis, whose focus is on the type of patterns followed by the extent of complementarity/substitutability between robots and different types of labor over the period under consideration, in order to shed light on the expected sign of the labor impact of robotization, in perspective.

Figure 2. Evolution of robotic capital and other forms of capital: % growth rates, 1994–2005 (1994 = 1).

Elaboration on IFR and EUKLEMS data.

Figure 3. Share of robotic capital (% of total capital) in the more robotized countries and industries, 1995–2009, average values.

Elaboration on IFR and EU KLEMS data.

In this respect, it is noteworthy that, despite a lower reported $RK$ share for the US compared to many other developed countries over the 1994–2005 period, a dramatic expansion in this indicator (growing by more than four times) is observed in the US economy from 2006 to 2018. This was presumably due to a halving of the average unit price of robots (see panel (c) in Figure 1). Since the share of $RK$ has recorded an average value of about 1% (with peaks of 3% in the computer, electronics, and optical industry, and 5% in the transport equipment sector), while for $IK$ (whose price level declined by about 40%) an average share of approximately 8% is documented, data (available upon request) point to a 8:1 proportion between $IK$ and $RK$ growth in the US. This is also evident in Figure E1 in the Appendix, reporting the evolution of our $RK$ measure for a subset of countries and sectors.

3. Estimation strategy

To assess the skill complementarity of $RK$ , we estimate the (country-sector-year) $\sigma _{RK,S}$ on the one hand, and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ , on the other hand; this allows us to compare the dynamics of the two elasticities from the second half of ’90s to the end of ’00s, relying on our IFR-WIOD dataset. As a measure of the “degree of curvature” of the isoquant, the EoS between two factors embodies information on how technically easy is to substitute a factor by another. In carrying out the empirical analysis, we use the recently developed local polynomial estimation (Li & Racine, Reference Li and Racine2007; Hall & Racine, Reference Hall and Racine2015), in the spirit of Henderson (Reference Henderson2009), who applied these techniques in the evaluation of capital-skill complementarity from a cross-country perspective. Particularly, we consider the following framework (see Battisti et al., (Reference Battisti, Gatto and Parmeter2022), for an application to two factors production function estimation):

(1) \begin{equation} Y_{ci,t} = m(NRK_{ci,t}, RK_{ci,t}, S_{ci,t}, U_{ci,t}, d_{ci}, d_t), \end{equation}

where discrete variables $d_{ci}$ and $d_{t}$ represent, respectively, a country-sector effect and a time effect. The advantage of following this approach is twofold. First, incorporating these effects within a parametric setting would quickly reduce degrees of freedom. Conversely, in a nonparametric framework, we can employ smoothing techniques across both time and sectors to leverage neighboring cells for localized information (see Li & Racine, Reference Li and Racine2007). Second, it enables us to avoid making any assumptions in terms of the functional specification of the production technology.Footnote 13

Equation (1) is estimated using local polynomial least squares (LPLS). Common examples include local constant and local linear. However, our primary focus in this context is less on directly estimating $m(\cdot )$ and more on the estimation of various orders of derivatives of the function (i.e., the first and second order). Therefore, we employ a higher-order polynomial to directly estimate the derivatives of interest. Specifically, we make use of a local quadratic estimation with data-driven bandwidth selection. Considering that we are estimating derivatives of an unknown smooth function, the data-driven bandwidths are adjusted to account for the optimal rate difference, as suggested by Henderson et al. (Reference Henderson, Kumbhakar, Li and Parmeter2015) (see Section B of the Appendix for methodological details).

Among possible EoS specifications, we rely on the “Morishima EoS,” which can be viewed as a multifactor extension of the Hicks EoS (Blackorby & Russell, Reference Blackorby and Russell1981). In a two-input context, the Hicks EoS measures the percentage change in the factor ratio associated with a 1% change in the marginal rate of technical substitution (i.e., the marginal productivity ratio) between the two inputs. The Morishima multifactor extension is defined, for any two inputs, at given values of output and keeping constant the EoS with respect to all the other production factors. The higher the value, the higher is the substitutability between the two inputs. While two inputs are said to be substitutes when the estimated values are positive and complements when values are negative (i.e., if $\sigma^{RK,U}\lt 0$ , the amount of $U$ will grow more than proportionally to $RK$ as a consequence of an increase in the marginal productivity of $RK$ ), we are mainly concerned with the inequality between $\sigma^{RK,S}$ and $\sigma ^{RK,U}$ : whenever $\widehat{\sigma }_{RK,S}\lt \widehat{\sigma }_{RK,U}$ , we conclude that $RK$ is more likely to substitute for $U$ than for $S$ or, alternatively, more likely to complement with $S$ than with $U$ , depending on whether the estimated elasticities are positive or negative — i.e., “RK-Skill complementarity.” This circumstance results in an increasing $\frac{S}{U}$ ratio, but, not necessarily a decreasing amount of $U$ , at given levels of $S$ and $Y$ .

Formally, the EoS between input $q$ and $l$ for the multiple-input production technology in equation (1) is defined as

(2) \begin{equation} \sigma ^{ql} \; = \; \frac{m_{l}}{x_{q}} \frac{H_{ql}}{|H|} - \frac{m_{l}}{x_{l}} \frac{H_{ll}}{|H|} \; \end{equation}

where $x_q$ and $x_l$ denote the used quantities of inputs $q$ and $l$ ; $m_l$ and $m_q$ are the first partial derivatives of $m$ with respect to $q$ and $l$ ; $|H|$ represents the determinant of the bordered Hessian matrix; $H_{ql}$ is the cofactor of the element $m_{ql}$ in $H$ , with $m_{ql}$ indicating the cross-partial derivative of $m$ .

A well-known problem in a parametric equivalent of a production function estimation like Equation (1), dating back to Marschak & Andrews (Reference Marschak and Andrews1944), is the “simultaneity” between the choice concerning the amount of inputs and the (unknown to the econometrician but known to the firm when the decision is made) productivity (or technological) component of the production function. While simultaneity poses a challenge in firm-level estimation, its nature at an aggregate level (i.e., country-sector) is less straightforward to discern — in terms of how firm knowledge of productivity affecting input choices may be analogously applied to the behavior of the entire industry to which it belongs. This is tantamount to stating that the diverse fixed effects in nonparametric estimation entirely capture productivity heterogeneity at the sector level. Equivalently, it assumes that any productivity innovations are observed subsequent to input decisions (at the sector level), thereby ensuring no correlation with input decisions.Footnote 14 Moreover, within this setup, the EoS is derived through estimating “relative” gradients. Any potential simultaneity bias, if present, would impact both the numerator and denominator, effectively canceling out when ratios are taken. However, we also recognize that the presence of endogeneity bias is serious and so we must interpret our results with caution. Future research in this area could assess the impact of endogeneity bias through productivity shocks and the adoption of robotic capital, similar to the large literature on firm-level productivity (Olley and Pakes, Reference Olley and Pakes1996; Ackerberg, Caves and Frazier, Reference Ackerberg, Caves and Frazer2015; Gandhi, Navarro and Rivers, Reference Gandhi, Navarro and Rivers2020, etc.).

4. Results

In Figure 4, we show the kernel densities of estimated median $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ , by country and by industry. We cut 10 percent of observations on the tails of the overall distribution to exclude potential outliers (subsequent analysis is based on such distribution).Footnote 15 As can be observed, in both panels, the distribution of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ — the solid line — is located to the left, with respect to that of $\sigma _{RK,U}$ , pointing to (relative) overall higher complementarity (or lower substitutability) between $RK$ and $S$ . Ultimately, we find that in approximately 60% of cases, $\sigma _{RK,S}$ is lower than $\sigma _{RK,U}$ In this regard, Figure E2 in the Appendix reports the distribution of both $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ values over the entire sample.

Figure 4. Kernel distribution of the estimated median Morishima EoS, 1995–2009.

Ideally, we would like to test that $\sigma _{RK,S}$ is lower than $\sigma _{RK,U}$ for all observations. This entails the hypothesis:

\begin{equation*} H_0:\; \sigma _{RK,S}\le \sigma _{RK,U}\quad \forall X, \end{equation*}

against the alternative that

\begin{equation*} H_1:\; \sigma _{RK,S} \gt \sigma _{RK,U}\quad \text {for some } X, \end{equation*}

where $X$ here is the complete vector of inputs. This is a difficult testing problem as it requires a comparison of each pair of estimates of EoS of a rather complex nonparametric object. To our knowledge, a general one-sided test of nonparametrically estimated objects does not yet exist. It is common in tests of, say, statistical significance or correct functional form that a weighted test statistic is deployed to eliminate the random denominator that arises with nonparametrically constructed obejcts. However, our situation here is much more difficult as the ‘denominator’ of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ (or its difference with $\sigma _{RK,U}$ ) is not obvious or known.

To address this testing challenge, we employ a two-pronged approach: a Kolmogorov–Smirnov (KS) test of first-order stochastic dominance and a graphical analysis of the EoS dynamics over time. The KS test examines whether the probability of observing a given level of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ is higher than an equally sized value of $\sigma _{RK,U}$ . While not ideal, it provides a step toward establishing that $RK$ is more substitutable with $U$ than with $S$ labor. We apply such a test to the entire period and three distinct sub-periods (1995–1999, 2000–2004, 2005–2009). The results reveal an evolving pattern: for the full period and the latter two sub-periods, we fail to reject the null hypothesis that $\sigma _{RK,U}$ first-order stochastically dominates $\sigma _{RK,S}$ ( $p$ -values of 0.4212, 0.6603, and 1, respectively). However, for the initial sub-period (1995–1999), we reject the null hypothesis ( $p$ -value of 1.649e-06).

To complement the statistical analysis, we exploit our nonparametric estimates to visually examine the EoS dynamics. Figure 5 presents the (normalized) cumulative distribution functions (CDFs) of the two EoS for the three aforementioned sub-periods: at the beginning (1995–1999), in the middle (2000–2004), and at the end of the period (2005–2009). Additionally, the last panel displays the distribution of the difference between $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ across these three periods.Footnote 16 The graphical analysis corroborates and extends the insights from the KS test. In fact, the overall trend suggests that the relationship between the two distributions has evolved substantially over time: initially, they intersected, indicating a lack of clear dominance. However, toward the end of the period, the distribution of $\sigma _{RK,U}$ exhibits a higher mean and lower variance compared to $\sigma _{RK,S}$ , consistent with the failure to reject stochastic dominance in later periods.

To sum up, this dual approach offers evidence of an increasing tendency for $RK$ to be more substitutable with $U$ than with $S$ labor over the studied period, particularly after 2000.

Figure 5. EoS normalized cumulative distribution: time dynamics.

This trend is confirmed by the evolution of the share of cases in which $\widehat{\sigma }_{RK,U}\gt \widehat{\sigma }_{RK,S}$ : 50% in the period 1995–1999, 60% over the years 2000–2004, and 72% in the period 2005–2009%.Footnote 17

Global trends are reported in Figure 6.Footnote 18 Quite interestingly, we observe that the two EoS exhibit a tendency to cross at the end of the 1990s and diverge in the early 2000s, with an inversion at the end of the period.

Figure 6. EoS estimated patterns, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

To delve more into the country-sector dimension of this aspect, Figures 7 and 8 report some disaggregated patterns. Namely, Figure 7 shows how the overall tendency in Figure 6 differently mirrors OECD and Non-OECD evolutions. In particular, while in the OECD countries the widening gap between $\sigma _{RK,U}$ and $\sigma _{RK,S}$ is driven by a substantial increase in the former, we document an important reduction in $\sigma _{RK,S}$ in Non-OECD countries, with a higher complementarity between $RK$ and $S$ detected (i.e., $\sigma _{RK,S} \lt 0$ ), especially at the end of the period. Within the OECD group, European countries’ patterns look very similar to the US, in terms of timing of sign change of the difference between $\sigma _{RK,U}$ and $\sigma _{RK,S}$ .

Figure 7. EoS estimated patterns in selected (groups of) countries, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

Figure 8. EoS estimated patterns in selected (groups of) sectors, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

At the sectoral level (see Figure 8), the divergence in Manufacturing started before and seems to last longer, compared to Non-Manufacturing. The two sectors more interested by the robotization process (transport equipment and electrical and optical equipment industries, according to our $RK$ measure) display different trajectories: unskilled are less complementary than skilled since the beginning of the period (i.e., $\sigma _{RK,U}$ always stands above $\sigma _{RK,S}$ ), with an increasing trend in the whole first decade of 2000 (without reversal) in electrical and optical equipment sector; the initial situation was opposite in the transport equipment industry.

The above dynamics are not surprising. In fact, as pointed out by Autor (Reference Autor2015), the years at the turn of the new millennium coincided with a dramatic drop for those workers employed in “production” and occupied as “operators/laborers” — the most vulnerable to robotization and included, throughout our empirical analysis, within the $U$ category. Moreover, such a pattern retraces the evidence uncovered by Koch et al. (Reference Koch, Manuylov and Smolka2021) in Spain, where robot adoption increased rapidly after 1998. Finally, Acemoglu and Restrepo (Reference Acemoglu and Restrepo2020) argue that the distinct impact of robots from other technologies started to appear after the 1990s. By and large, this phenomenon may be interpreted as a hint of an increasingly higher relative complementarity of $ S$ during the process of development (and of robotization).

4.1 Statistical Inference

Given the highly nonlinear nature of our estimated EoS, an asymptotic variance is unlikely to be of empirical value. Rather, we rely on a nonparametric bootstrap to construct standard errors for each of our EoS estimates. To do this, we use a two-point wild bootstrap procedure with 500 replications (see, Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Gatto and Parmeter2022), for details on bootstrapping in this framework). We keep the bandwidths fixed across the replications to reduce noise stemming from the estimation of the smoothing parameters.

In our benchmark analysis, conducted over $7,504$ Footnote 19 country-sector pairs, we find:

  • about 37% of estimates for $\sigma _{RK,S}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level;

  • about 45% of estimates for $\sigma _{RK,U}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level.Footnote 20

Although these values may appear prima-facie low, the nonparametric point estimates cannot be simply compared with the statistical significance of coefficients estimated via OLS (a mean estimator). A more proper comparison within similar works (such as, Henderson (Reference Henderson2009), who examined the capital-skill complementarity from a cross-country perspective, with a single type of capital and no sector controls), reveals a much higher share of statistically significant nonparametric EoS estimates in our case. In fact, the present analysis relies on a sample mainly containing OECD and/or developed economies, observed over a shorter time span, and is broken down by sector. Further, we detect that the proportion of statistically and economically significant EoS estimates increases when we consider observations with nonzero $RK$ . Specifically, this share peaks to nearly 70% when focusing on these observations, implying a higher confidence in estimations for developed countries as opposed to emerging economies, which utilize a much lower stock of $RK$ .

5. Robustness and broad validation

5.1 Different depreciation rates and different types of capital

The robustness of our results is first of all checked by changing the depreciation rate used in the construction of our $RK$ stock. As a further investigation, we repeat our analysis replacing our $RK$ measure with total capital in order to understand to what extent our findings can be thought of to be driven by the estimation methodology.Footnote 21 Table 1 synthesizes all the above checks focusing on some country classifications, the two major industries in terms of $RK$ intensity, as well as years at the beginning, in the middle and at the end of the period. Benchmark results (i.e., when $RK$ is calculated assuming $\delta = 10\%$ ) are reported in the first two columns to ease comparison. In the vast majority of cases, the hypothesis of a relatively lower (higher) substitutability (complementarity) between $RK$ and $S$ , as well as between $TotK$ and $S$ , seems consistent with the data.

Table 1. Estimated EoS: different depreciation rates and different types of capital. Median values

Notes: Time and country-by-sector fixed effects included. The cases in which the “RK-Skill complementarity” and capital-skill complementarity hypotheses holds true are reported in bold.

Anglo-saxons: Australia, United Kingdom, USA. Asian: Indonesia, India, Japan, Republic of Korea, Turkey.

Europe: Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Czech Republic, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Estonia, Finland, France, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Sweden.

Non-Europe: Australia, Brazil, Indonesia, India, Japan, Republic of Korea, Turkey, USA.

OECD: Belgium, Denmark, Germany, France, Netherlands, Sweden, Finland, Austria, Greece, Spain, Italy, Portugal, Ireland, United Kingdom, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Lithuania, Latvia, Poland, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Turkey, Australia, Japan, Republic of Korea, USA. Non-OECD: Bulgaria, Brazil, Indonesia, India, Malta, Romania, Russia.

Finally, a key result of our analysis is the unraveling of a diverging pattern driven by increasing $\sigma _{RK,U}$ in the first decade of 2000 in the OECD country-group (see Figure 7). One might wonder whether such tendency can be a some mechanical consequence of $RK$ accumulation. To check whether this is the case, we re-estimate the OECD trend using $IK$ , relying on the EU KLEMS (2009) sample, in place of $RK$ (that is estimating $\sigma _{IK,S}$ and $\sigma _{IK,U}$ instead of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ ). In so doing, we exploit the remarkable growth of ICT capital displayed in Figure 2. Since this type of capital does not include robots, a different dynamics can be expected. Indeed, Figure 9 reports decreasing substitutability with respect to both $ S$ and $U$ , with the former steadily and steeply decreasing over the whole period, with an acceleration in the first decade of the century. This seems to be in line with previous “ICT capital-skill complementarity” studies such as Eden & Gaggl (Reference Eden and Gaggl2018) and Taniguchi & Yamada (Reference Taniguchi and Yamada2022), providing a further broad validation of our nonparametric framework with respect to more traditional parametric settings.

Figure 9. Estimated patterns of $\sigma _{IK,S}$ and $\sigma _{IK,U}$ , OECD, 1994–2005.

5.2 Price and productivity effects

In principle, the above patterns can be driven by two order of forces. First, decreasing robot prices, coupled with non-decreasing skill premia, might induce a more intense use of robots — that is, robot prices might have fallen, relative to $U$ ’s wage, more than $S$ ’s wage did (i.e., a price effect). Second, the relative increase in robots usage might be pushed by robots’ increased ability to perform manual and/or routine tasks (i.e., a productivity effect).

The first force relies on the assumption that $ U$ (and their manual tasks) are easier to replace and can be linked to the directed technical change hypothesis (Acemoglu, 2002). The second effect can be intended as an equivalent of Moore’s Law applied to $RK$ , so that even without an increasing diffusion, new robots could be able to perform more tasks than previous ones.Footnote 22

Graphical inspection seems to suggest that both effects have been at work. As for the price effect, the declining medium-run trend of robot prices, relative to the (un)skill premium (the $U/S$ wage gap) in Figure 10 provides a first, strong incentive to replace $U$ with robots.

Figure 10. Evolution of robot price over unskilled/skilled wage ratio, US and Japan, 1995–2009.

Additionally, the marginal product of $RK$ sharply increased over the same years, as we document in Figure 11; thus, also the productivity effect might have triggered the substitutability process.

Figure 11. Evolution of marginal product of robotic capital, 1995–2009.

To more formally inquire into these relationships, we regress the (nonparametrically) estimated EoS on two proxies for the price and productivity effects.Footnote 23

(3) \begin{equation} \widehat{\sigma }^x_{j,t} = \beta _1 \left (\frac{W_U}{W_S}\right )_{j,t} + \beta _2 \widehat{MP}^{RK}_{j,t} + \alpha _{c} + \gamma _i + \tau _t + \epsilon _{j,t} \end{equation}

where $x = \left \lbrace (RK,S) \text{ or } (RK,U)\right \rbrace$ ; $W_S$ and $W_U$ are the wage of $ S$ and $U$ , respectively; $\widehat{MP}^{RK}=$ denotes the estimated marginal product of $RK$ ; $j$ is the country-sector index. Estimation of this regression is straighforward, however, we have nonparametrically generated regressors on both sides of the equation (see Mammen, Rothe and Scheinle, Reference Mammen, Rothe and Schienle2012, Chu, Reference Chu2023). This necessitates use of bootstrapping to construct appropriate standard errors.

It is worth noting that we interpret this relationship as a simple correlation, due to the lack of exogenous sources of variation. Therefore, we cannot claim any causal effect in this exercise, given the presence of reverse causality between EoS and prices/productivity.Footnote 24 A statistically significant negative (positive) $\hat{\beta }$ , when $\widehat{\sigma }_{RK,S}$ ( $\widehat{\sigma }_{RK,U}$ ) is used as dependent variable, would suggest the price (i.e., $\beta _1$ ) and/or the productivity (i.e., $\beta _2$ ) to play a role.

Results in Table 2 show that the estimated partial correlations have the expected signs, that is, negative (positive) in the left (right) panels, implying higher complementarity of $ S$ (substitutability of $ U$ ), with increasing relative costs of $ U$ and higher marginal product of $RK$ . By including country—, industry— and time-controls, the magnitude is reinforced and the statistical significance of the estimated coefficients is unaltered. These findings turn out to be robust when $RK$ is computed using different depreciation rates.

Table 2. Price and productivity effects (Eq. 3)

Notes: * $p\lt 0.10$ ,** $p\lt 0.05$ , *** $p\lt 0.01$ . Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses.

6. Conclusions

The growing concerns stemming from the extensive use of automation in production are prompting scholars to seek a better understanding of its implications for the labor market. Additionally, the pressure from international shocks necessitating a complete rethinking of the production process is fueling a heated debate on whether robots and other forms of automation will favor skilled workers ( $S$ ) at the expense of unskilled labor ( $U$ ).

In this paper, we contribute to the debate by investigating the extent of complementarity and substitutability in the productive processes between robotic capital ( $RK$ ) and workers of different skill levels (high-skilled versus medium-low-skilled).

We estimate country-sector Elasticity of Substitution (EoS) patterns between $RK$ and labor inputs. The main results of the analysis can be summarized as follows:

  • Overall evidence of “RK-skill complementarity,” with $\sigma _{RK,S} \lt \sigma _{RK,U}$ , suggesting that $RK$ deepening proceeds hand in hand with increasing labor ratios (i.e., $\frac{S}{U}$ ). However, it is not always the case that robotization results in shrinking $U$ and/or $S$ .

  • A certain degree of heterogeneity at the country-sector level.

  • The dynamic pattern of elasticities shows as the difference between $\sigma _{RK,U}$ and $\sigma _{RK,S}$ has grown substantially over the first decade of 2000 (indeed, while often lower than $\sigma _{RK,S}$ at the beginning, $\sigma _{RK,U}$ ends up being much higher in 2009).

  • Both the difference and its increase over the period have been more pronounced in OECD than in non-OECD countries (where the increase is mainly driven by shrinking $\sigma _{RK,S}$ ) and in Manufacturing with respect to Non-Manufacturing.

A possible explanation for the existence of a turning point at the end of the ’90s, in which the two estimated EoS cross each other with the $\sigma _{RK,U}$ growing more than the $\sigma _{RK,S}$ , can be associated with the fact that robots have increased their ability to reproduce complex tasks.

By and large, the contribution to increasing the $\frac{S}{U}$ ratio raises issues linked to unemployment and/or wage pressures for vulnerable segments of the labor market. In this respect, policymakers face numerous challenges. By shedding light on understanding the labor market asymmetries associated with the ongoing process of technological change, especially in manufacturing industries of advanced and transition economies, our study highlights how, if, on the one hand, industrial robots, as a subset of the broader category of automation technologies, turn out to be a powerful engine of economic growth, on the other hand, they appear to be associated with intensifying inequalities that, far from being trivial in terms of sign and intensity, follow strongly different patterns across countries and sectors.

We end here by noting there are many directions in which we could extend our analysis further. First, developing a formal test for size of skill bias through the EoS holds great empirical promise. Second, investigating the price of $RK$ and its impact on the analysis would provide an excellent robustness check. We have only investigated country-sector pairs with available information, including those completed through an imputation process, which obviously limits our coverage. Collecting and obtaining data for more countries-sectors (and years) would be an important upgrade. Third, our approach here effectively dealt with human capital stocks by moving middle-skilled workers into the $U$ group. This made our analysis much easier but also blurs the lines of the skill level of many workers. It would be worthwhile to consider a three skill level model and determine how robust our results are.

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to David Andolfatto, Rosario Crinó, Joseph Zeira, and the participants in the “North American Productivity Workshop XI” (NAPW XI, 2020), the Research Centre for Economic Analysis “3rd Warsaw Money-Macro-Finance Conference” (RCEA, 2021), the “II Biannual Workshop: Technological Change, Health, Inequality and Data for Policy Evaluation” (LABOR, 2022), the International Centre for Economic Analysis “Future of Work” Conference (ICEA, 2022), the “XXII AISSEC Scientific Conference” and the 2023 ISGEP Workshop on “Firms, Trade and Productivity” at “G. d’Annunzio” University of Chieti-Pescara, the “64th Annal Conference of the Italian Economic Association” (Gran Sasso Science Institute, 2023), and the “Economics Seminar Series” (Universities of Bergamo and Palermo, 2022) for many useful comments and suggestions. The usual caveat applies.

Financial support

Michele Battisti and Massimo Del Gatto gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Fondo per il Programma Nazionale di Ricerca e Progetti di Rilevante Interesse Nazionale (PRIN) 2022 of the Ministry of University and Research of Italy (grant number 2022FLBY7J - D53D23006480006).

Appendix

A. RK construction: retrieving the unit price of robots

Information on average unit price of robots, needed to obtain our RK measure, is retrieved from different IFR reports. In particular, prices are computed as the ratio of the turnover of total robot systems to the number of robots delivered in a specific country. Unfortunately, IFR provides series of industrial robot prices (in current, thousand dollars) for a few countries only (see, for instance, International Federation of Robotics (2005). Specifically, unit prices are available for: Japan, US, Germany, Republic of Korea, United Kingdom and France, from 1995 to 2008. For Italy, robot prices are available from 1995 to 2006.

To define the average unit price of robots in the remaining countries, we proceed as follows. For Italy, the 2007 and 2008 prices are computed using the average growth rate of the countries for which we have original data. For all the other countries, we relied upon geographical proximity, economic proximity and trade relationships. In particular:

  • European countries are assigned the average robot prices of Germany, United Kingdom, France and Italy;

  • American countries are assigned US robot prices;

  • Asian countries (plus Australia) are assigned the average robot prices of Japan and Republic of Korea.

In order to obtain the 1995 and 2009 prices, data are smoothed using uniformly weighted moving averages, with 1 lagged term, 1 forward term and the current observation in the filter.

B. The empirical methodology in details

Local polynomial least squares estimation. Nonparametric kernel methods have the ability to alleviate many of the restrictive assumptions made in classical parametric frameworks (the use of CES for example). Consider the canonical nonparametric regression model:

(B.1) \begin{equation} y_{i}=m(x_{i})+u_{i},\quad i=1,2,\ldots, n, \end{equation}

where $y_i$ is our response (in this case output growth), $x_i$ is a vector of $q$ regressors, $\varepsilon _i$ is the additive (mean zero) random disturbance and $m\left ( \cdot \right )$ is an unknown smooth function. Here, $m\left ( \cdot \right )$ is interpreted as the conditional mean of $y$ given $x$ ; in a traditional linear in parameters setting it is implicitly assumed that $E\left ( y_{i}|x_{i}\right ) =\alpha +\beta x_{i}$ .

Popular estimation approaches for estimating the conditional mean in (B.1) are local-constant and local-linear least-squares (LCLS and LLLS, respectively) regression. The intuition behind these estimators is that they construct a weighted average of $y_{i}$ based on the location of the covariates. These weights are dictated by kernels. The “local” determination is controlled through a user defined parameter known as the bandwidth.

One benefit of LLLS over LCLS is that the slope of the conditional mean is also estimated directly. This is important for our setting as we are not interested directly in the conditional mean of growth, but in the slope of the relationship in various dimensions that will allow us to measure “RK-skill complementarity.” In fact, because we are interested in second derivatives and cross partials, we need more advanced local smoothing methods to recover these gradients. For this, we turn to LPLS.

To describe LPLS, we note that we can approximate $m$ around $x_0$ as:

(B.2) \begin{equation} m(x_i) \approx \sum _{0 \leq \vert \mathbf{j} \vert \leq \rho _1} \frac{1}{\mathbf{j}!} (D^{(\mathbf{j})}m)(x_0) (x_i - x_0)^{\mathbf{j}}, \end{equation}

where

\begin{align*} \mathbf{j} =& \left ( j_1,\ldots, j_d\right ), \qquad \mathbf{j}! = j_1! \times \ldots \times j_d!, \qquad \vert \mathbf{j} \vert = \sum _{k =1}^d j_k,\\ (x_i - x_0)^{\mathbf{j}} =& (x_{1i} - x_{10})^{j_1} \times \ldots \times (x_{di} - x_{d0})^{j_d},\\ \sum _{0 \leq \vert \mathbf{j} \vert \leq \rho } =& \underset{j_1 + \ldots + j_d = \vert \mathbf{j} \vert }{\sum _{k =0}^{\rho } \sum _{j_1 = 0}^k \ldots \sum _{j_d = 0}^k}, \end{align*}

and

\begin{equation*} (D^{(\mathbf {j})}m)(x_0) = \frac {\partial ^{\mathbf {j}} m(x_0)}{\partial x^{j_1}_{10} \ldots \partial x^{j_d}_{d0}}. \end{equation*}

Notice that in this formulation, we can allow for an arbitrary order of polynomial for each different component in $x$ . From here we are interested in the solution to the weighted least squares problem

(B.3) \begin{equation} \frac{1}{nh} \sum _{i=1}^n \left [y_i - \sum _{\ell =0}^L \beta _\ell x_{\ell i}-x_{s0})^{j} \right ]^2 \mathcal{K}\left (\frac{x_i-x}{h} \right ) \end{equation}

in which $\mathcal{K}(\cdot )$ is a product kernel function and $h$ is a bandwidth vector. In this setup, $\beta _\ell$ denotes the partial derivative of order $j$ for coefficient $k$ with respect to component $s$ .

Define $\widetilde{x}_{si} \equiv \left ((x_{si} - x_s)^1,(x_{si} - x_s)^2,\ldots, (x_{si} - x_s)^{p_s} \right )$ and $\widetilde{Z}_i \equiv \left (\widetilde{x}_{1i},\widetilde{x}_{2i},\ldots, \widetilde{x}_{Si} \right )$ . Then, for $\widetilde{X}_i \equiv \displaystyle \binom{X_i}{\widetilde{x}_i \otimes x_i}'$ , we seek the $(L+1) \times (\sum p_s + 1)$ estimator $\widehat{\delta }$ given by

(B.4) \begin{equation} \widehat{\delta } = (\widetilde{X}'\mathcal{K}(x)\widetilde{X})^{-1}\widetilde{X}'\mathcal{K}(x)Y \end{equation}

Note that our estimates of the functions $\beta _\ell (z)$ are recovered by $\widehat{\beta }_\ell (z) = e_1 \widehat{\delta }$ for $e_1$ being a $(L+1) \times (\sum p_s + 1)$ -dimensioned vector with the first $L+1$ elements being unity and the remaining $(L+1) \times \sum p_s$ elements being zero.

To make our estimator operational in a mixed data setting, we follow Racine & Li (Reference Racine and Li2004) and deploy the generalized product kernel function for $\mathcal{K}(\cdot )$ .

(B.5) \begin{equation} \mathcal{K}(\cdot ) = \prod _{c=1}^{S_c} k^c\left (\frac{x_{i}^c - x^c}{h_c} \right ) \prod _{u=1}^{S_u} k^u(x_{i}^u - x^u; h_u) \prod _{o=1}^{S_o} k^o(x_{i}^o - x^o; h_o) \end{equation}

in which

(B.6) \begin{equation} k^c\left (\frac{x_{i}^c - x^c}{h_c} \right ) = \frac{1}{\sqrt{2 \pi }} \mbox{exp}\left [\frac{1}{2} \left (\frac{x_{i}^c - x^c}{h_c} \right )^2 \right ] \end{equation}

is a univariate Gaussian kernel function used for each of the $S_{c}$ continuous variables in $x_{i}$ ,

(B.7) \begin{equation} k^u(x_{i}^u - x^u; h_u) = \left \{ \begin{array}{ll} 1 & \mbox{if } x_{i}^u - x^u = 0\\ h_u & \mbox{if } x_{i}^u - x^u \neq 0.\end{array} \right . \end{equation}

is a univariate discrete kernel function used for each of the $S_u$ unordered discrete variables in $x_{i}$ , and

(B.8) \begin{equation} k^o (x_{i}^o - x^o; h_o) = \left \{ \begin{array}{ll} 1 & \mbox{if } x_{i}^o - x^o = 0\\ h_o^{|x_{i}^o - x^o|} & \mbox{if } x_{i}^o - x^o \neq 0.\end{array} \right . \end{equation}

is a univariate discrete kernel function used for each of the $S_o$ ordered discrete variables in $x_{i}$ (Li & Racine, Reference Li and Racine2007). In the above product kernel setup, $h_c$ is a $S_c$ -dimensioned vector of bandwidths for the continuous variables and $h_u$ and $h_o$ are $S_u$ - and $S_o$ -dimensioned vectors of unordered and ordered discrete variable bandwidths.

Since we are concerned with the class of second derivatives, we engage in local-cubic ( $p=3$ ) estimation. We deploy least-squares cross-validation (LSCV) to estimate the respective bandwidths. Specifically, LSCV selects bandwidths which minimize

(B.9) \begin{equation} LSCV\left (h\right ) =\sum \limits _{i=1}^n\left [y_i-\widehat{m}_{-i}(x_i)\right ] ^{2}\!, \end{equation}

where $\widehat{m}_{-i}(x_i)$ is the leave-one-out estimator of $m(\cdot )$ . The idea of the leave-one-out estimator is that the conditional mean of $y_i$ is estimated without using the observation with the most information, $x_i$ . In this way, the bandwidths are selected so that the surrounding observations are providing as much information as possible to assist with smoothing.

C. Countries and industries covered

Table C1. List of WIOD and EU KLEMS countries

Table C2. List of industries

Notes: Industries codes are ISIC Rev. 3.1.

D. Descriptive statistics (tables)

Table D1a. IFR-WIOD dataset: main variables’ average by country

Source: Authors’ calculations based on International Federation of Robotics (2019) and WIOD (2015). * $R^S$ (i.e., the robot stock) is obtained through Perpetual Inventory method and expressed in quantity (number of robots); this explains the presence of non-integer values.

Table D1b. IFR-WIOD dataset: main variables’ average by industry

Source: Authors’ calculations based on International Federation of Robotics (2019) and WIOD (2015). * $R^S$ (i.e., the robot stock) is obtained through Perpetual Inventory method and expressed in quantity (number of robots); this explains the presence of non-integer values.

Table D2a. IFR-EU KLEMS dataset: main variables’ average by country

Source: Authors’ calculations based on International Federation of Robotics (2019) and EU KLEMS (2009). * $R^S$ (i.e., the robot stock) is obtained through Perpetual Inventory method and expressed in quantity (number of robots); this explains the presence of non-integer values.

Table D2b. IFR-EU KLEMS dataset: main variables’ average by industry

Source: Authors’ calculations based on International Federation of Robotics (2019) and EU KLEMS (2009). * $R^S$ (i.e., the robot stock) is obtained through Perpetual Inventory method and expressed in quantity (number of robots); this explains the presence of non-integer values.

E. Additional figures

Figure E1. Robotic capital evolution in selected WIOD countries and industries 1995–2009.

Figure E2. Kernel distribution of the estimated morishima EoS, 1995–2009.

F. Comparison with parametric estimates

For the sake of completeness, we carry out an EoS analysis adopting a parametric approach in order to highlight key differences with our nonparametric setup, on the one hand, and to contrast results (to the extent it is possible), on the other. Indeed, the type of analysis that we can perform in a parametric setting is limited from a number of perspectives. First, being our benchmark approach observation-specific, we are not able to have an equivalent direct estimate of EoS in a parametric setup. Second, since marginal productivity can hardly be estimated at the country-sector-year level using parametric methods, the EoS analysis usually proceeds by proxying the marginal rate of technical substitution with the factor price ratio under the implicit assumption that input markets are perfectly competitive. Our nonparametric approach allows us to completely avoid this, being based on marginal productivity comparison. Third, a functional specification of the production technology is required under the parametric approach; estimation usually relies on a CES nested in Cobb–Douglas specification (e.g., (Krusell et al. Reference Krusell, Ohanian, Ríos-Rull and Violante2000; Duffy et al. Reference Duffy, Papageorgiou and Perez-Sebastian2004; Eden & Gaggl, Reference Eden and Gaggl2018)).

In light of this, a standard formulation incorporating distinct kinds of capital and derive different substitutability degrees among factor inputs is offered by the Cobb–Douglas production function (removing subscripts for countries, industry and time to ease notation) over $NRK$ , assumed as neutral, with respect to skill types, and a CES technology over non-neutral $RK$ , $S$ and  $U$ :

(F.1) \begin{align} Y=NRK^\alpha \left [ \beta \: Q^{\sigma } + (1-\beta ) \: U^{\sigma } \right ] ^{\frac{1-\alpha }{\sigma }} \\ \text{with} \; Q=\left [ \gamma \: RK^\rho + \left ( 1 - \gamma \right ) \: S^\rho )\right ] ^{\frac{1}{\rho }}, \nonumber \end{align}

where $Y$ represents aggregate output; $\beta$ and $\gamma$ are distribution parameters; $\rho$ and $\sigma$ govern the elasticity of substitution between $RK$ and $S$ , and between the composite input ( $Q$ , encompassing $RK$ and $S$ ) and $U$ , respectively.Footnote 25 Throughout the empirical analysis, $ U$ includes medium- and low-skilled workers.

As can be observed, direct pairwise comparison between $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ is not possible in the parametric setup, which can only focus on comparing $\sigma _{RK,S}$ with the EoS, with respect to $U$ , of the inputs bundle $Q$ (i.e., $\sigma _{Q,U}$ ). Indeed, assuming that the markets for inputs are competitive, the first-order conditions of profit-maximizing and price-taking firms imply (simultaneously) estimating the following system of equations:

(F.2) \begin{equation} \ln \left (\frac{\theta ^{RK}_{ci,t}}{\theta ^{S}_{ci,t}}\right )=\ln \left (\frac{\gamma }{1 - \gamma }\right )+\rho \ln \left (\frac{RK_{ci,t}}{S_{ci,t}}\right )+\epsilon _{ci,t} \end{equation}
(F.3) \begin{equation} \ln \left (\frac{\theta ^{U}_{ci,t}}{\theta ^{Q}_{ci,t}}\right )=\ln \left (\frac{\beta }{1 - \beta }\right )+\sigma \ln \left (\frac{U_{ci,t}}{Q_{ci,t}}\right )+\mu _{ci,t} \end{equation}

where $c$ , $i$ and $t$ represent country, industry and time, respectively; $\theta ^R$ , $\theta ^S$ , $\theta ^U$ and $\theta ^Q$ denote the income shares of $RK$ , $S$ , $U$ and $Q$ , respectively, while $\epsilon$ and $\mu$ are the error terms, allowed to be correlated across equations. EoS between $RK$ and $S$ , $\left .1\right /\left (1-\rho \right )$ , is derived by equation (F.2), while EoS between the composite factor and $U$ , $\left .1\right /\left (1-\sigma \right )$ , is identified from equation (F.3).

Table F1. EoS, parametric estimates

Notes: * $p\lt 0.10$ ,** $p\lt 0.05$ , *** $p\lt 0.01$ . Standard errors in parentheses. All the models are simultaneously estimated using GMM estimation techniques, with lagged values of input factors as instrumental variables and HAC robust standard errors.

Table F2. Robustness checks: EoS, parametric estimates. Different $RK$ depreciation rates

Notes: * $p\lt 0.10$ ,** $p\lt 0.05$ , *** $p\lt 0.01$ . Standard errors in parentheses. All the models are simultaneously estimated using GMM estimation techniques, with lagged values of input factors as instrumental variables and HAC robust standard errors.

Complementarity between $RK$ and $ S$ can be said to exist iff:

\begin{equation*} \left .1\right /\left (1-\rho \right ) \lt \left .1\right /\left (1-\sigma \right ) \implies \sigma \gt \rho \end{equation*}

Estimation is conducted using GMM, treating all the input factors as endogenous and exploiting their second and third lagged values as instruments. Table F1 reports the results of our benchmark parametric estimates.Footnote 26 In this respect, our findings provide broad evidence in favor of complementarity between $RK$ and $S$ . Specifically, the procedure points to this direction when applied to both the IFR-WIOD and the IFR-EU KLEMS datasets, where the EoS between the $RK$ and $S$ , $\left .1\right /\left (1-\rho \right )$ , is lower than between the $\left [RK-S\right ]$ composite and $U$ , $\left .1\right /\left (1-\sigma \right )$ , which implies $\sigma \gt \rho$ .

The sensitivity of the estimates presented in Table F1 is assessed, in line with suggestions by Graetz & Michaels (Reference Graetz and Michaels2018), to different constructions of the $RK$ stock, using both 5 and 15 percent depreciation rates. The corresponding results are presented in Table F2. In both cases, our main findings remain unchanged, thus providing substantial confirmation of the presence higher complementarity between $RK$ and $S$ .

Footnotes

1 A challenging aspect of the current technological progress is its occurrence amidst a series of aggregate shocks: the 2007-2008 economic crisis, the US–China trade war, the Covid-19 pandemic, as well as the recent Russia–Ukraine and Israel–Palestinian conflicts. In fact, Muro et al. (2020) highlight how “Robots’ infiltration of the workforce doesn’t occur at a steady, gradual pace” but is “concentrated especially in bad times such as in the wake of economic shocks when humans become relatively expensive as firms’ revenues rapidly decline.” Generally, these international shocks are thought to amplify the asymmetric effects of the adoption of new technologies. See, for example, Okyere et al. (Reference Muro, Maxim and Whiton2020) and Prettner and Bloom (Reference Prettner and Bloom2020) for the pandemics, with Leduc and Liu (Reference Leduc and Liu2020) discussing how pandemic-induced uncertainty about labor productivity may further trigger automation adoption. Additionally, Singer (Reference Singer2009) and Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal (Reference Fajgelbaum and Khandelwal2022) explore the case of armed conflicts. Other authors emphasize the indirect dimension of the relationship, showing, for example, how robotization can induce re-shoring of economic activity (Bonfiglioli et al. Reference Bonfiglioli, Crino’, Gancia, Papadakis, Bonfiglioli, Crino’, Gancia and Papadakis2022), adversely impacting employment (Faber, Reference Faber2020).

2 On this point, see, inter alia, Acemoglu (Reference Acemoglu1998, Reference Acemoglu2002).

3 Additional empirical evidence supporting this trend is provided, among others, by Autor and Dorn (Reference Autor and Dorn2013), Michaels et al. (Reference Michaels, Natraj and Van Reenen2014), Jaimovich and Siu (Reference Jaimovich and Siu2020), and vom Lehn (Reference vom Lehn2020).

4 While causality typically moves from technology to factor accumulation, the complementarity/substitutability argument is crucial in the discussion of the reverse causality of technology adoption. Originally proposed by Krugman (Reference Krugman1979), this argument suggests that if a productive factor, such as $U$ , becomes less complementary to capital, and there is a higher capitalization of productive processes, then this is equivalent to a higher opportunity cost for the less complementary factor. In productive factor markets, this implies greater demand for $U$ -saving technologies aimed at replacing it, as discussed in Alesina et al. (Reference Alesina, Battisti and Zeira2018).

5 It is worth noting that, given the focus on the relative use of $\frac{S}{U}$ , the presence of “RK-Skill complementarity” does not necessarily imply an absolute decrease in the use of $U$ .

6 Data on operational stock and deliveries of robots are provided by International Federation of Robotics (2019) according to the ISIC Rev. 4 Industry classification, contrary to ISIC Rev. 3.1 characterizing both the WIOD (2015) and EU KLEMS (2009) datasets. In order to merge the different coded sources, we make use of a correspondence table to convert IFR data from ISIC Rev. 4 to ISIC Rev. 3.1 industry classification.

7 As in Graetz and Michaels (Reference Graetz and Michaels2018), to check the robustness of our findings, the $RK$ variable is also constructed using depreciation rates of 5 and 15 percent.

8 The use of the country-sector-year specific total capital deflator from WIOD (2015) stems from the lack of specific details on the price level of robots that can be tailored to our sample. On this point, as well as for further information on the IFR database, see Jurkat et al. (Reference Jurkat, Klump and Schneider2022).

9 From a comparative perspective, medium-skilled workers can also be grouped with high-skilled workers. In the literature, it is quite common to consider high-skilled workers as those with tertiary education, especially in samples like this one, where most countries are OECD members (e.g. Alesina et al. Reference Alesina, Battisti and Zeira2018, Kunst et al. Reference Kunst, Freeman and Oostendorp2022). Empirical works such as Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Gatto and Parmeter2022) show that qualitative results remain largely unchanged regardless of whether medium-skilled workers are grouped with high-skilled workers.

10 A similar trend is highlighted by Schivardi and Schmitz (Reference Schivardi and Schmitz2018) for ICT capital in a sample of OECD economies. In our EU KLEMS sample, the share of ICT capital in total capital recorded an average of about 8.2%, with maxima exceeding 25% in industries of Austria, Australia, Denmark, Finland, United Kingdom, Slovenia and United States.

11 In accordance with the International Standard Industrial Classification of all Economic Activities (ISIC Rev. 4), robots are grouped under “general-purpose machinery,” specifically under “lifting and handling equipment” and “other special-purpose machinery.” As these are reported within the broader heading of machinery (i.e., non-ICT capital), robots are not part of ICT capital, which covers computers and telecommunication equipment. We are grateful to Robert Inklaar for bringing this point to our attention.

12 Code descriptions of the ISIC Rev. 3.1 industries are reported in Table C2 of the Appendix.

13 See Section F in the Appendix for a parametric estimation.

14 For example, Battisti et al. (Reference Battisti, Gatto and Parmeter2022) find only minor differences between controlling for simultaneity or not in an aggregate context, by implementing a correction procedure based on a Markov process assumption for the idiosyncratic productivity shock.

15 It is essential to emphasize that, in contrast to parametric generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation (as discussed in Section F in the Appendix), this framework does not constrain the EoS to fall within upper and lower bounds. Consequently, extreme values may influence the average value, leading to either extremely large or small numbers. Therefore, the interpretation of the results are in relative rather than absolute terms, aligning with the approach in Henderson (Reference Henderson2009). Additionally, the use of medians to convey our results is aimed at ensuring consistency and comparability with other studies in the literature (e.g., Henderson, Reference Henderson2009; Redding & Weinstein, Reference Redding and Weinstein2020; Gechert et al. Reference Gechert, Havranek, Irsova and Kolcunova2022).

16 The first three graphs in Figure 5 are obtained after trimming the distribution of each period of the first and last percentile in terms of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and $\sigma _{RK,U}$ ; the first and last decile of the distribution of the difference between $\sigma _{RK,U}$ and $\sigma _{RK,S}$ are instead dropped in the last graph.

17 These shares change to 50%, 61%, and 65% when the depreciation rate $\delta$ is set to 5%, and to 49%, 60%, and 63%, when $\delta =15\%$ , thereby confirming the validity of the analysis.

18 To facilitate visual consistency across Figures 6– 8, we applied a min-max normalization to the variables. This transformation scales the data to a common range, while preserving relative relationships among data points.

19 Nonparametric regressions require non-missing values for both the dependent and independent variables, in each country-industry-year observation, leading to a drop from the original 8,217 observations.

20 With $\delta = 5\%$ , about 33% of the estimates for $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and 36% of the estimates for $\sigma _{RK,U}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level. With $\delta = 15\%$ , about 39% of the estimates for $\sigma _{RK,S}$ and 37% of the estimates for $\sigma _{RK,U}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level.

21 When using TotK, we find, in the benchmark case with $\delta =10\%$ : about 45% of the estimates for $\sigma _{TotK,S}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level by considering observations with not nil $RK$ (30% if you calculate over the 7,504 total observations); about 70% of the estimates for $\sigma _{TotK,U}$ are statistically significant at least at the 10% level (50% if you calculate over the 7,504 total observations). When $RK$ $\delta = 5\%$ , we obtain about 47% (30% over 7,504 observations) of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ estimates and about 84% (54% over 7,504 observations) of $\sigma _{RK,U}$ estimates that are statistically significant at least at the 10% level. When $RK$ $\delta = 15\%$ , we obtain about 41% (27% over 7,471 observations) of $\sigma _{RK,S}$ estimates and about 71% (45% over 7,471 observations) of $\sigma _{RK,U}$ estimates that are statistically significant at least at the 10% level.

22 Moore observed an exponential growth of semiconductor capacity (i.e., the number of components per integrated circuit) in 1965, with a good regularity, at least until the end of ’90s, followed by a slight decline in ’00s (Mack, Reference Mack2011; Schaller, Reference Schaller1997). For an economic application, see Jovanovic and Rousseau (Reference Jovanovic and Rousseau2002).

23 The problem of additional variance implied by generated regressors back 40 years ago to Adrian Pagan (see, Oxley & McAleer (Reference Oxley and McAleer1993) for a survey). We use bootstrapped standard errors as a common solution to deal with this issue.

24 As pointed out by Knoblach and Stöckl (Reference Knoblach and Stöckl2020), the determinants of EoS between capital and labor include, among others, institutional characteristics (e.g., labor market regulations and unions), monetary policy, and financial system. In terms of data, these are mostly available at a country level. To absorb such characteristics, we use country and/or sector controls.

25 The specification in (F.1) implies the crucial assumption of treating $NRK$ as completely neutral with respect to different skill groups. Nonetheless, due to data availability — especially from a macro perspective — and constraints imposed by the functional forms, there are not many ways to overcome this issue, and such a formulation turns out to be suitable in our case to test our “RK-Skill complementarity hypothesis.

26 As an extended analysis, we also test the total capital-skill complementarity hypothesis, from a country-industry perspective, in the spirit of Duffy et al. (Reference Duffy, Papageorgiou and Perez-Sebastian2004). Estimations performed on both the WIOD and EU KLEMS samples generally confirm the hypothesis of a lower EoS between capital stock and $S$ . Additionally, we also find evidence of the robotic (and ICT) capital-skill complementarity hypothesis according to a six-factor production function. Results of these specifications are not presented here for reasons of space, but are available upon request.

References

Acemoglu, D. (1998) Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(4), 10551089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002) Directed technical change. The Review of Economic Studies 69(4), 781809.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Autor, D. (2011) Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for employment and earnings, Handbook of Labor Economics, vol. 4, pp. 10431171, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Restrepo, P. (2020) Robots and jobs: Evidence from US labor markets. Journal of Political Economy 128(6), 21882244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerberg, D. A., Caves, K. and Frazer, G. (2015) Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica, 83(6), 24112451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Battisti, M. and Zeira, J. (2018) Technology and labor regulations: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Growth 23(1), 4178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D., Goldin, C. and Katz, L. F. (2020, May) Extending the race between education and technology. AEA Papers and Proceedings. 110, 347351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D. H. (2015) Why are there still so many jobs? The history and future of workplace automation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 29(3), 330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D. H. and Dorn, D. (2013) The growth of low-skill service jobs and the polarization of the US labor market. American Economic Review 103(5), 15531597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, D. H., Levy, F. and Murnane, R. J. (2003) The skill content of recent technological change: An empirical exploration. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(4), 12791333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battisti, M., Gatto, M. D. and Parmeter, C. F. (2022) Skill-biased technical change and labor market inefficiency. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control. 139, 104428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, A., Buffie, E. F. and Zanna, L.-F. (2018) Should we fear the robot revolution? (The correct answer is yes). Journal of Monetary Economics. 97, 117148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blackorby, C. and Russell, R. R. (1981) The Morishima elasticity of substitution; symmetry, constancy, separability, and its relationship to the Hicks and Allen elasticities. The Review of Economic Studies 48(1), 147158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonfiglioli, A., Crino’, R., Gancia, G. and Papadakis, I. (2022) Robots, Offshoring and Welfare. In: Bonfiglioli, A., Crino’, R., Gancia, G. and Papadakis, I.. (eds.), Robots and AI: A New Economic Era, Taylor & Francis.Google Scholar
Brynjolfsson, E. (1993) The productivity paradox of information technology. Communications of the ACM 36(12), 6677.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caselli, F. and Manning, A. (2019) Robot arithmetic: New technology and wages. American Economic Review: Insights 1(1), 112.Google Scholar
Chu, B. (2023) Local linear regression with nonparametrically generated covariates for weakly dependent data. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 225, 89109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costinot, A. and Werning, I. (2020) Robots, trade, and luddism: A sufficient statistic approach to optimal technology regulation, National Bureau of Economic Research, Technical report.Google Scholar
David, P. A. and Van de Klundert, T. (1965) Biased efficiency growth and capital-labor substitution in the us. The American Economic Review 1960, 357394.Google Scholar
Diamond, P., McFadden, D. and Rodriguez, M. (1978) Measurement of the elasticity of factor substitution and bias of technical change, Contributions to economic analysis, vol. 2, pp. 125147, Elsevier.Google Scholar
Division, U. N. S. (2008) International Standard Industrial Classification of all Economic Activities (ISIC), vol. Number 4. New York: United Nations Publications, United Nations Statistics Division.Google Scholar
Duffy, J., Papageorgiou, C. and Perez-Sebastian, F. (2004) Capital-skill complementarity? Evidence from a panel of countries. Review of Economics and Statistics 86(1), 327344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eden, M. and Gaggl, P. (2018) On the welfare implications of automation. Review of Economic Dynamics. 29, 1543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estlund, C. (2021) Automation Anxiety: Why and How to Save Work. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faber, M. (2020) Robots and reshoring: Evidence from Mexican labor markets. Journal of International Economics 127, 103384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fajgelbaum, P. D. and Khandelwal, A. K. (2022) The economic impacts of the US–China trade war. Annual Review of Economics 14(1), 205228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fallon, P. R. and Layard, P. R. G. (1975) Capital-skill complementarity, income distribution, and output accounting. Journal of Political Economy 83(2), 279302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ford, M. (2015) Rise of the Robots: Technology and the Threat of a Jobless Future. Hachette, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Furman, J. (2016) Is this time different? The opportunities and challenges of artificial intelligence, presentation, AI Now: The Social and Economic Implications of Artificial Intelligence Technologies in the Near Term, New York, NY Google Scholar
Gandhi, A., Navarro, S. and Rivers, D. A. (2020) On the identification of gross output production functions. Journal of Political Economy, 128(8), 29733016.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gechert, S., Havranek, T., Irsova, Z. and Kolcunova, D. (2022) Measuring capital-labor substitution: The importance of method choices and publication bias. Review of Economic Dynamics. 45, 5582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, C. D. and Katz, L. F. (2009) The race between education and technology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Graetz, G. and Michaels, G. (2018) Robots at work. Review of Economics and Statistics 100(5), 753768.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griliches, Z. (1969) Capital-skill complementarity. Review of Economics and Statistics 51(4), 465468.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guerreiro, J., Rebelo, S. and Teles, P. (2022) Should robots be taxed? The Review of Economic Studies 89(1), 279311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, P. G. and Racine, J. S. (2015) Infinite order cross-validated local polynomial regression. Journal of Econometrics 185(2), 510525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hémous, D. and Olsen, M. (2022) The rise of the machines: Automation, horizontal innovation, and income inequality. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 14(1), 179223.Google Scholar
Henderson, D. J. (2009) A non-parametric examination of capital–skill complementarity. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71(4), 519538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henderson, D. J., Kumbhakar, S. C., Li, Q. and Parmeter, C. F. (2015) Smooth coefficient estimation of a seemingly unrelated regression. Journal of Econometrics 189(1), 148162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. P. (2014) The relative price of services. Review of Income and Wealth 60(4), 727746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Federation of Robotics (2005) World robotics industrial robots. Technical report.Google Scholar
International Federation of Robotics (2019) World robotics industrial robots. Technical report.Google Scholar
Jaimovich, N., Saporta-Eksten, I., Siu, H. and Yedid-Levi, Y. (2021) The macroeconomics of automation: Data, theory, and policy analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics. 122, 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaimovich, N. and Siu, H. E. (2020) Job polarization and jobless recoveries. Review of Economics and Statistics 102(1), 129147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jovanovic, B. and Rousseau, P. L. (2002) Moore’s law and learning by doing. Review of Economic Dynamics 5(2), 346375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jurkat, A., Klump, R. and Schneider, F. (2022) Tracking the rise of robots: The ifr database. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 242(5-6), 669689.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, L. F. and Murphy, K. M. (1992) Changes in relative wages, 1987: Supply and demand factors. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(1), 3578, 1963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knoblach, M. and Stöckl, F. (2020) What determines the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor? A literature review. Journal of Economic Surveys 34(4), 847875.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, M., Manuylov, I. and Smolka, M. (2021) Robots and firms. The Economic Journal 131(638), 25532584.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krugman, P. (1979) A model of innovation, technology transfer, and the world distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy 87(2), 253266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P., Ohanian, L. E., Ríos-Rull, J.-V. and Violante, G. L. (2000) Capital-skill complementarity and inequality: A macroeconomic analysis. Econometrica 68(5), 10291053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunst, D., Freeman, R. B. and Oostendorp, R. (2022) Occupational skill premia around the world: New data, patterns and drivers. Labour Economics. 79, 102255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leduc, S. and Liu, Z. (2020) Can pandemic-induced job uncertainty stimulate automation?, San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2020-19.Google Scholar
Li, Q. and Racine, J. S. (2007) Nonparametric econometrics: theory and practice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mack, C. A. (2011) Fifty years of moore’s law. IEEE Transactions on semiconductor manufacturing 24(2), 202207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mammen, E., Rothe, C. and Schienle, M. (2012) Nonparametric Regression with Nonparametrically Generated Covariates. The Annals of Statistics, 40(2), 11321170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marschak, J. and Andrews, W. H. (1944) Random simultaneous equations and the theory of production. Econometrica, Journal of the Econometric Society 12(3/4), 143205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michaels, G., Natraj, A. and Van Reenen, J. (2014) Has ICT polarized skill demand? Evidence from eleven countries over twenty-five years. Review of Economics and Statistics 96(1), 6077.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, J., Vickers, C. and Ziebarth, N. L. (2015) The history of technological anxiety and the future of economic growth: Is this time different? Journal of Economic Perspectives 29(3), 3150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moll, B., Rachel, L. and Restrepo, P. (2021) Uneven growth: automation’s impact on income and wealth inequality, National Bureau of Economic Research, Technical report.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muro, M., Maxim, R. and Whiton, J. (2020) The robots are ready as the COVID-19 recession spreads. Brookings Metro’s COVID-19 Analysis. 24.Google Scholar
O’Mahony, M. and Timmer, M. P. (2009) Output, input and productivity measures at the industry level: the EU KLEMS database. The Economic Journal 119(538), F374F403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okyere, M. A., Forson, R. and Essel-Gaisey, F. (2020) Positive externalities of an epidemic: the case of the coronavirus (COVID-19) in China. Journal of Medical Virology 92(9), 13761379.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Olley, G. S. and Pakes, A. (1996). The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry. Econometrica, 64(6), 12631297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oxley, L. and McAleer, M. (1993) Econometric issues in macroeconomic models with generated regressors. Journal of Economic Surveys 7(1), 140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prettner, K. and Bloom, D. (2020) Automation and its Macroeconomic Consequences. Cambridge, MA: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Racine, J. and Li, Q. (2004) Nonparametric estimation of regression functions with both categorical and continuous data. Journal of Econometrics 119(1), 99130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raveh, O. and Reshef, A. (2016) Capital imports composition, complementarities, and the skill premium in developing countries. Journal of Development Economics. 118, 183206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redding, S. J. and Weinstein, D. E. (2020) A unified approach to estimating demand and welfare changes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135(1), 503560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schaller, R. R. (1997) Moore’s law: Past, present and future. IEEE spectrum 34(6), 5259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schivardi, F. and Schmitz, T. (2018) The IT revolution and southern Europe’s two lost decades. Journal of the European Economic Association 18(5), 24412486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singer, P. W. (2009) Military robots and the laws of war. The New Atlantis 23, 2545.Google Scholar
Susskind, D. (2020) A World Without Work: Technology, Automation and how We Should Respond. London: Penguin UK.Google Scholar
Taniguchi, H. and Yamada, K. (2022) ICT capital-skill complementarity and wage inequality: Evidence from OECD countries. Labour Economics 10, 2151.Google Scholar
Timmer, M. P., Dietzenbacher, E., Los, B., Stehrer, R. and De Vries, G. J. (2015) An illustrated user guide to the world input–output database: The case of global automotive production. Review of International Economics 23(3), 575605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinbergen, J. (1974) Substitution of graduate by other labour. Kyklos 27(2), 217226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
vom Lehn, C. (2020) Labor market polarization, the decline of routine work, and technological change: A quantitative analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics. 110, 6280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, D. M. (2018) The Future of Work: Robots, AI, and Automation. Washington D.C: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Robot diffusion, 1995–2009 and 1995–2018, USA.Elaboration on IFR and WIOD data.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Evolution of robotic capital and other forms of capital: % growth rates, 1994–2005 (1994 = 1).Elaboration on IFR and EUKLEMS data.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Share of robotic capital (% of total capital) in the more robotized countries and industries, 1995–2009, average values.Elaboration on IFR and EU KLEMS data.

Figure 3

Figure 4. Kernel distribution of the estimated median Morishima EoS, 1995–2009.

Figure 4

Figure 5. EoS normalized cumulative distribution: time dynamics.

Figure 5

Figure 6. EoS estimated patterns, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

Figure 6

Figure 7. EoS estimated patterns in selected (groups of) countries, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

Figure 7

Figure 8. EoS estimated patterns in selected (groups of) sectors, 1995–2009, normalized median values.

Figure 8

Table 1. Estimated EoS: different depreciation rates and different types of capital. Median values

Figure 9

Figure 9. Estimated patterns of $\sigma _{IK,S}$ and $\sigma _{IK,U}$, OECD, 1994–2005.

Figure 10

Figure 10. Evolution of robot price over unskilled/skilled wage ratio, US and Japan, 1995–2009.

Figure 11

Figure 11. Evolution of marginal product of robotic capital, 1995–2009.

Figure 12

Table 2. Price and productivity effects (Eq. 3)

Figure 13

Table C1. List of WIOD and EU KLEMS countries

Figure 14

Table C2. List of industries

Figure 15

Table D1a. IFR-WIOD dataset: main variables’ average by country

Figure 16

Table D1b. IFR-WIOD dataset: main variables’ average by industry

Figure 17

Table D2a. IFR-EU KLEMS dataset: main variables’ average by country

Figure 18

Table D2b. IFR-EU KLEMS dataset: main variables’ average by industry

Figure 19

Figure E1. Robotic capital evolution in selected WIOD countries and industries 1995–2009.

Figure 20

Figure E2. Kernel distribution of the estimated morishima EoS, 1995–2009.

Figure 21

Table F1. EoS, parametric estimates

Figure 22

Table F2. Robustness checks: EoS, parametric estimates. Different $RK$ depreciation rates