We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
This chapter presents speculation regarding factors that contributed to the success of the Cobb–Douglas regression. I discuss in particular four factors that helped facilitate the widespread adoption of the regression approach to production function estimation. (i) Douglas’s decision to link his procedure to fundamental concepts of the neoclassical approach to economics, which was destined to grow in influence over the course of the twentieth century. (ii) the flexibility and adaptability of the technique. (iii) Douglas’s rhetoric of persuasion, and (iv) the emergence of prominent advocates for the technique, such as Earl Heady and Zvi Griliches who communicated, by words and example, the attitude that despite its weaknesses, the technique was potentially very valuable, that the best way to realize that potential was to continue using the technique while working to address the weaknesses, and that even while this process of improvement was going on, the technique was still able to contribute to knowledge. The question of why such allies emerge is explored.
This chapter describes a process in which a number of long-standing hypotheses about sources of economic growth came to be represented as a series of modifications to Solow’s basic neoclassical production function, which in turn led to attempts to test empirically these hypotheses using production function regressions. Particular attention is given to two empirical research programs that made use of variants of Douglas’s regression procedure: the literature on “embodied technical change” initiated by Robert Solow, and Zvi Griliches’s work measuring the causes of economic growth, both of which emerged in the late 1950s and early 60s. Griliches and Solow proposed empirically tractable ways of testing various hypotheses about causes of economic growth. Their proposals were attractive in part because they made use of an empirical procedure, production function estimation, that involved statistical methods that were coming to be the foundation of graduate training in econometrics, and because they were expressed in terms of the mathematical neoclassical theory that was becoming central to graduate training in economic theory.
The introduction provides an overview of the book. Although Paul Douglas is the most important person in the story of the Cobb–Douglas regression, the book is not a biography of Douglas, but of his best known and most successful creation. The book covers the period from the mid-1920s, when Douglas was doing the statistical work that led to the first use of the Cobb–Douglas regression, to the late 1960s, when Douglas’s idea had come to be widely accepted by economists, and the CES production function was emerging as the first popular alternative to the Cobb–Douglas function for estimation of production functions. My perspective is mainly that of a historian of the use of statistical analysis in economics, with particular attention given to the challenges faced by empirical researchers, and the roles played by statistical and economic theory in their development of strategies to overcome them. At various point in the book, I reflect on factors that might have helped the production function regression go from an innovative and controversial statistical procedure to a widely accepted general purpose tool in empirical economics.
The Cobb-Douglas regression, a statistical technique developed to estimate what economists called a 'production function', was introduced in the late 1920s. For several years, only economist Paul Douglas and a few collaborators used the technique, while vigorously defending it against numerous critics. By the 1950s, however, several economists beyond Douglas's circle were using the technique, and by the 1970s, Douglas's regression, and more sophisticated procedures inspired by it, had become standard parts of the empirical economist's toolkit. This volume is the story of the Cobb-Douglas regression from its introduction to its acceptance as general-purpose research tool. The story intersects with the histories of several important empirical research programs in twentieth century economics, and vividly portrays the challenges of empirical economic research during that era. Fundamentally, this work represents a case study of how a controversial, innovative research tool comes to be widely accepted by a community of scholars.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.