We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
With the emergence of modern reorganization law in the 1930s, the absolute priority rule came into being. In contrast to what proceeded it, this priority regime cashed out the value of everyone’s stake in the firm at the time of the reorganization. The fifth chapter shows that this idea emerged in large reorganizations not because of any belief in the intrinsic merit of recognizing absolute priority but only because New Deal reformers thought that such a priority rule best protected passive and unsophisticated investors from insiders. Giving each individual creditor the right to insist on being paid in full before anyone junior received anything, however, proved to be incompatible with achieving the mutually beneficial bargains that justified reorganization law in the first instance.
The sixth chapter looks at reorganization practice after the Second World War. The heavy regulatory oversight that New Deal reforms imposed on large firms was unsuccessful. Government regulators showed themselves to be insufficiently nimble. And the law depended too much on judicial valuations that proved too malleable and too uncertain. Moreover, although the norms of the credit men and the emphasis on accommodating worthy debtors worked tolerably well for small businesses, these norms offered judges no easy way to find their bearings elsewhere. Nowhere was this more evident than in real estate insolvencies.
The law of corporate reorganizations controls the fate of enterprises worth billions of dollars and has reshaped entire sectors of the economy, yet its inner workings largely remain a mystery. Judges must police a small and closed fraternity of professionals as they sit down at a conference table and forge a new future for a distressed business, but little appears to tell judges how they are to do this. Judges, however, are in fact bound by a coherent set of unwritten principles that derive from a statute Parliament passed in 1571. These principles are not simply norms or customary practices. They have hard edges, judges must enforce them, and parties are bound by them as they are by any other law. This book traces the evolution of these unwritten principles and makes accessible a legal world that has long been closed off to outsiders.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.