Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-29T05:36:13.390Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Affluence and Influence in a Social Democracy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 July 2022

RUBEN B. MATHISEN*
Affiliation:
University of Bergen, Norway
*
Ruben B. Mathisen, PhD Candidate, Department of Comparative Politics, University of Bergen, Norway, Ruben.Mathisen@uib.no.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Research from the United States and Europe suggests that affluent citizens enjoy considerably more policy influence than do average citizens and the poor. I examine the extent of unequal policy responsiveness in one of the countries that have gone farthest in reducing economic inequality and restricting money in politics: Norway. I use an original dataset on public opinion and public policy containing 603 specific issues over five decades (1966–2014). The results show that although policy is certainly skewed toward the preferences of the privileged, Norway stands out among previously studied cases for two reasons: (1) The preferences of the poor seem to have some sway on economic issues and (2) not all affluent citizens get their way: educational attainment appears to be the more important determinant. The Norwegian case suggests that influence need not be as dependent upon affluence as in the United States.

Type
Letter
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the American Political Science Association

“[C]ountries in Scandinavia, like Denmark, Norway, Sweden, they are very democratic countries, obviously.” —Bernie SandersFootnote 1

Introduction

A defining feature of democracy is that citizens, considered as political equals, have influence over policy making. In contrast to this ideal, there is mounting evidence from the United States suggesting that the rich enjoy disproportionately large policy influence at the expense of the average citizen (Bartels Reference Bartels2016; Erikson Reference Erikson2015; Gilens Reference Gilens2012). Research on this topic for the rest of the world remains sparse. There are some studies that have looked at differential responsiveness in Western Europe (Elsässer, Hense, and Schäfer Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2017; Peters and Ensink Reference Erikson2015; Rosset Reference Rosset2016). They tend to point in the same direction as the American studies, but they are usually not directly comparable to them. If we were to measure political inequality in exactly the same way as has been done in the most prominent U.S. studies (Gilens Reference Gilens2012; Gilens and Page Reference Gilens and Page2014), but in a social democracy that has come far in equalizing opportunities, economic differences, and limiting the role of money in politics, what would we find? Would the poor and middle class have more influence than in the US and Western Europe?

Academics disagree about the roots of political inequality and, consequently, how it can be tackled. Some argue that institutional reform such as tightening the rules on electoral campaign finance (Page and Gilens Reference Page and Gilens2020), more descriptive representation in parliament (Carnes Reference Carnes2013), and redistributing income and wealth (Piketty Reference Piketty2020), should lead to a more even dispersion of political power. Others are not that optimistic. Unequal responsiveness could be a systemic problem of capitalism or, worse, a direct consequence of any distribution of economic resources that is not equal (Przeworski Reference Przeworski2012). The debate is not new. In fact it was salient in the early twentieth century, when the socialist movement split into reformists who believed that ”the people” could successfully voice their opinions through electoral politics, and revolutionaries who believed it to be a lost cause. The reformists developed social democracy as a compromise intended to ensure workers’ control over politics, within a capitalist system (Przeworski Reference Przeworski1986). Whether it succeeded is an open question.

In this research letter, I apply the methodology from one of the flagship studies of political inequality in the US, Affluence and Influence (Gilens Reference Gilens2012), to a very different case—namely Norway. Norway is a prime example of social democracy, with low levels of income inequality, strict regulations of campaign spending, strong unions, and a generous welfare state. If social democracy is capable of curtailing the disproportionate influence of the affluent, then we should see it in this case. I constructed an original dataset of Norwegian public opinion on 603 specific policy proposals at the national level from representative surveys between 1966 and 2014. Then, for each proposal, I estimated the level of support among different income percentiles and matched those data with information on which of the proposals were subsequently adopted by government.

I find that although public policy in Norway is clearly tilted toward the preferences of high-income citizens (Figure 1), the affluent do not appear to enjoy the kind of exclusive influence that characterizes the American case. First, within economic issues the preferences of both the poor and the affluent seem to matter (Figure 2). Second, the opinions of the highly educated are strongly related to policy regardless of their income (Figure 3). These results suggest a weaker link between money and politics in Norway than in the US.

Figure 1. Policy Responsiveness to High Income and Median Income Respondents When Their Preferences Diverge by More Than 10 Percentage Points

Note: Predicted probabilities for each whole percentage between 5% and 95% support, based on the logistic regressions reported in Table 2 (rows 3 and 4).

Figure 2. Unequal Responsiveness When Preferences Diverge, by Policy Area

Note: Full results reported in Appendix Table A3. Standard errors in parentheses.

Figure 3. Income versus Education, Norway and the US Compared

Note: “High” is the 90th income/education percentile; “low” is the 10th income/education percentile. Standard errors in parentheses. Full results reported in Appendix Table E1.

Case Study: Norway

Norway is commonly perceived to be a particularly well-functioning democracy, with little room for the rich to exert disproportionate political influence (EIU 2020). There are several plausible reasons for this.

First, Norway is widely considered a social democracy in the comparative welfare state literature (Esping-Andersen Reference Esping-Andersen1990; Powell, Yörük, and Bargu Reference Powell, Yörük and Bargu2020). As such, it has generous and universal welfare schemes and high levels of redistribution (Hicks Reference Hicks1999). In combination with strong unions and centralized wage bargaining that contribute to a compressed wage structure (Allern, Aylott, and Christiansen Reference Allern, Aylott and Christiansen2007; Pontusson, Rueda, and Way Reference Pontusson, Rueda and Way2002), the resulting level of income inequality is among the lowest in the world.Footnote 2 Low inequality implies less of a resource advantage for the affluent to be used (in whichever way possible) to influence politics. Additionally, it has been argued that the universality of the social democratic welfare schemes generates legitimacy and support across classes (Rothstein Reference Rothstein2005). That means that such policies, which are usually strongly favored by the poor, have a better chance at being maintained or even expanded by government (Brooks and Manza Reference Brooks and Manza2008). Thus, the process might have a self-reinforcing component by which new policy gains for the poor are more easily achieved over time.

Second, in contrast to the US, where political candidates depend on large donations from private individuals and organizations to run effective election campaigns (Ferguson Reference Ferguson1995), parties in Norway get about two-thirds of their financing from public subsidies.Footnote 3 The country also maintains a general ban on political advertisement on television, which is the major campaign expenditure in the US (Ridout et al. Reference Ridout, Franz, Goldstein and Feltus2012).

Third, Norway has historically had strong trade unions. In the literature, unions have been found to be pivotal in shaping social welfare policy in the interest of organized workers (Esping-Andersen Reference Esping-Andersen1990). Norwegian unions have influenced economic and social policy through pressure in the corporate channel but also through their close ties with the Norwegian Labor Party (Allern, Aylott, and Christiansen Reference Allern, Aylott and Christiansen2007). In the context of policy responsiveness, this could serve as a countervailing force to the influence of the wealthy.

Fourth, Norway’s exceptional oil and gas resources have widened the spectrum of policy options available to government by allowing extra spending, usually amounting to around 5% of mainland GDP every year (Holden Reference Holden2013). Potentially, this makes it easier to respond to a diverse set of popular preferences. To illustrate, Norway has been able to maintain generous welfare transfers while imposing lower tax rates than would otherwise be necessary (Holden Reference Holden2013), presumably catering to the preferences of both the poor and the wealthy. Also, during economic crises, such as the Great Recession in 2008, the government has used oil money, rather than spending cuts or tax increases, to finance stimulus packages (Mjøset and Cappelen Reference Mjøset, Cappelen and Mjøset2011).

Finally, the country’s political class is not particularly rich. Although MP salaries surely are in the top third of the income distribution, the median wealth among MPs is in fact zero, according to tax data.Footnote 4 Therefore, it is unlikely that policy is biased toward the rich because politicians are rich themselves (Carnes Reference Carnes2013).

To be sure though, relatively small differences in political influence between rich and poor in Norway could have more indirect reasons if, for instance, there were little political inequality along—or simply an absence of—other dimensions that usually intersect with economic affluence, such as gender or ethnicity (Crenshaw Reference Crenshaw1989). Previous studies in the US and Europe have suggested that the interests of both women and ethnic minorities tend to be politically underrepresented (Costa Reference Costa2017; Reher Reference Reher2018; Whitby Reference Whitby2000). However, in Norway, policy makers have actively sought to increase the political influence of women—for example, by adopting laws requiring gender balancing in government institutions and company boards, an approach sometimes called “state feminism” (Hernes Reference Hernes1987; Siim and Skjeie Reference Siim and Skjeie2008). Because women on average have lower income than men do,Footnote 5 these measures might have indirectly increased the influence of low-income citizens. Furthermore, for most of the period under investigation here, both ethnic fractionalization in Norway and the share of foreign-born citizens have been comparatively low (Dražanová Reference Dražanová2020; see Appendix H). The absence of a prominent ethnic cleavage overlapping with class suggests that this type of double underrepresentation might not be as common among the Norwegian poor as for example among the poor in the US (e.g., Strolovitch Reference Strolovitch2008).

Measuring Policy Responsiveness

To examine the possibility of unequal responsiveness in Norway, I constructed an original dataset, containing Norwegian public opinion on 603 concrete policy proposals at the national level as well as information on which of these proposals were subsequently adopted by government. The dataset was constructed following the same procedure as in Gilens (Reference Gilens2012). Policy questions posed to representative samples of the Norwegian population were extracted from preexisting surveys.Footnote 6 Data were available for the period 1966–2014. To be included in the dataset, questions had to ask respondents whether they support or oppose some change in national government policy. This can be anything from “should the right to abortion be extended to week 16?” to “should Norway send troops to Afghanistan?” The proposed change had to be specific enough so that it could be reliably determined whether or not the change was subsequently adopted.

I managed to obtain 431 survey items from commercial surveys and 172 from academic ones (total of 603). I then imputed, for each policy proposal, the percentage that favored the proposed change among respondents at different income percentiles, using Gilens’ approach. Finally, each proposal was coded, using government and media sources, as either adopted or not adopted in the subsequent four years (for details about the data collection and imputation method, see Appendix F).

Three studies inspired by Gilens (Reference Gilens2012) have examined unequal policy responsiveness outside the US. All find that policy is skewed toward the preferences of the affluent. Although all provide interesting results, only one of the studies, of Germany (Elsässer, Hense, and Schäfer Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2017), is directly comparable to Gilens’s results for the US. For the other two, the Netherlands (Schakel Reference Schakel2021) and Sweden (Persson and Gilljam Reference Persson and Gilljam2017), according to the authors, the results are not strictly comparable because their survey data partially or fully come from academic sources, whereas Gilens (Reference Gilens2012, 54–6) used commercial survey data (the distinction is discussed in Appendix D).

To make my data maximally comparable to Gilens’s U.S. data, I do three things: (1) I primarily analyze the sample of proposals from the commercial surveys, (2) I filter out policy proposals that would require constitutional change (n = 43), and (3) I remove policy proposals that were “half-adopted” (n = 3; Gilens Reference Gilens2012, 60). After this, 397 proposals are left for the analysis below.Footnote 7

Findings

I begin by looking at the overall relationship between public opinion and policy.Footnote 8 A simple bivariate logistic regression of policy outcome on policy support (Table 1, first row) suggests a moderate relationship between what the public wants and what it gets (b = 0.44, p < 0.001).Footnote 9 Predicted probabilities allow us to better understand the size of the effect: If 20% of Norwegians support a policy proposal, it has a predicted 17% chance of being adopted within the subsequent four years. If 80% favor it, the probability increases to 41% (i.e., it increases by a factor of 2.4). Public opinion matters, although with a status quo bias. This is quite similar to the results from the US (see Gilens Reference Gilens2012, 76).

Table 1. Policy Responsiveness by Income

Note: Bivariate logistic regression models (rows). The dependent variable is a dichotomous measure of whether or not the policy change was adopted within four years of the time of the survey question. *p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Next, Table 1 presents results from bivariate logistic regression models where policy outcome is regressed on the policy support of five income percentiles. Although the effect sizes vary (from a factor 1.8 for the 10th percentile, to 2.3 for the 50th, to 2.9 for the 90th), all income groups have a positive, statistically significant effect on policy.

However, the preferences of the income groups are highly correlated. Consequently, the moderate responsiveness to the preferences of the middle-class and the poor that we observe in Table 1 could arise merely because these groups often want the same from government as do the affluent. In order to disentangle the preferences of the income groups and estimate their independent effects, one would normally use multivariate regression. But as Gilens (Reference Gilens2012) points out, this will produce biased results due to the correlated measurement error of the opinion estimates for the income percentiles (Achen Reference Achen1985). As an alternative, I subset the data, as has become standard in this type of study, keeping only policy proposals where preferences diverge by at least 10 percentage points across income groups (Elsässer, Hense, and Schäfer Reference Elsässer, Hense and Schäfer2017; Gilens Reference Gilens2012; Schakel Reference Schakel2021).Footnote 10

Having filtered out the policy proposals where income groups more or less agree, Table 2 paints a very different picture of whose opinions matter. Although the preferences of the affluent still have a substantial, statistically significant effect on policy, there is no detectable effect for any of the other income groups. On the issues where the preferences of the affluent and the poor diverge, responsiveness to the preferences of the affluent is even greater than before: From low to high popularity among affluent respondents, the probability of policy adoption changes from 13% to 59% (factor of 4.7). In contrast, popularity among the poor only marginally affects the probability (28% vs. 33%, factor of 1.2), and the effect is statistically indistinguishable from zero (p = 0.66). When comparing the affluent and the middle class in the same way, I find the same: responsiveness to the affluent is substantial (factor of 3.9), whereas responsiveness to the middle class is weak and insignificant (factor of 1.1, p = 0.9). The magnitude of this unequal responsiveness is illustrated in Figure 1, which plots predicted probabilities of policy change at different levels of support among the middle class and the affluent.

Table 2. Policy Responsiveness When Preferences Diverge by More Than 10 Points across Income Percentiles

Note: Bivariate logistic regression models (rows). The dependent variable is a dichotomous measure of whether or not the policy change was adopted within four years of the time of the survey question. Poor = P10, Middle = P50, and Affluent = P90. *p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

To rule out that the results above are caused by the more or less arbitrary choice of a 10-point threshold for preference divergence, I also ran the regression models in Table 2 using multiple different thresholds. This showed a clear pattern of increasing unequal responsiveness the higher the threshold (see Appendix B). I also checked whether unequal responsiveness has increased over time and whether it is lower on highly salient issues. The results suggest that unequal responsiveness has been quite stable over time and that it does not decrease on the more salient proposals (see Appendix C).

Is there any policy area in which the preferences of the poor matter? Yes. Figure 2 shows estimates of responsiveness for the poor and the affluent, by policy area.Footnote 11 Within moral issues, foreign policy and national security, and other (uncategorized) issues, the familiar pattern is observed: strong effect for the affluent, near zero effect for the poor. The economic area is somewhat different. Here as well, responsiveness to the affluent is substantial, but so is responsiveness to the poor. Given that the proposals of relative agreement have been excluded, it seems that on economic policy, the government sometimes follows the will of the affluent and other times the will of the poor, when the two are opposed.

Although my data do not include public opinion estimates by race/ethnicity, they do contain estimates by gender. Regression results (Appendix G) suggest that on economic issues, women’s preferences are better represented than are men’s (despite being less represented overall). Because women on average have lower income than men do, this could possibly account for some of the responsiveness to low-income citizens in this area.

Is the overall policy bias toward the preferences of the affluent simply explained by the fact that they are more educated than the rest? To investigate this, I imputed the policy preferences of different combinations of income and education percentile (see Appendix E). Then, I estimated policy responsiveness to income percentiles at the same level of education. The results, presented in Appendix Table E1, show that education explains some but not all of the unequal responsiveness across economic groups. Still, what is also evident from the results is that education has a stronger effect than income. For example, the preferences of respondents with high education and low income (i.e., at the 90th education percentile and 10th income percentile) have a strong effect on policy, whereas respondents with high income and low education have a weak, insignificant effect.Footnote 12 This suggests that education is by itself enough to see ones preferences reflected in policy. Income, on the other hand, must be coupled with a certain level of education. This is interesting because it is the exact opposite from what Gilens found in the US. In the US, “high income alone seems sufficient to ensure a strong association between preferences and outcome, while education alone does not” (Gilens Reference Gilens2012, 95). This contrast is visualized in Figure 3, where the results from Norway are juxtaposed to the equivalent ones for the US.Footnote 13

Implications

The findings of this study are twofold. On the one hand, there are surprising similarities between my results for Norway and Gilens’s (Reference Gilens2012) results for the United States. The most important is that public policy tends to be heavily skewed toward the preferences of the privileged, violating the democratic principle of political equality. However, the Norwegian case deviates from the American in two rather consequential ways, suggesting that influence is not quite as dependent on affluence as in the US.

First, the data show responsiveness to both poor and rich citizens on economic issues. It is somewhat striking that the exception lies in this particular area, given that it is here that class interests are most clearly opposed and where one usually expects the wealthy to wield the strongest influence. One plausible explanation is the focus on economic welfare and redistribution in Norway’s social democratic project as well as the powerful allies that the poor have in this domain through the unions and the left (Allern, Aylott, and Christiansen Reference Allern, Aylott and Christiansen2007). In that case, it suggests that social democracy can be expected to empower the have-nots in one of the policy areas that affects them the most as a class. It is also possible that Norway’s gender equality policies have indirectly increased the voice of the less well-off. To be sure though, Norway’s oil wealth might play a special role within the economic sphere by granting government extra leeway to satisfy the interests of both affluent and poor (Holden Reference Holden2013). If this is indeed an important part of the explanation, Norway might represent a sort of upper bound of what can be expected from social democracies in terms of equality of responsiveness.

Second, education is a stronger predictor of responsiveness than income; the opposite of what Gilens (Reference Gilens2012) found in the US. In Norway, public policy generally reflects the preferences of low-income citizens, so long as they are higher educated. A possible explanation is the fact that government members are predominantly recruited from the highly educated, which causes their descriptive overrepresentation (Bovens and Wille Reference Bovens and Wille2017; Lie Andersen Reference Lie Andersen, Korsnes, Hansen and Hjellbrekke2014). Although this is certainly also the case in the US (Carnes Reference Carnes2013), there might be more room for it to have an effect on policy in Norway. The importance of political finance in U.S. elections constrains the behavior of politicians as they try to attract private funding (Ferguson Reference Ferguson1995). The absence of a comparable mechanism in Norway would imply that other factors, such as an education-based value system, could potentially play a larger role in determining their behavior.

It is important to emphasize that the type of data employed here, and in Gilens (Reference Gilens2012), cannot demonstrate that popular opinions are in fact causing policy change. Even though this is the usual interpretation of opinion–policy links in the literature, there is evidence of reversed causality as well: cues from political elites can shape public opinion, and such effects might be stronger and occur more quickly for the rich and highly educated (Zaller Reference Zaller1992), possibly explaining part of the unequal responsiveness. Although Gilens (Reference Gilens2012, 93–6) argued that this was unlikely in the American case, it cannot be ruled out as an explanation for my results. However, it is unlikely to be the whole story. For example, it does not explain why there would be less unequal responsiveness on economic issues, as shown above.

The main conclusion from this study is that although social democracy, of the kind that exists in Norway, probably cannot be counted on to eliminate political inequality, the link between money and politics does appear to be weaker than in the American case. Public policy, at least partially, reflects the economic preferences of the poor and is robustly associated with the preferences of the highly educated, suggesting that political influence need not be reserved for the affluent.

Achieving results similar to those of Norway in other contexts could prove difficult and perhaps most difficult precisely where reforms are most needed—that is, where the affluent already hold dominant influence. Still, reducing the initial level of economic inequality, restricting how money can be used to influence elections, and strengthening the countervailing forces (such as unions), are some steps that might change the balance of power in favor of the less well-off.

Supplementary Materials

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055422000739.

DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

Research documentation and data that support the findings of this study are openly available at the American Political Science Review Dataverse: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ISBPIH.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I would like to thank Martin Gilens, Yvette Peters, Cornelius Cappelen, Jonas Pontusson, Jonas Linde, all participants at the 2019 Roots of Political Inequality Workshop in Paris, all participants at the Solstrand PhD seminar and the CORE research group at the Department of Comparative Politics (UIB), three anonymous reviewers, and the editors, for their valuable feedback. I also thank Martin Jamne for research assistance and the Norwegian Centre for Research Data and the Norwegian Citizen Panel for data access.

FUNDING STATEMENT

The research was supported by the Meltzer Research Fund, grant #19225.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST

The author declares no ethical issues or conflicts of interest in this research.

ETHICAL STANDARDS

The author affirms this research did not involve human subjects.

Footnotes

3 Accessed January 25, 2020, https://www.ssb.no/valg/statistikker/partifin.

5 As late as 2011, the average household income of women was still 71% of the average among men. Accessed July 28, 2021, https://www.ssb.no/statbank/table/09903/.

6 The replication materials include the finalized dataset as well as all code necessary to reproduce the dataset and analyses (Mathisen Reference Gilens2022). However, the original surveys files are subject to restricted access. Appendix I explains how interested researchers can obtain such access.

7 Analyses with the academic surveys included showed somewhat less unequal responsiveness across income groups, strengthening the paper’s final conclusion (see Appendix D).

8 I refer to this relationship as policy responsiveness.

9 Overall, 27% of the proposed policies were adopted. All support variables are logit transformed as in Gilens (Reference Gilens2012, 73–96).

10 Appendix A reports some of the most contested proposals in different policy areas.

11 See Appendix A for an overview of how proposals were coded into different areas.

12 Appendix H shows, using registry data, that these two groups are comparable in size in the actual population and that although the groups disproportionately consist of certain types of occupations (e.g., service workers and teachers in the group with low income/high education; managers in the opposite group), they are quite heterogeneous. Therefore, it seems unlikely that such differences would be driving much of the reported effects.

13 Extracted from Table A3.4 in Gilens (Reference Gilens2012, 259).

References

REFERENCES

Achen, Christopher H. 1985. “Proxy Variables and Incorrect Signs on Regression Coefficients.” Political Methodology 11 (3/4): 299316.Google Scholar
Allern, Elin Haugsgjerd, Aylott, Nicholas, and Christiansen, Flemming Juul. 2007. “Social Democrats and Trade Unions in Scandinavia: The Decline and Persistence of Institutional Relationships.” European Journal of Political Research 46 (5): 607–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 2016. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bovens, Mark, and Wille, Anchrit. 2017. Diploma Democracy: The Rise of Political Meritocracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Brooks, Clem, and Manza, Jeff. 2008. Why Welfare States Persist: The Importance of Public Opinion in Democracies. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Carnes, Nicholas. 2013. White-Collar Government: The Hidden Role of Class in Economic Policy Making. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Costa, Mia. 2017. “How Responsive Are Political Elites? A Meta-Analysis of Experiments on Public Officials.” Journal of Experimental Political Science 4 (3): 241–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crenshaw, Kimberlé. 1989. “Demarginalizing the Intersection of Race and Sex: A Black Feminist Critique of Antidiscrimination Doctrine, Feminist Theory and Antiracist Politics.” University of Chicago Legal Forum 1989 (1): article 8.Google Scholar
Dražanová, Lenka. 2020. “Introducing the Historical Index of Ethnic Fractionalization (HIEF) Dataset: Accounting for Longitudinal Changes in Ethnic Diversity.” Journal of Open Humanities Data. https://openhumanitiesdata.metajnl.com/articles/10.5334/johd.16/.Google Scholar
Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU). 2020. Democracy Index 2020. https://www.eiu.com/n/campaigns/democracy-index-2020/.Google Scholar
Elsässer, Lea, Hense, Svenja, and Schäfer, Armin. 2017. “‘Dem Deutschen Volke’? Die ungleiche Responsivität des Bundestags [Government for the People? Unequal Responsiveness of the Bundestag].” Zeitschrift Für Politikwissenschaft 27 (2): 161–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erikson, Robert S. 2015. “Income Inequality and Policy Responsiveness.” Annual Review of Political Science 18:1129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esping-Andersen, Gosta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Thomas. 1995. Golden Rule: The Investment Theory of Party Competition and the Logic of Money-Driven Political Systems. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin, and Page, Benjamin I.. 2014. “Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (3): 564–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hernes, Helga Maria. 1987. Welfare State and Woman Power: Essays in State Feminism. Oslo: Norwegian University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, Alexander. 1999. Social Democracy & Welfare Capitalism: A Century of Income Security Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Holden, Steinar. 2013. “Avoiding the Resource Curse the Case Norway.” Energy Policy 63 (December): 870–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lie Andersen, P. 2014. “Den norske politiske eliten.” In Elite Og Klasse I et Egalitært Samfunn, eds. Korsnes, Olav, Hansen, Marianne Nordli, and Hjellbrekke, Johs, 144–64. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.Google Scholar
Mathisen, Ruben B. 2022. “Replication Data for: Affluence and Influence in a Social Democracy.” Harvard Dataverse. Dataset. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/ISBPIH.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mjøset, Lars, and Cappelen, Ådne. 2011. “The Integration of the Norwegian Oil Economy into the World Economy.” In The Nordic Varieties of Capitalism, ed. Mjøset, Lars, 167263. Bingley, UK: Emerald Group Publishing Limited.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Benjamin I., and Gilens, Martin. 2020. Democracy in America? What Has Gone Wrong and What We Can Do about It. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Mikael, and Gilljam, M.. 2017. “Who Got What They Wanted? The Opinion-Policy Link in Sweden 1956-2014.” University of Gothenburg. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas. 2020. Capital and Ideology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pontusson, Jonas, Rueda, David, and Way, Christopher R.. 2002. “Comparative Political Economy of Wage Distribution: The Role of Partisanship and Labour Market Institutions.” British Journal of Political Science 32 (2) 281308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Martin, Yörük, Erdem, and Bargu, Ali. 2020. “Thirty Years of the Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism: A Review of Reviews.” Social Policy & Administration 54 (1): 6087.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 1986. Capitalism and Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2012. “Democracy, Redistribution, and Equality.” Brazilian Political Science Review 6 (1): 1136.Google Scholar
Reher, Stefanie. 2018. “Gender and Opinion–Policy Congruence in Europe.” European Political Science Review 10 (4): 613–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ridout, Travis N., Franz, Michael, Goldstein, Kenneth M., and Feltus, William J.. 2012. “Separation by Television Program: Understanding the Targeting of Political Advertising in Presidential Elections.” Political Communication 29 (1): 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosset, Jan. 2016. Economic Inequality and Political Representation in Switzerland. Cham, CH: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, Bo. 2005. Social Traps and the Problem of Trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schakel, Wouter. 2021. “Unequal Policy Responsiveness in the Netherlands.” Socio-Economic Review 19 (1): 3757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siim, Birte, and Skjeie, Hege. 2008. “Tracks, Intersections and Dead Ends: Multicultural Challenges to State Feminism in Denmark and Norway.” Ethnicities 8 (3): 322–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strolovitch, Dara Z. 2008. Affirmative Advocacy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Whitby, Kenny J. 2000. The Color of Representation: Congressional Behavior and Black Interests. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Policy Responsiveness to High Income and Median Income Respondents When Their Preferences Diverge by More Than 10 Percentage PointsNote: Predicted probabilities for each whole percentage between 5% and 95% support, based on the logistic regressions reported in Table 2 (rows 3 and 4).

Figure 1

Figure 2. Unequal Responsiveness When Preferences Diverge, by Policy AreaNote: Full results reported in Appendix Table A3. Standard errors in parentheses.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Income versus Education, Norway and the US ComparedNote: “High” is the 90th income/education percentile; “low” is the 10th income/education percentile. Standard errors in parentheses. Full results reported in Appendix Table E1.

Figure 3

Table 1. Policy Responsiveness by Income

Figure 4

Table 2. Policy Responsiveness When Preferences Diverge by More Than 10 Points across Income Percentiles

Supplementary material: Link

Mathisen Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Mathisen supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Mathisen supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 254.5 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.