Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T01:06:17.806Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Reasonable Royalties

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 July 2019

C. Bradford Biddle
Affiliation:
Arizona State University
Jorge L. Contreras
Affiliation:
University of Utah
Brian J. Love
Affiliation:
Santa Clara University, California
Norman V. Siebrasse
Affiliation:
University of New Brunswick

Summary

This chapter describes the current state of, and normative basis for, the law of reasonable royalties among the leading jurisdictions for patent infringement litigation, as well as the principal arguments for and against various practices relating to the calculation of reasonable royalties; and for each of the major issues discussed, the chapter provides one or more recommendations.  The chapter’s principal recommendation is that, when applying a “bottom-up” approach to estimating reasonable royalties, courts should replace the Georgia-Pacific factors (and analogous factors used outside the United States) with a smaller list of considerations, specifically (1) calculating the incremental value of the invention and dividing it appropriately between the parties; (2) assessing market evidence, such as comparable licenses; and (3) where feasible and cost justified, using each of these first two considerations as a “check” on the accuracy of the other

Type
Chapter
Information
Patent Remedies and Complex Products
Toward a Global Consensus
, pp. 6 - 49
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2019
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

1.1 Preliminary Matters

This section will briefly describe (a) the extent to which reasonable royalties are awarded in the major jurisdictions for which descriptive statistics are available; (b) the principal theoretical justifications for awarding them; and (c) at a very general level, the principal methods for calculating them.

1.1.1 Empirical Literature

The empirical literature on reasonable royalties consists largely of descriptive statistics reporting median, average, or largest-ever patent damages awards for selected countries. These statistics provide insight into different jurisdictions’ approaches and priorities related to awarding damages.

The most extensive literature on this subject pertains to the United States. According to a 2014 Lex Machina Patent Litigation Damages Report, for example, in 708 U.S. patent cases filed and terminated from 2000 to 2013, district courts awarded over $8 billion in reasonable royalties, slightly less than $3 billion in lost profits, and slightly more than $2 billion in compensatory lump sum damages for which “the specific sub-type (reasonable royalties or lost profits) is not specified or the apportionment of the award between sub-types is not specified.”Footnote 1 Lex Machina’s list of median reasonable royalty, lost profit, and compensatory lump sum awards from 2000 to 2013 indicates that reasonable royalty awards are more common than lost profits awards, but that in some years the median lost profit award exceeded the median reasonable royalty award.Footnote 2 Lex Machina’s Patent Litigation Year in Review 2016 reports median reasonable royalty damages in 2016 of $3,552,600, based on thirty-six cases; median lost profits damages of $1,631,231, based on eight cases; and median “Other/Mixed Damages” of $67,785, based on eighteen cases.Footnote 3

PricewaterhouseCoopers (PwC) also publishes annual patent litigation reports. However, PwC reports median patent damages awards in the United States (excluding summary and default judgments) without separately accounting for lost profits and reasonable royalties. Interestingly, PwC’s reported median award for 1997–2016 ($5.8 million in 2016 dollars) is considerably higher than the medians reported by Lex Machina for 2000–2015, most likely due to methodological differences between the two studies.Footnote 4 PwC also reports that in 80 percent of the cases in which courts awarded damages to practicing entities from 2007 to 2016 they awarded reasonable royalties.Footnote 5 (Courts awarded lost profits in 40 percent of these cases; the percentages exceed 100 percent because courts sometimes award lost profits on a portion of infringing sales and reasonable royalties on the remainder.) Further, although nonpracticing entities (NPEs) had a lower win rate than practicing entities during the time period studied, the median award to NPEs that prevailed at trial from 2012 to 2016 was almost four times the median award to practicing entities ($15.7 million versus $4.1 million).Footnote 6 Awards to NPEs almost always consist of reasonable royalties, rather than lost profits.

For other countries, less data is available, and the data that is available is generally less precise. Studies of Japanese damages awards indicate that reasonable royalty awards make up a plurality of all such awardsFootnote 7 but that the amounts awarded tend to be low by U.S. standards. For example, according to a 2014 study of all sixty-eight cases from January 1, 1999, to March 5, 2013, in which Japanese courts awarded reasonable royalties, in only five cases did the award exceed ¥200,000,000 (equal to about U.S. $1.7 million).Footnote 8 The royalty rate was 5 percent in 28 percent of cases, 3 percent in 22 percent, and 10 percent in 16 percent (based on the value of the infringer’s sales revenue from the infringing product). Like the PwC studies of U.S. damages, the reports of which we are aware on average or median damages awards in France do not distinguish between royalty and lost profits awards.Footnote 9 In China, statutory damages predominate and awards of reasonable royalties are comparatively rare.Footnote 10

1.1.2 Theoretical Justifications

As noted in the Introduction, for purposes of this project we take the substantive law of patents as a given, and do not advise courts to use the law of remedies to correct for perceived flaws in the substantive law. It follows from this premise that, in general, the law of patent damages should work to preserve the patent incentive, such as it is, by restoring the patent owner to the position it would have occupied, but for the infringement. Consistent with this rationale, courts and other observers often view reasonable royalty awards as a substitute for the royalty the patent owner would have earned, and that the infringer would have paid, absent the infringement. Commentators nevertheless sometimes express concern that such a standard threatens to encourage infringement (and to discourage ex ante negotiation), since it leaves the infringer no worse off for having infringed. This concern is particularly applicable if the royalty award is exactly the same as the royalty the patent owner would have negotiated, if the infringement was intentional, and if the infringer rationally could expect to avoid detection some nonzero percent of the time.Footnote 11 In addition, the infringer may avoid some of the risks that a real-world licensee would incurFootnote 12 – though of course, if the infringer is sued, it may wind up incurring substantial attorney fees, which it otherwise could have avoided, to defend itself.Footnote 13 To the extent that restorative damages risk underdeterring infringement, the law in the United States already ensures that royalty awards will not be exactly the same as what would have been negotiated, because the royalty awards must be calculated based on an assumption that the patent in question is valid and infringed, whereas in actual negotiations the parties commonly reduce the royalty based on the possibility of invalidity and noninfringement.Footnote 14 In addition, to address the risk of underdeterrence due to nondetection, policymakers could authorize courts to (1) grant injunctions, (2) award the disgorgement of the infringer’s profits, (3) shift fees to the prevailing party, (4) impose criminal sanctions, or (5) award enhanced damages. Other chapters of this book discuss these alternatives in depth. However, as specifically discussed in Chapter 3, many countries decline to award enhanced or punitive damages on public policy grounds – though in some of these countries, courts occasionally award reasonable royalties above the “normal” rate to reflect the infringer’s avoidance of risks that a good-faith licensee would have incurred.Footnote 15

Alternatively, one could view reasonable royalties as a form of restitution, in the sense that the award forces the infringer to pay back the royalty it wrongfully withheld from the patentee.Footnote 16 Whether the characterization of royalties as restorative or restitutionary makes any practical difference may depend on whether the focus is on awarding the royalty the parties would have negotiated absent the infringement, or the royalty the infringer should be required to pay in light of some normative criterion. The “hypothetical bargain” or “willing licensor-willing licensee” approach, as it is often applied in the United States, might seem to be an example of the former approach, insofar as it attempts to construct the terms of the bargain the parties themselves would have negotiated prior to the date of infringement. But even that approach does not construct the exact bargain the parties would have made, because the hypothetical negotiation assumes the patent in question was valid and infringed, as discussed above. Without these assumptions, there would appear to be little difference between characterizing reasonable royalties as restorative or restitutionary. The royalty the court believes the patent owner would have earned absent the infringement is identical to the infringer’s gain (i.e., the royalty it withheld, if not adjusted upward to reflect certainty as to validity and infringement).Footnote 17 On the other hand, an approach that attempts to determine the royalty the infringer should be required to pay does not necessarily entail restoring the parties to the positions they actually would have occupied but for the infringement – though any such approach needs to specify just what the appropriate normative criterion is. Some recent scholarship recommends focusing more on the benefit the infringer actually derived from the use of the invention (as opposed to its expected benefits ex ante), so that the resulting award will more closely correlate with the invention’s contribution to the art. As discussed in Sections 1.2 and 1.3, one would then have to determine how to divide that benefit between the parties. In theory, the division could be based on what the parties likely would have negotiated ex ante, or on industry custom or other criteria.Footnote 18 Other recent scholarship also suggests that a restitutionary approach to patent damages would provide courts with more flexibility to adjust the requisite level of proof based on factors such as the stakes involved and the extent to which the infringer was at fault.Footnote 19

1.1.3 Principal Approaches

Courts throughout the world often consider a range of factors in calculating reasonable royalties. One approach often used in the United States, the United Kingdom, and some other countries is to construct the hypothetical bargain to which the court believes the parties would have agreed to avoid infringement.Footnote 20 As discussed above, the hypothetical bargain approach may be viewed as either restorative or restitutionary. If the resulting royalty reflects what the parties actually would have negotiated, the patentee is rendered no worse off, and the infringer no better off, compared to the positions they would have occupied had they actually negotiated a license. As discussed in the following Sections, however, among the issues courts may need to address in constructing such a hypothetical bargain are (1) the timing of the bargain, (2) the knowledge the court should impute to the parties (including knowledge of validity and infringement of the relevant patent, as discussed above), and (3) the relevant factors that are probative of the terms of the bargain. Alternatively, as suggested above, an approach that focuses on dividing the actual gain to the infringer could still be cast as a hypothetical bargain, albeit one in which the parties agree ex ante on how to divide the benefit the infringer actually derives ex post.Footnote 21 This approach would be less concerned than the more common Georgia-Pacific approach with trying to accurately construct the terms the parties themselves actually would have negotiated ex ante.

Another option under U.S. law is the so-called analytical approach, which “focuses on the infringer’s projections of profit for the infringing product.”Footnote 22 The leading case is TWM Mfg. Co. v. Dura Corp.,Footnote 23 in which the Federal Circuit approved a damages award that involved subtracting “the infringer’s usual or acceptable net profit from its anticipated net profit realized from sales of infringing devices.” Although courts sometimes permit the patentee who employs the analytical approach to use the infringer’s actual profits as a proxy for expected profits,Footnote 24 the approach does not appear to be used very frequently. Critiques of the analytical approach argue, among other things, that the method is indistinguishable from disgorgement; that the concept of a “usual or acceptable net profit” is not very precise; that the approach does not account for various other factors that can explain a divergence from the normal rate of return, including the presence of other product features, or for the fact that different products can have different profit margins; and that the approach can unfairly penalize an infringer who has a higher profit rate due to efficiencies in production.Footnote 25

Where an established royalty rate exists, courts sometimes have used that rate rather than endeavoring to construct a hypothetical bargain or an appropriate division of the profits projected or earned from the use of the invention.Footnote 26 Where no such established rate exists, courts nevertheless frequently turn to comparable license rates as an aid in constructing the hypothetical bargain. In some countries, courts also make extensive use of what are believed to be industry standard rates for various technologies. For example, in Japan courts often start with the standard royalty rate for a given technological field, as reported in publications of the Japanese Institute of Inventors and Innovation (Hatsumei Kyokai), and then adjust the rate up or down based on factors such as “the technical or economical value and importance of the invention,” the plaintiff’s own high profit margin, the contribution of the invention to the infringer’s profitability or to the value of the end product, the existence of alternatives, and the infringer’s sales volume.Footnote 27

A fourth possibility would be to employ some sort of “top-down” approach as in In re Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litigation,Footnote 28 whereby the court identifies an appropriate royalty base, decides how much of the revenue attributable to the base should be payable as aggregate royalties, and then determines what portion of those aggregate royalties should accrue to the patents in suit, based on their relative importance. Some form of “top-down” approach may be used in cases involving complex products, but the accuracy of the approach in estimating the value of the patents in suit depends upon obtaining a considerable amount of arguably difficult-to-obtain information.Footnote 29 This approach is discussed further in Chapter 5 on the effect of FRAND commitments on patent remedies.

1.2 Reformulating Georgia-Pacific

Judicial systems throughout the world often permit the finder of fact to consider a range of factors of arguable relevance to the calculation of reasonable royalties. In the United States, for example, damages expert witnesses frequently base their opinions on the fifteen factors first compiled in Georgia-Pacific Co. v. U.S. Plywood Co. (set forth below).Footnote 30 Courts in other countries, including Canada,Footnote 31 Germany,Footnote 32 and Japan,Footnote 33 sometimes look to a similar range of factors.

Critics nevertheless have noted several potential problems with the Georgia-Pacific framework. First, depending on the facts of the case, some of the Georgia-Pacific factors may simply be irrelevant,Footnote 34 thus potentially distracting the trier of fact from focusing on the economically relevant considerations.Footnote 35 Second, the framework offers little or no guidance to either the trier of fact or the judge on how to weigh or prioritize the factors.Footnote 36 Third, and following from the first two points, it is sometimes said that a clever expert can manipulate the factors in support of virtually any award.Footnote 37 As a consequence, it can be very difficult for the parties to predict how the trier of fact will apply the factors, and for a reviewing court to detect errors in their application.Footnote 38 In combination, these problems threaten not only to reduce accuracy and increase costs, but also to make settlement more difficult and to place the more risk-averse party at a disadvantage.Footnote 39

In response to these problems, some recent scholarship and other initiatives advocate restructuring the analysis to focus on a smaller number of economically relevant factors. Most prominent, perhaps, are the Federal Circuit Bar Association’s Model Patent Jury Instructions, which propose that U.S. courts instruct juries to “consider all the facts known and available to the parties at the time the infringement began,” but that “[s]ome of the kinds of factors that you may consider in making your determination are: (1) The value that the claimed invention contributes to the accused product. (2) The value that factors other than the claimed invention contribute to [the accused product]. (3) Comparable license agreements, such as those covering the use of the claimed invention or similar technology.”Footnote 40 In a similar vein, Durie and Lemley argue that the Georgia-Pacific factors largely “boil down to three fundamental questions: (1) what is the marginal contribution of the patented invention over the prior art?; (2) how many other inputs were necessary to achieve that contribution, and what is their relative value?; and (3) is there some concrete evidence suggesting that the market has chosen a number different than the calculus that results from (1) and (2)?”Footnote 41 Jarosz and Chapman also have advocated a three-step framework, focusing on the incremental value of the invention over alternatives, comparable licenses, and design-around costs.Footnote 42

Following from the above, our principal recommendation is that, when applying a “bottom-up”Footnote 43 approach to estimating reasonable royalties, courts should replace the Georgia-Pacific factors (and analogous factors used outside the United States for calculating reasonable royalties) with a smaller list of considerations. More specifically, courts should collapse the Georgia-Pacific factors into the following three steps. (We defend each of the individual parts of this recommendation in detail in Section 3.1 below.)

  1. 1. Calculate the incremental value of the invention and divide it appropriately between the parties. A license for the useFootnote 44 of a patented technology typically requires the licensee to share with the licensor some portion of the incremental value the licensee derives or expects to derive from the use of that technology. To ensure that a reasonable royalty for the unauthorized use of a patented technology accurately reflects this incremental value, ideally a court would (1) estimate the difference between the value the infringer derived from the use of the patented invention (as distinct from the value contributed by other features of the infringing end product), and the value the infringer would have derived by using the next best available noninfringing alternative instead; (2) divide that differential value between the patent owner and the infringer; and (3) as an aid in carrying out this division, consider any relevant evidence, including possibly the use of a rebuttable presumption that the parties would have agreed, ex ante, to an even (50/50) split.

  2. 2. Assess market evidence. In negotiating licenses for the use of patented technologies, parties often consider the rates and other terms disclosed in relevant comparable licenses (or, where applicable, the rates charged by relevant patent pools or disclosed in publications of industry standard rates). Courts also should consider such evidence for purposes of calculating reasonable royalties for the unauthorized use of patented technologies, albeit subject to appropriate adjustments and with due appreciation for the potential limitations of such evidence as discussed in Section 1.3.6.

  3. 3. Comparison. When it is feasible and cost justified, courts should carry out both steps described above – each one acting as a “check” on the accuracy of the other – and then attempt to reconcile or adjust the results, as the evidence warrants. That said, one can expect only that courts do the best they can with the evidence available to them. Thus, when the evidence necessary to carry out Step 2 is available but the evidence necessary to carry out Step 1 is notFootnote 45 – as will likely often be the case in litigation involving complex products – courts may need to rely exclusively on market evidence. (The converse will be true when the available evidence relates only to Step 1, not 2.) Furthermore, as discussed in greater detail in Chapter 5 on the effect of FRAND commitments on patent royalties, in appropriate cases courts also may consider applying a “top-down” approach either as direct evidence or as a check on the value derived from the use of comparables and other market evidence.

Explanation. As discussed in Section 1.3.1 below, economists generally accept “incremental value” – that is, the difference between the value derived from the patented invention over the next best available noninfringing alternative – as an accurate measure of the value of patented technology.Footnote 46 By necessity, such an inquiry also requires the trier of fact to apportion the value attributable to the patented invention as opposed to other features of the infringer’s product, assuming that the noninfringing alternative end product sold by the infringer would have retained those other features.Footnote 47 The first part of Step 1 above therefore combines Georgia-Pacific factors 8, 9, 10, and 13 into one overarching concept.Footnote 48 Step 1 presumably will be easier to accomplish, however, when the infringing product embodies relatively few patented features. We defend our recommendation regarding the division of incremental value in Section 1.3.3 below.

Step 2 recommends that courts also make appropriate use of comparables and other market evidence of how actors in the real world value the technology in suit. To be sure, courts and commentators have identified numerous potential pitfalls in the use of comparables, which we discuss in greater detail in Section 1.3.6 below. These theoretical problems notwithstanding, however, we do not advocate forgoing the use of comparables (nor do we see that as a likely development, in any event), but rather emphasize the need for careful judgment in applying them. Moreover, at least in some cases a patent pool rate or other comparable may have a very high probative value, though that rate may need to be adjusted (for example, to account for the reasons why the patentee did not join the pool).Footnote 49

Step 3 recommends that, where feasible, courts apply both Step 1 and Step 2, and then compare the results. To the extent the numbers generated by each step diverge, the court will then have to decide how best to reconcile them based on all of the relevant facts and circumstances. For example, a court may be more confident in the result generated by Step 1 when the end product embodies only a small number of patents or when there are few if any licenses that are closely comparable. By contrast, Step 2 may seem more probative when the product’s complexity makes it difficult to distinguish the value contributed by a single patent over the next best alternative. (On the other hand, even in complex products cases it sometimes may be possible to estimate the value of a specific patented feature relative to other features, through the use of conjoint or discrete choice analysis, testimony from technical experts, or application of some form of “top-down” approach as discussed in the FRAND chapter.)Footnote 50 Further, in cases (1) involving relatively small stakes, or (2) arising in countries that impose substantial limits on pretrial discovery or the use of expert witnesses, or (3) in which the parties’ evidence on damages is inadmissible or incompetent, the best practice may be to consider comparables, industry standard rates, or other such market evidence, despite its potential drawbacks, rather than to award zero damages or rely on other, even more speculative, evidence of the value of the technology over alternatives.

1.3 Incremental Value and Other Issues

In this Section, we present the analysis underlying our principal recommendation as described in Section 1.2. We also present our recommendations relating to various issues that may arise either in the application of our principal recommendation or in the event courts continue to employ a multifactor, Georgia-Pacific-like approach to reasonable royalties.

1.3.1 Incremental Value

1 Overview

We perceive a widespread consensus among innovation economists and lawyers that the social value of a technology is its incremental value over the next best alternative, and that the economic value of a patented technology to an implementer is the (actual or expected) profit or cost saving the implementer derives from the use of the patented technology over the next best available noninfringing alternative.Footnote 51 We therefore recommend that policymakers adopt, subject to the systemic considerations noted in the Introduction, the guiding principle that the royalties awarded in litigation should be commensurate with the value of the patented technology as so defined.Footnote 52 We also recognize, however, that there are substantial difficulties, both practical and conceptual, in assessing that value – particularly in the case of complex products, where the patented technology contributes only a small part to the overall value of the product. In those contexts, a patented feature might be the deciding factor for a few purchasers, and it might increase the value to others, but for most purchasers it is likely to be one of a host of factors that shift buying preferences as a whole. We discuss the conceptual difficulties below.

2 Complements

The first conceptual difficulty involves complementarity between the infringing technology and other patented technologies that are also implemented in the same product. The problem is illustrated most clearly in a case in which two versions of a complex product are sold, with no difference between the two except that one version embodies the patented technology while the other does not.Footnote 53 It may seem that this is a case in which it is easy to determine the incremental value of the patented technology; it would seem to be simply the difference between the two prices. However, this is not correct if, as is commonly the case, the patented technology depends on other patented technology. For example, suppose the patented invention provides for 20 percent longer battery life in a smartphone, and a smartphone with the longer battery life sells for $50 more than the phone would with the shorter battery life it would otherwise have. The incremental value of the patented invention would appear to be $50. But the price consumers are willing to pay for the phone depends on its patented wireless technology, and without that wireless technology the phone would be worthless, no matter how long the battery life. In that case, the $50 price difference is only partially attributable to battery technology, because it is also partially attributable to the wireless technology.Footnote 54 Put another way, the patentee holding the wireless technology might reasonably demand a higher royalty for the phone with the battery-extending technology than for the base phone, leaving only some part of the $50 to be split between the battery patentee and the phone vendor. Whether the wireless patentee actually demands a higher royalty in such a case is a different question – though it is not unlikely that it would do so. It is common for patentees, particularly those with basic technology patents, to charge an ad valorem royalty on the product price, with the result that the wireless royalty would be higher for the more expensive phone.

3 Patented Alternatives

A second conceptual difficulty arises from the proposition that the value of the invention is its value over the best noninfringing alternative. This proposition is uncontroversial so long as the alternative is unpatented, but its application is not so clear if the alternative is patented. It is not at all uncommon that the best substitutes for a patented technology are also patented, as several inventors devise different solutions to the same problem.Footnote 55 The problem is illustrated most clearly when the inventions are near perfect substitutes,Footnote 56 and it is particularly salient in the context of standard-essential patents (SEPs), where it is often the case that multiple alternative patented technologies competed for inclusion in the standard.

One possibility is that in such a case the value of the patented invention is zero, on the view that the infringing user in the hypothetical negotiation should be imagined to play one patentee off against another until the patentee is haggled down to its minimum willingness to accept.Footnote 57 More generally, on this view the value of the invention is its incremental value over the patented alternative, ignoring the royalties that would have to be paid to use that alternative, on the rationale that those royalties do not reflect the value of the alternative technology but merely the value of the patent right.Footnote 58 By the same token, if the infringed technology were not quite as good as the patented alternative, the value of the infringed technology would be zero. We recommend rejecting this approach, on the ground that although it makes sense from a static welfare perspective, it provides a facially inadequate incentive to invent (zero compensation) and therefore appears inconsistent with the conventionally understood purpose of the patent system.

Another possibility would be to assume that a patented alternative that is on the market is available for its established market price, which is normally above marginal cost. Put another way, “[t]he proper comparison is between the cost and value of the patentee’s component and the cost and value of the alternative, including patent royalties that would have to be paid on the alternative where appropriate.”Footnote 59 This approach has some support in the case law, though it cannot be considered established law.Footnote 60 Nevertheless, although this approach might seem appealing when both technologies are mature and both have an established price, it might be difficult to apply if both technologies are new to the market and neither has an established price. This suggestion is therefore likely to be unhelpful in the SEP context, where alternative technologies competed for inclusion in the standard ex ante, and the alternative that was not selected may not have a market presence at all ex post, or will have a value that is much lower than if it had been selected for inclusion in the standard. Another problem arises when the alternative technology is mature and has an established price, and the infringed technology is new. If the technologies are close substitutes, we would expect the new technology to drive down the price of the established technology, even in the absence of infringement. Thus, if the established price of the alternative is used for comparison purposes, the patentee will be overcompensated in comparison with the royalties it would have received but for the infringement. Perhaps, then, the proper approach in principle would be to assess how the price of the patented alternative would have evolved in response to the introduction of the infringed technology, in the absence of infringement. On the other hand, simply using the established price has clear advantages in terms of ease of proof.

We are not aware of any literature providing a thorough theoretical analysis of this problem.Footnote 61 We therefore propose further research on this issue.

1.3.2 Hypothetical Bargain

In the United States, the most common approach to assessing a reasonable royalty is usually referred to as the “hypothetical negotiation” approach:Footnote 62

The hypothetical negotiation tries, as best as possible, to recreate the ex ante licensing negotiation scenario and to describe the resulting agreement. In other words, if infringement had not occurred, willing parties would have executed a license agreement specifying a certain royalty payment scheme.Footnote 63

While this approach is now deeply entrenched, the leading cases emphasize that the goal of the hypothetical negotiation framework is not to replicate the bargain that actual willing parties would have arrived at; that would be “inaccurate, and even absurd,”Footnote 64 given that “[t]here is, of course, no actual willingness on either side, and no license to do anything, the infringer being normally enjoined … from further manufacture, use, or sale of the patented product.”Footnote 65 The hypothetical negotiation is a “legal fiction,”Footnote 66 “employed by the court as a means of arriving at reasonable compensation,”Footnote 67 and it is to be “flexibly applied as a ‘device in the aid of justice.’”Footnote 68

We recommend that courts embrace this view of the hypothetical bargain framework as a tool – a proxy for the issues of how to split the surplus from the invention – rather than as a goal in and of itself.Footnote 69 For example, it is well established in U.S. law that the parties to the hypothetical negotiation are assumed to have known that the patent was valid and infringed, even though actual parties would not. This rule is required to achieve just compensation, because the opposite view – that the parties should be assumed to discount the royalty to allow for the probabilistic nature of the patent (as would presumably be done by parties to an actual negotiation) – would result in so-called double discounting;Footnote 70 not only would the court-approved royalty derived from the hypothetical negotiation include a discount for the risk of non-liability, but then pre-litigation negotiations in which royalties were based on the expectation of such a court award occurring with a less than 100 percent probability would include a further discount for risk of non-liability. For that reason, we agree that this well-established principle of U.S. law is sound. Moreover, based on similar reasoning, the hypothetical negotiation should include an assumption of liability, not just validity and infringement, as well as entitlement to relief and enforceability.Footnote 71 And more generally, departures from a strict attempt to reconstruct what real parties would have done had they actually bargained are justified whenever such a departure would be a better means of arriving at reasonable compensation – in particular, compensation that reflects the value of the patented technology over its best noninfringing alternative. Indeed, if sound principles of reasonable compensation require an unwieldy number of departures from a hypothetical negotiation framework, the proper course would be to abandon the framework rather than the sound principles.Footnote 72

1.3.3 Dividing Incremental Value

The second and third parts of Step 1 involve identifying the appropriate division of the incremental value. Both sides often can make a substantial claim to at least a portion of the incremental value – the patentee because this value results from use of the claimed invention, and the adjudged infringer because it made complementary or supplementary investments that resulted in a commercial embodiment of that invention. How then should the value be divided?

In theory, an invention can give rise to pure economic rents, reflecting the value of the invention over the best noninfringing alternative. If two parties, such as a patent owner and a licensee, must cooperate to realize those rents, there is no simple theoretical answer as to how the parties will split the rents between them, since even a very lopsided split, in either direction, would leave both parties better off as compared with using the noninfringing alternative. The most prominent solution to the problem is the Nash Bargaining Solution (NBS), which implies a 50/50 split. However, the NBS requires unrealistically restrictive assumptions about the parties, such as that they are identical in every way. Economic theory is relatively underdeveloped in terms of fleshing out how pure rents would be split when the parties are modeled more realistically.Footnote 73 The Nash Bargaining Solution is sometimes used, not because it is a particularly accurate model, but for lack of anything better.

Moreover, the division of the incremental profit due to the invention is unlikely to be a split of pure rents. Turning a patented invention into a commercialized innovation that actually commands a premium in the marketplace requires some or all of manufacturing, distribution, marketing, process refinement, technical support to the licensee by the patentee, end-user support, and so on, all of which involve risk and investment by one party or the other. The royalty paid by the licensee to the patentee does not reflect a split of pure rents, but also, or even instead, compensation to the party who made the investments and shouldered the risks relating to these ancillary services.Footnote 74 Georgia-Pacific factor 13 recognizes this possibility,Footnote 75 as have cases such as Tights, Inc. v. Kayser-Roth Corp.:

The Court finds, in the context of this case, that the patentee would have been reasonably entitled to receive from 25% to 50% of the cost saving as reasonable royalties. This Court finds that 25% of the cost saving is a reasonable entitlement where the parties anticipate that the licensee will have to make substantial contributions to practical commercialization. This Court finds that 50% of the cost saving is a reasonable entitlement where the parties anticipate that the licensee will have to make only routine creative contributions toward commercialization.Footnote 76

We therefore recommend that, to the extent possible, the split of the incremental profit should reflect the value of any such ancillary services or risks that either the patent owner or the infringer, in fact, undertook. In our view this is consistent with the hypothetical bargaining construct because it reflects the agreement the parties themselves would have arrived at in similar circumstances. Recall that the principal justification for the hypothetical bargain is that it preserves the patent incentive by restoring the patent owner to the position it would have occupied absent the infringement. That position would depend in part on how the parties would have agreed, ex ante, to divide the value to be derived from the use of the patented invention, in comparison with alternatives. However, we emphasize that we recommend taking such services into account to the extent they are actually incurred. Even if an actual licensee would have provided marketing for the invention, and an actual royalty would have reflected that value, the reasonable royalty award should only reflect that if in fact the infringer undertook the marketing.Footnote 77

More broadly, we propose further research to unpack and refine the nature of “bargaining power” as it relates to the division of the incremental value of the invention.Footnote 78 We suspect that the division in any given case is determined in part by compensation for ancillary services and in part by industry norms (which may themselves reflect reflect standard practices about provision of ancillary services). To some extent this unpacking is a matter of obtaining better evidence as to what factors actually drive the division of the incremental profit in practice. In addition, there are some conceptual or normative issues to be resolved. In particular, one intuitive understanding of “bargaining power” is that a party with deeper pockets has greater bargaining power, and so would be able to extract a greater share of the incremental value in an actual licensing negotiation. For example, if the patent owner was a small cash-strapped start-up, and the potential licensee was a large company, the licensee might in practice be able to extract very favorable terms. It can be argued that it would be appropriate to replicate that unequal division in a reasonable royalty assessment, on the view that the patentee should not be made better off than it would have been had the parties actually licensed. On the other hand, the favorable terms might be considered to be an illegitimate holdout by the licensee, which should not be replicated in a reasonable royalty, on the view that it does not reflect the incremental value of the invention, just as the courts should not give the patentee a higher royalty if it would have been able to engage in holdup in an actual negotiation. These questions deserve further exploration.

Having decided which factors should be relevant to the division of the incremental profit, the second question is what evidence should be used to establish that division. A few possibilities come to mind. First, comparables may shed light, either explicitly or implicitly, on how the parties would have agreed to divide the surplus. As discussed above, evidence also could reflect any ancillary services or risks that either the patent owner or the infringer, in fact, incurred, so as to adjust the royalty derived from the comparable license. Second, there may be evidence of what the parties would have agreed to based on their own prior negotiations, the patentee’s course of dealing with other parties, or the custom of the industry. To illustrate, in United States Frumentum Co. v. Lauhoff, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit held that evidence was admissible as to what share of the profits or of the selling price “it may be customary in that or similar business to allow for the use of such an invention.”Footnote 79 (Of course, questions may arise as to just how similar a “similar business” must be.) When there is no such evidence of how the parties would have agreed to split the incremental value, however, what then? On the one hand, it would seem wrong to award the patent owner nothing – and in any event U.S. law normally would preclude such a result because section 284 of the U.S. Patent Act requires courts to award “damages adequate to compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use made of the invention by the infringer.”Footnote 80 Indeed, one of the reasons for the gradual adoption of the reasonable royalty remedy in the United States in the early to mid-twentieth century was precisely to avoid situations in which courts could award only nominal damages, due to difficulties in quantifying the owner’s loss or the infringer’s gain with sufficient certainty.Footnote 81 Rather, as Judge Learned Hand expressed it back in 1933, “[t]he whole notion of a reasonable royalty is a device in aid of justice, by which that which is really incalculable shall be approximated, rather than that the patentee, who has suffered an indubitable wrong, shall be dismissed with empty hands.”Footnote 82 By the same token, it would seem equally wrong to award the patentee 100 percent of the profit the infringer earned from the use of the claimed invention simply because the infringer couldn’t prove the appropriate division (unless the patentee was seeking, and was entitled to under the relevant substantive law, an award of the infringer’s profits).Footnote 83

Arguably then, the best practice would be to permit the parties to introduce whatever competent evidence they have on the division of profits, including comparables, while also permitting the fact finder to take note of, for example, findings from behavioral psychology and economics (e.g., the ultimatum game) suggesting that people in Western societies generally view a 50/50 split of benefits as fair. (Similarly, the Nash Bargaining Solution, application of which often may result in a 50/50 split, is a widely used construct in game theory – albeit with economists often employing the 50/50 split as a plausible assumption, rather than substantiating it as an empirical fact of how two actual parties would have bargained.)Footnote 84 For example, in Summit 6, LLC v. Samsung Electronics Co., the Federal Circuit recently affirmed a damages judgment based on an expert witness’s purported isolation of the incremental profit Samsung had derived from the use of the patented invention, and his subsequent division of that profit between the parties based on analysis of Samsung’s bargaining power and application of the Nash Bargaining Solution.Footnote 85

We therefore recommend that, when faced with the question of how to divide the incremental value derived from the use of the invention over the next best alternative, courts permit the parties to introduce any competent evidence on this issue – including, where necessary to estimate a royalty “in aid of justice,” empirical findings that people in Western societies generally view a 50/50 split of benefits as fair, and that economists often use the Nash Bargaining Solution in modeling bargaining behavior. Further to this point, policymakers may wish to consider adopting a rebuttable presumption that the parties would have agreed to a 50/50 split – which presumption, however, should come into play only after there has been an initial determination of the incremental profit derived from the use of the invention, and should not be difficult for the parties to rebut by means of more specific evidence (comparables, industry practice, risk allocation, etc.).Footnote 86

By contrast, we would not recommend use of a stronger presumption (e.g., one that can be rebutted only by clear and convincing evidence) out of concern that, inter alia, the trier of fact (particularly a lay jury) might accord such a presumption too much weight. Further, a weak presumption of this sort should be sharply distinguished from the 25 percent rule of thumb previously used by U.S. courts and rejected by the Federal Circuit in Uniloc USA, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp.Footnote 87 Unlike that rule of thumb, under which a damages expert was permitted to presume that “the licensee pay a royalty rate equivalent to 25 per cent of its expected profits for the product that incorporates the IP at issue,”Footnote 88 the presumptive value split suggested here would apply only after the incremental profit properly attributable to use of the claimed invention has been isolated from all other portions of overall revenue and profit. In complex product cases, there are likely to be multiple innovations besides the claimed invention that have contributed to overall revenue and profit. Consequently, in such cases, 50 percent of the incremental profit attributable to the claimed invention can be expected to often be only a small percentage or even only a small fraction of a percent of the overall profit from the complex product.

1.3.4 Timing of Hypothetical Negotiation

The standard view in U.S. case law is that the hypothetical bargain occurs just prior to the date on which the infringement began.Footnote 89 This timing has been controversial in two main respects. First, it is the basis for the mainstream view in U.S. law that the hypothetical bargain should be based only on information that is available to the parties ex ante, and that ex post information is relevant only as indirect evidence of what the parties would have expected ex ante (the “book of wisdom” approach).Footnote 90 The standard in Germany, by contrast, states that the court should consider the bargain the parties would have reached ex ante had they foreseen all relevant ex post information;Footnote 91 and a few commentators argue for the expanded use of ex post information in U.S. law as well, on the view that this allows for a more accurate valuation of the patented technology.Footnote 92 Second, there is substantial scholarly commentary, particularly in the SEP context, suggesting that the timing of the hypothetical negotiation should be earlier, just prior to the time when sunk costsFootnote 93 were incurred; this commentary reflects the view that the user would inevitably have incurred sunk costs by the time of the first infringement, so that a license negotiated at that time would allow the patentee to hold up the user for part of those sunk costs, leading to a royalty in excess of the value of the invention.Footnote 94

With these critiques in mind, we recommend that, to the extent courts continue to employ a hypothetical bargaining construct at all, they should apply a flexible approach that takes into account the hypothetical bargain’s status as a legal fiction employed as an aid to arriving at reasonable compensation, rather than as a foundational principle in its own right to be applied strictly and literally. With regard to timing in particular, in many cases the precise date of the hypothetical negotiation does not have any impact on the reasonable royalty, and the early U.S. decisions invoking the hypothetical negotiation approach did not usually specify the time when the negotiation took place. On the other hand, in the cases establishing the time of the first infringement as the appropriate date, courts have chosen the infringement date not because it reflects the time of a negotiation between truly willing parties, but because that timing does justice on the facts of the particular case. As discussed in Sections 1.2 and 1.3.5, our preferred approach is not to employ a hypothetical negotiation as such, but rather to identify the surplus that the parties are negotiating over, and to divide that surplus in an appropriate manner. But whichever construct is used, the ultimate goal is to ensure that the division does not reflect lock-in but that it does reflect any ancillary services or risks that either party has shouldered.

To illustrate our recommendation, consider a case in which the court deems the hypothetical negotiation to have taken place at the time of first infringement, but after the infringer has incurred sunk costs. In such a case, the patentee might be able to extract some of the value associated with those sunk costs even if it has no substantial relation to the value of the patented technology, contrary to the consensus view that the patentee normally should not be able to extract such unrelated value.Footnote 95 Fortunately, we are not aware of any cases in which the courts have approved of allowing the patentee to extract value associated with such sunk costs specifically on the basis that this would have happened had the parties bargained on the infringement date. In our view, the key point is to ensure that the evidence used to establish the reasonable royalty avoids problems associated with sunk costs. If, for example, the bargain is constructed using comparable licenses, a strict adherence to the principle that the bargain takes place prior to infringement would bar the use of any comparable licenses entered into after that date. But if the party to the relevant comparable had negotiated its license prior to incurring any sunk costs, then neither that license nor a royalty based on it would reflect sunk-costs holdup, and there would be no reason to reject the use of that comparable based on its date of execution.

Further, while the view that a reasonable royalty should not reflect the infringer’s sunk costs is generally sound, it doesn’t necessarily require that the royalty be based on evidence that predates those sunk costs. The previous example highlights one such scenario. As another example, often it may be easier to determine the date on which infringement began than the date on which the infringer began incurring sunk costs, in which case – as long as the sunk costs are not too large – the marginal increase in accuracy resulting from moving up the date of the hypothetical negotiation may not be justifiable in view of the additional administrative expense. Alternatively, consider the facts of Tights, Inc. v. Kayser-Roth Corp.,Footnote 96 in which the court noted that a licensee would pay a lower royalty if it would be required to make substantial contributions to practical commercialization, and a higher royalty if it made less contributions toward commercialization. The timing of the hypothetical negotiation was important because the product market was relatively mature by the time of the first infringement, and so the reasonable royalty was higher than it would have been had the infringer entered a nascent market.Footnote 97 If the bargain date were moved back to avoid sunk-costs holdup, this would imply that the reasonable royalty in Tights would have to be reduced correspondingly. In our view, Tights was correctly decided on its facts, and a lower royalty to notionally avoid sunk-costs holdup – which was not in issue – would be inappropriate.

This illustrates the importance of addressing the underlying issue rather than focusing solely on the date of the hypothetical negotiation. A negotiation date that is appropriate for some purposes (avoiding sunk-costs holdup) may be inappropriate for others (ensuring that the royalty reflects the infringer’s contribution to commercialization). Moving the negotiation date back to solve one problem might simply create other problems, when all that is really necessary is to ensure that the specific evidence on which the royalty is based does not inappropriately incorporate sunk-costs holdup.

1.3.5 Information Set

We now turn our attention to the issue of changed information. Suppose that at the time of the first infringement, the parties anticipated that the invention would be a great success, and so they would have contracted for a very high royalty, but in fact the invention was a failure. If the royalty is to be based only on the information that was available to the parties at the time of the first infringement, the damages award would be very high; but if it is based on the knowledge that the invention is in fact worthless, then the royalty would be very low. For example, following a jury trial in 2012, a federal district court entered judgment in the amount of $1 billion in favor of Monsanto in a patent infringement dispute against DuPont. This amount reflected the jury’s best estimate of the lump-sum amount that DuPont would have agreed to pay and that Monsanto would have accepted, just before the infringement began, even though DuPont never sold any of the infringing seed at all.Footnote 98 Notably, the opposite story may also be told. A technology expected to be worthless may prove to be valuable. The mainstream view in U.S. law nevertheless is that ex post information can be used only to establish what the parties believed at the time of first infringement, and if it can be established that their views turned out to be wrong, then the reasonable royalty will be calculated on the basis of those wrong views, and not on the basis of what actually transpired.

We recommend, however, that contrary to the mainstream U.S. approach, courts should adopt what Siebrasse and Cotter refer to as the “contingent ex ante approach” under which the hypothetical negotiation is generally assumed (subject to the caveats noted in the preceding section) to take place before any sunk costs are incurred, but with the benefit of ex post information.Footnote 99 The rationale for this approach is that the bargain must be assumed to take place ex ante, so that the patentee is not entitled to extract any holdup value; but at the same time, using ex post information more accurately reflects the true incremental value of the invention, and so provides a more accurate reward to the patentee. This is not really inconsistent with a hypothetical negotiation framework, because parties often negotiate on a contingent basis. For example, it is routine to negotiate a running royalty, the effect of which is to make the return to the patentee contingent on ex post information. Using ex post information in the hypothetical negotiation posits that the parties would contract on a broadly contingent basis, taking into account all relevant factors, not just the volume sold. This approach would not exclude evidence that the parties actually would have agreed upon a lump sum royalty, but merely presumes that the parties would have preferred a royalty that took into account the risk of lack of success of the patented technology. This approach is also consistent with the established rule that the parties to the hypothetical negotiation are assumed to know that the patent is valid and infringed even though during actual negotiations they would have discounted the royalty for risk of non-liability.

This view also has some support in U.S. case law, most prominently in the statement by Justice Cardozo in Sinclair Refining that:

An imaginary bid by an imaginary buyer, acting upon the information available at the moment of the breach, is not the limit of recovery where the subject of the bargain is an undeveloped patent. Information at such a time might be so scanty and imperfect that the offer would be nominal. The promisee of the patent has less than fair compensation if the criterion of value is the price that he would have received if he had disposed of it at once, irrespective of the value that would have been uncovered if he had kept it as his own.Footnote 100

This is often said to reflect only the principle that ex post information may be used as evidence of what the parties would have believed at the time of the first infringement, but on its face it supports the use of ex post information more generally. Similarly, in Georgia-Pacific, the district court actually did consider post-infringement evidence, and on appeal the Second Circuit held that the district court had not erred in so doing.Footnote 101 More recently, it appears that the courts have begun to be more liberal in the use of ex post evidence.Footnote 102

On the other hand, one objection to the use of ex post information is that courts have tended to invoke the “book of wisdom” asymmetrically to benefit patentees but not infringers.Footnote 103 One obvious response to this objection is that it is wrong to do so. Presumably clarifying that the use of ex post evidence is generally permissible would help avoid an unprincipled asymmetric approach.Footnote 104 Lee and Melamed further argue that using ex post information substantively, rather than merely as evidence of what the parties would have known or believed at the time of the first infringement, leads to two mistakes:

First, the rationale assumes that the actual profits would have been unforeseen entirely at the time of the hypothetical negotiation, when the parties negotiating ex ante would likely have understood that there would be a range of possible outcomes (some leading to higher profit and some leading to little or no profit for the infringer) and would have taken all of them into account in selecting a reasonable royalty ex ante. Second, … a royalty determined on the basis of ex post evidence will generally include a premium based on ex post economic developments that increase the infringer’s reliance on the patent – in particular, lock-in costs – and that are unrelated to the incremental benefit the patent confers.

The first objection, however, misses the point. When the parties’ expectations are accurate ex ante, there is no difference between an approach that uses ex post information and one that does not.Footnote 105 The rationale for the use of ex post information is that it allows more accurate determination of the royalty when the parties are mistaken. The second objection is sound so far as it goes, though it actually applies equally to the standard position that the negotiations are assumed to take place at the time of first infringement, by which time the infringer will normally have already incurred lock-in costs. The response is the same whether or not ex post information is to be taken into account; it is to refuse to award royalties that reflect lock-in costs. Put another way, Lee and Melamed implicitly assume that in order to take into account ex post information, it is necessary to assume that the hypothetical negotiation takes place ex post; but under the Siebrasse and Cotter proposal, the hypothetical negotiation is assumed to take place before sunk costs have been incurred, but in light of all ex post information, not just information regarding validity and infringement.

In short, rather than excluding ex post information entirely, the better response is to clearly articulate the rationale, which is not simply to increase the patentee’s reward, and thereby make it clear that ex post information is admissible no matter what effect it has on the reasonable royalty damages. Consequently, we are of the view that the contingent ex ante approach is sound.

1.3.6 Comparable Licenses

If we imagine a reasonable royalty as the product of a hypothetical negotiation between the parties using certain assumptions, the use of comparable licenses – what similarly situated parties “did in fact agree to”Footnote 106 – as an aid in making this determination seems quite sensible.Footnote 107 Indeed, when a license meets the stringent requirements to qualify as an “established” one, its probative value might seem clear.Footnote 108 There are nonetheless significant practical and conceptual problems involved with using comparable licenses – even “established” onesFootnote 109 – as evidence of a reasonable royalty. Although we do not suggest that courts should forgo the use of comparable licenses, we recommend that courts should be aware of the problems discussed below, and to the best of their ability take these considerations into account when using comparables.

1 Comparability

The most obvious hurdle in using comparable licenses is to ensure comparability. It is rare to find actual licenses entered into in exactly the circumstances of the hypothetical negotiation. In theory, a license may be sufficiently comparable to be considered as evidence of a reasonable royalty even though it was not negotiated in circumstances exactly corresponding to the hypothetical negotiation, though adjustments then may have to be made to allow for the differences. And if the license is too dissimilar, it may be properly excluded – particularly in U.S. practice, in which judges play an important gatekeeper role by excluding evidence from consideration by juries.

While licenses involving different patents for related technologies may in principle be useful comparators, there are evident problems in determining whether a different technology is sufficiently comparable. Consequently, courts prefer to rely on licenses granted by the patent owner for the same patent,Footnote 110 but even then problems arise. Licenses often bundle many patents together, including the patent of interest, which makes it difficult to separate out the value of the technology protected by the patent in suit. Licenses involving technology transfer, as opposed to a mere promise not to sue, routinely include other forms of supporting IP such as trademarks or trade secrets relevant to the patented technology, as well as other obligations on both sides such as grantback clauses or obligations to provide ongoing technical support. In litigation, the hypothetical negotiation concerns a very different transaction, often one involving a bare license to the patent itself. Nevertheless, it may be possible to make adjustments to compensate for the value attributable to other factors.Footnote 111 At least U.S. courts appear generally well attuned to this problem, and commonly exclude licenses including substantial non-patent benefits.Footnote 112

Moreover, even licenses to the same patent with similar ancillary clauses are not necessarily comparable in terms of the royalty, because patentees are likely to price discriminate – that is, to charge different users prices that reflect the variation in value among those users.Footnote 113 A few square centimeters of Gore-Tex may save a life when used in a vascular graft, while a square meter of it may be needed for added comfort in a rain jacket. If the patent owner charged the same amount per unit area to the raincoat manufacturer as to the stent manufacturer, it would either forego substantial profits on the license for the stent, or forgo the raincoat license entirely. Price discrimination is consistent with the principle, enunciated at the outset of this chapter, that the patentee should be entitled to a reward commensurate with the value of its technology over the next best alternative. If that value varies between applications, the patentee is likely to charge a different price for those applications. This means that the royalty in a license for the use of the patented technology in a raincoat is probably not a valid comparable in litigation of the use of the technology in a stent, even if the ancillary clauses (and even the licensee) are exactly the same. (Indeed, even licensees that manufacture both stents and raincoats may well pay a different royalty to the patentee for the different uses.)Footnote 114 Similarly, a patentee may also price discriminate between different users, even for the same application, if for example one of the users has access to complementary technology while the other does not.Footnote 115

2 Circularity

Another possible problem with using comparable licenses is circularity. Because the use of comparables to determine a reasonable royalty is one of the most predictable aspects of a reasonable royalty assessment, one would expect the parties to anticipate the use of comparables if the matter were to proceed to litigation, and to factor this into their bargaining. Thus, if there is any systematic and predictable error in the courts’ assessment of the royalty, this error will then be amplified through the use of comparables. Moreover, circularity can arise even if the parties never litigate, as it depends only on the parties’ expectation of the litigation outcome.Footnote 116

Circularity can come in two distinct forms, which we will refer to as “holdup/holdout circularity” and “probabilistic circularity.” First, if the prior licenses being used as comparables were negotiated in circumstances where the licensee was subject to holdup or the patentee subject to holdout, the comparable will reflect holdup or holdout value, not just the value of the patented technology over the noninfringing alternative.Footnote 117 One cure for holdup circularity would be to eliminate the risk of holdup itself by denying injunctive relief, though the question of whether denying injunctions in a broader class of cases is desirable, is a significant issue in and of itself (and one that probably should not be driven by the problem of holdup circularity). Alternatively, courts can avoid holdup circularity even if they grant injunctions by excluding evidence of licenses that were negotiated in circumstances giving rise to holdup. This implies excluding evidence of licenses that were negotiated after the licensee had incurred sunk costs. But this may not be easy, as it requires knowledge not just of the prior license itself, but the circumstances under which it was negotiated. In addition, Lemley and Shapiro argue that a form of holdup arises when the user would have had to keep its product off the market after litigation to allow for redesign, and this form of holdup also can be magnified by circularity. This “redesign holdup circularity” can be avoided by excluding licenses negotiated in those circumstances, but this rule too would seem difficult to implement, since it would require knowledge of what the licensee would have thought its best option was in the counterfactual world in which its licensing negotiations failed. The problem of redesign holdup circularity nevertheless can be mitigated if stays are normally granted to allow redesign, as discussed in Chapter 4 on injunctions.Footnote 118

A different kind of circularity can arise due to the probabilistic nature of patents. As discussed in Section 7.3.1, parties to an actual negotiation would discount the value of the patented technology by the probability of liability, thus potentially giving rise to the double discounting problem if courts use a negotiated royalty as the basis for a reasonable royalty. (The doubly discounted reasonable royalty awarded by the court then would serve as background to the negotiation of the next license, which would then be trebly discounted and so on.)Footnote 119 In contrast with the problem of holdup circularity, which potentially inflates negotiated royalties as compared with the benchmark value of the patented technology, this problem of “probabilistic circularity” deflates negotiated royalties as compared with the benchmark. (Note too that it is likely to infect even established royalties, notwithstanding their more elevated status in the hierarchy of comparables as noted above.) Furthermore, unlike holdup circularity, which does not arise if the parties do not anticipate that a permanent injunction will be granted, probabilistic circularity arises whether or not the parties expect a permanent injunction to be granted.

Conceivably, holdup circularity and probabilistic circularity may offset one another in some cases, but given the difficulty in assessing the magnitude of both types of circularity, it will be impossible to determine the degree to which this is so. The most that might be said is that when the prior license involved a license to a patent that was not already known to be valid and infringed, and it was negotiated after the licensee had incurred sunk costs, the negotiated royalty might be too high or too low, depending on which effect dominates.

In principle, the problem of probabilistic circularity can be avoided by suitably enhancing the actual royalties to compensate for discounting.Footnote 120 There are two problems with this response, however. The first is that, in practice, it seems that such an enhancement is rarely made.Footnote 121 The second, and more fundamental, problem is the difficulty of making an appropriate adjustment. The ideal multiplier would turn on the belief of the parties to the comparable license as to the probability of liability at the time they negotiated the license. But this will be very hard to prove, as it turns “upon private information, available only to the parties to the first licensing agreement, about the plaintiff’s probability of success in litigation.”Footnote 122 The information may not exist at all outside the minds of the negotiators, and because the prior licensee is not a party to the current litigation, any internal memoranda shedding light on the licensee’s view of the probability of liability probably would not be discoverable. (In some cases, the patentee’s internal memoranda might shed light on the issue, but even using this information would be problematic, as it would normally represent only the patentee’s view.)Footnote 123 And in any event, this inquiry would require time-consuming and expensive satellite litigation. An alternative would be for the court to try to estimate the discount based on objective factors relative to the particular prior license, such as the testimony of experts as to the probability of liability. But this would be a difficult inquiry on a new issue that would not otherwise have to be litigated, and that does not seem especially susceptible to the production of reliable results.Footnote 124 Thus, in many situations, courts might be better off without adjusting for the implicit discount, and instead simply being mindful that the comparable license provides “a floor for valuing the patent, not [necessarily] a reasonable estimate.”Footnote 125

Finally, one could imagine using a standard multiplier. For example, if “any given patent owner has a 25% chance ex ante of prevailing against any given alleged infringer, then the appropriate multiplier is four.”Footnote 126 But a standard multiplier not calibrated to evidence of discounting in a particular case merely recasts the circularity problem.Footnote 127 This is because a standard multiplier will overcompensate patentees with strong patents. Anticipating this, parties bargaining in the shadow of the expected trial outcome will negotiate a royalty based on the inflated damages value, and that inflated royalty will feed back into future awards, and so on.Footnote 128 This would result, in effect, in a new source of holdup that would allow a patentee with a strong patent to extract more than the value of its invention. The same spiral would happen in the other direction with patents that are weaker than average.Footnote 129

It therefore would appear very difficult in most cases to reliably enhance the actual royalty arrived at in prior comparable licenses, even though the licenses are themselves otherwise very similar to that at issue in litigation. An alternative approach would be to try to select licenses in which the royalty was not discounted, because they were negotiated in circumstances in which the probability of liability is high. One example would be licenses negotiated after a patent had been held to be valid in other litigation. But even then, the previous judgment of validity would not be binding in litigation involving a different infringer, so it is likely there would still be some discount for the probability of invalidity. And unless the implementation was exactly the same (as might be the case in the SEP context), there might be substantial discounting as to infringement as well, let alone discounting due to risks of invalidity or unenforceability. Further, this approach would severely restrict the cases in which comparables could be used.

In the same vein, some authors have suggested that prior settlements, which courts in the United States normally (though not always) exclude from evidence,Footnote 130 actually should be preferred, particularly if the settlement was entered into when the patent owner appeared to be winning the underlying litigation.Footnote 131 This proposal is again only helpful in a relatively narrow range of cases, as prior settlements are not always available. Moreover, it must be clear that the patentee was winning on the basis of objective factors, such as preliminary motions favoring the patentee, or the discounting problem will not be addressed.Footnote 132 Further, if the patentee in the prior litigation would have expected to obtain an injunction if successful, the settlement may reflect holdup value – thus solving the problem of probabilistic circularity at the expense of inviting the problem of holdup circularity. Another concern with settlements is that they may reflect the value of avoiding litigation costs rather than the value of the patented technology, though this would be a significant problem only when litigation costs are at least comparable to the value of the patented technology.Footnote 133

3 Dynamic Considerations

Some of these problems are likely to get worse in contexts where patentees can predict that a reasonable royalty will be the primary remedy, because we would expect them to adjust their licensing practices to reflect this expectation.Footnote 134 These adjustments might have two kinds of unwanted effects. First, they may make determining accurate damages in the particular case even more difficult. A patentee worried about probabilistic discounting depressing its recovery in future litigation may insist on artificially bundling unnecessary trade secrets or other sham terms into a license solely to ensure that it cannot subsequently be used as a comparable. This is wasteful in itself, though if the parties are careful to include terms that they know are in fact of no value, it will not otherwise distort the transaction.Footnote 135 Another possibility is that a patentee would include self-indulging statements in license agreements about large discounts in light of significant risks of non-recovery.Footnote 136 Conversely, the patentee may try to game the system by negotiating licenses with artificially high rates, in hopes that these will be used as comparables.Footnote 137 This tactic is also wasteful in terms of increased transaction costs, but again it will not affect the licensing terms more generally if courts can detect and exclude such licenses from being used as comparables (which, however, is debatable).

Second, such adjustments may distort the general licensing behavior of the patentee in ways that will have more general effects. As discussed above, price discrimination means that a patentee will rationally charge a high royalty to a high-value user and a low royalty to a low-value user. But if the patentee anticipates that its license to a low-value user will be used as a comparable in subsequent litigation against a high-value user, it may prefer not to license the low-value user at all. This hurts both parties, and society as a whole.Footnote 138 The cure for this, in principle, would be for courts to exclude licenses negotiated with a low-value user as comparables in subsequent litigation with the high-value user, but it is far from clear that courts could reliably and predictably differentiate the two cases.Footnote 139 And of course, the first step would be for courts to acknowledge the need to do so. Otherwise, the use of comparable licenses to assess reasonable royalties may actually result in restricted licensing of the technology. This would be highly undesirable if it is now, or is likely to become, a problem in practice.

All of this is not to say that comparables are not probative at all, or that the above problems can never be mitigated or avoided. For example, Judge Robart’s use of the MPEG LA H.264 patent pool rate in Microsoft v. Motorola probably did not trigger a serious probabilistic discounting problem, because even if some individual patents in the pool might have been invalid or not infringed, parties to the pool could be highly confident that it was necessary to take a pool license to practice the technology in question. The price discrimination problem also did not appear to arise in that case, because the pool did not price discriminate other than on the basis of volume,Footnote 140 and a pool license would have been available to the infringer. Sunk-costs circularity also probably did not arise because, at least as it appears, the pool rates were set to attract licensees who had not yet incurred sunk costs. Moreover, it may be the case that the circularity problems noted above are more theoretical than practical. Although the annual patent litigation studies produced by PwC and Lex Machina, discussed above in Section 1.1.1, reveal some variations from year to year, there does not appear to be any trend toward consistently higher (or lower) median damages awards in the United States over the past decade. Theoretical difficulties aside, therefore, it may be that courts already are adequately counteracting the potential spiraling effects of circularity.

Overall, then, we recommend that courts should apply comparables and other market evidence with caution. Such evidence often may be the best that is available, and even when there is other evidence of the value of the technology over alternatives, it may still be useful to consider market evidence by way of comparison. Nonetheless, courts probably could make more accurate determinations if more license terms were publicly accessible. We therefore recommend (and propose further research devoted to) ongoing efforts to encourage such disclosure.Footnote 141

1.3.7 Entire Market Value Rule and Smallest Saleable Unit

Another practical concern that often arises when applying a multifactor approach to reasonable royalties is that the parties may make strategic choices with respect to the royalty base and royalty rate that they present to fact finders. To reach a specific reasonable royalty award, a patentee could argue (or a fact finder could determine) that a relatively small rate should be applied to a relatively large base, or conversely that a relatively large rate should apply to a relatively small base. For example, a 1 percent royalty rate applied to a $10,000 base and a 25 percent rate applied to a $400 base both lead to a $100 reasonable royalty award.

In theory, it should be irrelevant which method a litigant elects when presenting a damages case in court, and a fact finder should be able to determine an appropriate royalty employing either method. In line with this observation, in many jurisdictions courts routinely use the value of the end product as the royalty base.Footnote 142

In recent years, however, U.S. law has placed limits on patentees’ ability to introduce evidence of the profit or revenue derived from sales of the entire accused product. These restrictions have been motivated at least in part by the long-recognized need to ensure that damages are properly apportioned to the patented features of the accused device, and not to other elements.Footnote 143 Concerns over large bases resulting in overcompensation thus have led the Federal Circuit to articulate a general rule that the royalty base should be the “smallest saleable patent-practicing unit” (SSPPU) in the accused product, and that use of the “entire market value” of the end product as the base is permissible only when the patent drives the demand for the end product.Footnote 144 In yet more recent cases, however, the Federal Circuit has permitted use of the entire market value when the parties themselves negotiated ex ante on the basis of the entire accused product,Footnote 145 or comparable licenses were negotiated on the basis of entire products.Footnote 146

In addition to concerns over apportionment, the Federal Circuit justifies its preference that the royalty base be the smallest saleable unit on the grounds that the value of the entire accused product will tend to have an undue influence on jurors in cases where the asserted patent covers just one of many components or features that comprise the entire product, and in such cases may lead to damages awards that are overcompensatory.Footnote 147 The concern may stem from a cognitive bias known as “anchoring,” i.e., the human tendency to give undue weight to the first data point one encounters, even if that data point is arbitrary or irrelevant.Footnote 148 In the context of U.S. litigation, anchoring tends to reinforce the importance of the plaintiff’s damages case,Footnote 149 which is virtually always presented first and in some cases is not countered at all by the infringer.Footnote 150 Experimental studies using fact patterns involving personal injury cases and punitive damages awards have found evidence of an anchoring effect and suggest that, all else equal, a plaintiff that requests more damages will tend to receive a larger award.Footnote 151 Thus, there is a risk that reasonable royalty awards based on the entire value of the accused multicomponent products will systematically overvalue patent rights that cover just a fraction of the products’ components or features.

A related problem is that, according to one study based on royalties awarded from 1982 to 2005, U.S. juries tend to award royalty rates that are within the general vicinity of 10 percent, regardless of the size of the base that the rate is applied to.Footnote 152 Combined with anchoring, this finding (if it is still valid) suggests that a patentee who is permitted to present large revenue figures to a jury or judgeFootnote 153 might receive a larger damages award as a result, even if the revenue figures themselves bear little relation to the value of the patented technology. On the other hand, we are not aware of any more recent studies on the issue, and it is possible that the effect has diminished over time (due, perhaps, to the abolition of the 25 percent rule of thumb). There is also concern that juries prefer whole-number rates even when the evidence suggests that the appropriate rate is less than 1 percent. We therefore propose further research on the question of whether juries are susceptible to awarding inappropriately high damages given concerns with apportionment, anchoring, and preferences for particular royalty rates.

In addition, there may be a risk that use of the entire market value as the royalty base will skew litigation outcomes by encouraging patentees to sue downstream parties that are ill suited to defend patent cases. Imagine for example, an allegedly infringing component that is produced by manufacturer M, incorporated into a consumer electronics product produced by company C, shipped to retailer R, and sold to user U. Because infringement can occur by making, selling, or using patented technology, M, C, R, and U are all potential targets for suit. However, in all likelihood it is M that is best positioned to defend a patent suit.Footnote 154 R and U, in particular, may well know nothing about how the component operates, not to mention the intricacies of patent law. Nonetheless, the effect of anchoring will tend to inflate the amount of damages a patentee can expect to recover from C, R, or U. While M may sell the chip to C for pennies or a few dollars, C may earn dozens or hundreds of dollars per unit in sales to R, and R may sell the final product to users for several hundred dollars more per unit.Footnote 155 In addition, U may use the product as part of a business that generates many thousands of dollars a year. Given the option to choose, a patentee will find it advantageous (for reasons that have little to do with the value of the patented technology) to seek damages from component purchasers, retailers, or even users, all of whom have suboptimal incentives to test the patent’s validity and the patentee’s infringement contentions.Footnote 156 On the other hand, if patentees are suing retailers and users who are ill-positioned to defend themselves in an effort to obtain inappropriately high royalties, the first best solution may be to rein in the ability to maintain patent infringement lawsuits down the chain of distribution, rather than to alter damages law.

Finally, limiting damages to the smallest saleable unit may have certain practical benefits. For example, defaulting to a smaller royalty base will tend to reduce the effect of error in royalty rate selection.Footnote 157 It will also tend to narrow the range of possible trial outcomes, which benefits risk-averse parties and increases the likelihood of pretrial settlement.

At the same time, there are several economic arguments in favor of using the entire market value as the royalty base. First, limiting damages calculations to the component level may undervalue patented technology by failing to share with the patentee a portion of the spillover value created by its invention.Footnote 158 A new high-resolution computer screen, for example, may be undervalued by U.S. patent law because, though demand for computers is not primarily driven by their screens, better screens enable or improve other computer functionality, such as video gaming and movie watching.Footnote 159 While in many circumstances we would expect spillover value to be reflected in the sales price of the patented component, it may not be in some instances. Thus, as Petit has argued, “general purpose” technologies with many relatively low-value uses may be undervalued in patent suits against parties that use the technology for less common applications that produce especially large cost savings or profits.Footnote 160

Relatedly, to the extent price discrimination is economically efficient, it makes sense to allow patent owners to extract a higher royalty from implementers who market comparatively expensive end products for which the patent confers substantial value. In addition, as noted above, in real-world licensing transactions parties often, though not invariably, use the entire market value as the base. To the extent reasonable royalty awards should mimic real-world licenses, use of the entire market value often would seem unexceptional.Footnote 161

Given the wide variety of arguments for and against the entire market value/SSPPU rules as employed in the United States, we first propose further research, both with regard to the economic issues highlighted above and into the psychology of judges and juries (e.g., can anchoring and other biases be overcome in other ways?). Given the likelihood that anchoring does play a role in jury deliberations, however, we further recommend that, for now at least, the Federal Circuit retain rules substantially restricting the use of the entire market value. By the same token, given the likelihood that professional judges are less affected (though perhaps not unaffected) by anchoring, for now we do not recommend that other countries (which do not employ juries to decide patent cases) alter their more liberal approach to the use of the entire market value.

1.4 Practical Considerations

In this final Section, we briefly address three remaining practical issues that courts in some countries either have considered or may devote further attention to in the future, namely (1) the evaluation of individual pieces of expert evidence to satisfy a basic threshold of quality; (2) the enhancement of reasonable royalty awards to achieve additional deterrence; and (3) the calibration of damages awards based on context-specific factors.

1.4.1 Expert Evidence and Daubert Gatekeeping in the United States

In the United States, there are two main ways by which judges can police proof of reasonable royalty damages. First, they can enforce and, as appropriate and necessary, develop legal doctrine directly regulating what constitutes adequate evidence for reasonable royalty damages. Second, they can enforce and, as appropriate and necessary, develop legal doctrine regulating the admissibility of evidence for purposes of such proof.

The second, admissibility oriented mechanism looms large in the United States, where the primary fact finder is commonly a jury, rather than the trial judge. Under the United States’ Federal Rule of Evidence 702, which essentially embodies a requirement previously articulated by the Supreme Court of the United States in Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc.,Footnote 162 trial judges police the admissibility of expert testimony to ensure that this evidence “will help the trier of fact to understand the evidence or to determine a fact in issue,” “is based on sufficient facts or data,” and results from the application of “reliable principles and methods.”Footnote 163 Because expert testimony is often a vital component of the proof of reasonable royalty damages, judicial gatekeeping under Daubert has become a powerful tool for limiting the permissible evidentiary bases for such damages. The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit has reversed or vacated a number of damages verdicts in patent cases on Daubert grounds.Footnote 164

In the absence of a jury or other fact finder distinct from the trial-level adjudicator of questions of law, there is probably less significance to the distinction between (1) the ultimate assessment of the overall sufficiency of evidence to support a damages award and (2) gatekeeping for the relevance and reliability of expert testimony. But although the particular standard for expert testimony gatekeeping has been controversial within the United States,Footnote 165 something like Daubert-style review might generally be useful even in the absence of juries. We recommend that courts consider whether individual pieces of expert evidence satisfy a basic threshold of quality in addition to separately examining the overall sufficiency of all relevant evidence.

1.4.2 “Kickers” for Reasonable Royalties

There has been discussion in the United States about whether there should be the possibility of a “kicker” that increases damages beyond a straight reasonable royalty for any of multiple reasons: for example, compensation for litigation costs,Footnote 166 deterrence,Footnote 167 compensation for lost profits that a royalty rate might not ordinarily reflect,Footnote 168 and correction for pre-existing royalty rates’ incorporation of a discount because of uncertainty about patent claim validity or scope.Footnote 169 The U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit has indicated that courts may combine a reasonable royalty award with compensation for other damages that the royalty does not cover – for example, lost profits from depression of royalties obtained from others because infringement has bred “widespread and open disregard of [relevant] patent rights.”Footnote 170 But the Federal Circuit has also held that monetary awards to compensate for litigation expenses or to punish an infringer may only be awarded in accordance with statutory provisions and precedent specific to awards of attorney fees or enhanced damages.Footnote 171 Thus, under current law in the United States, courts may not include a kicker for such purposes when assessing standard compensatory damages.

Consideration of awarding a kicker beyond reasonable royalties generally seems best addressed under other rubrics, which we explore in other parts of this book. In this chapter, we have already addressed questions about the need to correct for pre-litigation uncertainty in the context of the hypothetical negotiation framework. Likewise, questions about when and how to award lost profits are addressed in Chapter 2, and questions about when and how to punish infringement or compensate for litigation costs are discussed in Chapter 3. Rather than handle such concerns obliquely through the use of kickers added to reasonable royalties, we recommend that they be addressed directly through remedial doctrines created for those particular purposes.

1.4.3 Calibrated Evidentiary Burdens or Royalty Measures

As an alternative to applying the same standards for measuring or proving reasonable royalty damages in every case, courts could apply standards for measuring or proving reasonable royalty damages that are responsive to context-specific factors. These factors could include (1) the relative blameworthiness of the parties; “(2) the state of the art or the availability of evidence for proving damages,” including one or another party’s status as a cheaper information provider; and “(3) the amount of damages alleged.”Footnote 172 Calibration of damages measures or evidentiary burdens based on context-specific factors has occurred in other legal areas, such as contract lawFootnote 173 and the law of restitution.Footnote 174 In these areas of law, doubts are often resolved against parties viewed as blameworthy,Footnote 175 and courts have relaxed “demands of reasonable certainty when … the state of the art or other circumstances do not permit more precise or robust proof of damages.”Footnote 176 Extension of such calibration to encompass sensitivity to “the amount of damages alleged” seems plausible and perhaps even natural for a form of monetary relief that uses the word “reasonable” in its very name. At least if the law wishes to ensure that smaller claims for damages are practically enforceable, the law should not generally demand that a claimant for such limited damages expend more on proving these damages than the claimant alleges the damages to be worth. Nonetheless, because there is enough immediate challenge in articulating basic principles for computing reasonable royalties, we propose further research on more context-specific calibration.

Footnotes

2 See Footnote id. at 6.

3 See Howard & Maples 2016, 32.

4 For discussion of some differences in methodology, see Cotter & Golden Reference Cotter, Golden, Menell and Schwartz2018, 15 Footnote n.65.

5 We use the phrase “courts award” above even though in the majority of U.S. cases a jury awards damages. A judge ultimately must decide whether or not to enter final judgment in accordance with the verdict and the applicable rules of civil procedure.

6 See Barry et al. 2017, 9–11, 16.

7 See Matsunaka Reference Matsunaka2004, based on a review of all cases “published in the list of IPR related judgments on the Supreme Court website, in which the right holder claimed damages relating to IP … and for which judgment affirming all or part of the claim was rendered during the period from January 1, 1998, to December 31, 2003,” reporting that reasonable royalty awards made up the plurality in both patent (forty out of seventy-nine) and utility model (twenty-two out of forty-two) cases from 1999 to 2003.

8 Second Subcommittee of the Second Patent Committee 2014 (in Japanese); Cotter Reference 322Cotter2015 (discussing this article). See also Nakamura Reference Nakamura2014, 407–10 (listing all Japanese patent damages judgments from January 1, 2003 to January 30, 2014); Yamaguchi Reference Yamaguchi2016, 136 (reporting that there were thirteen first instance patent damages judgments in 2014, the top one being in the amount of ¥1,568,040,000, equal to about $13.3 million as of December 21, 2016).

9 See, e.g., Dumont Reference Dumont2015 (reporting mean and median damages of €323,270 and €60,000, respectively, based on analysis of “483 patent infringement suits encompassing 673 patents” filed in the Tribunal de la grande instance de Paris from 2008 to 2013). But see République Française, Ministère du Redressement Productifs 2014, 58, 154–56 (in a study comparing awards in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom from January 1, 2010 to August 1, 2013, and believed to cover approximately 25 percent of all decisions rendered during the applicable time periods, reporting inter alia that 36 percent of reasonable royalty awards in France and 50 percent of such awards in Germany were for more than €100,000). For discussion of other French studies, see Cotter & Golden Reference Cotter, Golden, Menell and Schwartz2018, 17.

10 See Cotter & Golden Reference Cotter, Golden, Menell and Schwartz2018, 18 (citing literature).

11 This underdeterrence concern is likely to be less pronounced in cases in which the patent owner seeks an award of lost profits rather than reasonable royalties, because a patent owner presumably would seek lost profits only when it would have refused to license the infringer at all, due to the patent owner’s or its exclusive licensee’s superior efficiency in producing the patented product. See Blair & Cotter Reference Blair and Cotter2005, 58. In addition, concerns that a reasonable royalty might discourage patent owners from commercializing their technology, by not taking the value of commercialization efforts into account, should be alleviated if the fact finder considers the impact such investments would have had on the bargain the patentee would have struck ex ante, including its timing and the relevant information set; the appropriate division of the value of the invention between the parties; and the selection of appropriate comparator licenses. See infra Sections 1.3.1 through 1.3.6.

12 For example, in many countries a licensee may be able to avoid paying royalties once the patent is invalidated, but it would be unable to recover back the royalties it paid prior to invalidation. By contrast, an infringer who challenges validity can avoid paying royalties altogether if the patent is invalidated (and in some countries with bifurcated infringement and validity proceedings, the “infringer” may even be entitled to recover back any damages it paid prior to invalidation). In addition, an intentional infringer may be aware from the time it begins infringing that there is a market for the patented product – unlike a licensee, who at the time the license is concluded may face an uncertain demand for the product – and may avoid other disadvantages, such as upfront royalty payments or submitting to periodic inspections by the patentee.

13 See AIPLA 2015, I-105–8 (reporting that the median cost of litigating a patent infringement suit with less than $1 million at risk through to judgment is $600,000; for a suit with between $1 million and $10 million at risk, $2 million; for a suit with between $10 million and $25 million at risk, $3.1 million; and for a suit with over $25 million at risk, $5 million). For estimates of the cost of litigating a patent infringement action in other countries, see generally Elmer & Gramenopoulos Reference Elmer and Gramenopoulos2016; Heath Reference Heath2015.

14 See generally Taylor Reference Taylor2014.

15 For discussion, see, e.g., Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 269–70 (discussing this possibility under French and German law). Although the theory is economically sound, courts and commentators in France and Germany have not universally embraced such awards due to their resemblance to disfavored enhanced or punitive damages.

16 See Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment § 42 cmt. a.

17 See Cotter Reference Cotter2013b. One drawback of an approach that attempts to construct the bargain the parties would have struck is that it does not provide much guidance in cases in which (1) no bargain would have been struck, because the patentee preferred exclusivity and would not have licensed the infringer at any rate the infringer would have accepted, but (2) the plaintiff cannot, or chooses not to, prove its own lost profits. It also does not provide much guidance on what to do when the parties’ evidence is defective but the court is statutorily obligated to award some royalty anyway, as is arguably the case for example under 35 U.S.C. § 284. In such instances, reliance on industry standard rates or other nonspecific evidence may be the only available fallback.

Note also that when the infringer is required to give up the entire profit or cost saving it derived from the use of the patented invention, the remedy is more appropriately characterized as “disgorgement” or an “accounting of profits,” as opposed to a reasonable royalty. For further discussion, see Chapter 2.

18 See, e.g., Risch Reference Risch2018 (arguing that reasonable royalties should reflect the value of the use of the patented invention to the infringer); Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016 (proposing that, consistent with the standard sometimes articulated by German courts, U.S. courts aspire to construct the bargain the parties would have negotiated ex ante with full knowledge of all relevant information that is made known ex post); Taylor Reference Taylor2014 (arguing that reasonable royalties should reflect the value of the use of the patented technology). Compare BGH v. 14.3.2000 – X ZR 115/98 (Ger.) (stating that “what is owed is what reasonable contracting parties would have agreed to, at the conclusion of a licensing agreement, if they had foreseen the future development and specifically the duration and amount of the use of the patent”), with General Tire & Rubber Co. Ltd. v. Firestone Tyre & Rubber Co. Ltd. (HL 1975, p.186–87) (UK) (in a case in which the trial court had awarded a royalty of one U.S. cent per pound of tire tread stock (T.T.S.), based on evidence that the infringer’s use of the patented method reduced its costs by 1.8 old pence per pound of T.T.S., holding on appeal that a proper royalty would have been only 3/8 of a U.S. cent per pound of oil extended rubber (O.E.R.), based on the “going rate” the patentee had charged others for the use of the invention).

19 See Golden & Sandrik Reference Golden and Sandrik2017. It is also conceivable that, if restitutionary awards are characterized as equitable in nature, there might not be a constitutional right to trial by jury on the amount of the award under U.S. law, though the point is highly debatable. See Cotter Reference Cotter2013b, 25–29.

20 See, e.g., Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.); General Tire & Rubber Co. Ltd. v. Firestone Tyre & Rubber Co. Ltd. (HL 1975, p.178–79 (opinion of Lord Wilberforce), 188–89 (opinion of Lord Salmon)) (UK).

21 See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016.

22 Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2009, p.1324) (U.S.).

23 TWM Mfg. Co., Inc. v. Dura Corp. (Fed. Cir. 1986, p.899) (U.S.). The infringer’s expected profit from the sales of products incorporating the patented technology also was an important factor in the Second Circuit’s modification of the royalty awarded in Georgia Pacific. See Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (2d Cir. 1971, p.289–99) (U.S.). For further discussion of the analytical approach, see Skenyon et al. Reference Skenyon, Marchese, Land and Porcelli2016, § 3.8; Cox Reference Cox2017; Gooding Reference Gooding2012; Pedigo Reference Pedigo2017; Rooklidge Reference Rooklidge2014.

24 See Pedigo Reference Pedigo2017.

25 See Cox Reference Cox2017 (arguing that the analytical approach is economically deficient, for reasons stated in the text above); Gooding Reference Gooding2012, 7 (critiquing the analytical approach on the ground, inter alia, that it “assumes that every penny of additional profit (above the infringer’s ‘usual’ or ‘acceptable’ profit) is attributable solely to the patented invention. It therefore makes no attempt to account for the importance of the infringed technology in generating those incremental profits and does not reflect ‘the invention’s contribution to the infringing product or service’”) (quoting Uniloc USA, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp. Fed. Cir. 2011, p.1313) (U.S.); Rooklidge Reference Rooklidge2014.

26 See, e.g., Rude v. Westcott (U.S. 1889, p.164–65) (U.S.) (stating that, to qualify as an established royalty, the rate “must be paid or secured before the infringement complained of,” “must be paid by such a number of persons as to indicate a general acquiescence in its reasonableness by those who have occasion to use the invention,” “must be uniform at the places where the licenses are issued,” and should not be paid in settlement of another infringement claim). For discussion, see Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 108.

27 See Second Subcommittee of the Second Patent Committee 2014 (in Japanese); Cotter Reference 322Cotter2015. See, e.g., Fulta Elec. Machinery Co. v. Watanabe Kikai Kogyo K. K. (IP High Ct. 2015) (Japan).

28 In re Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litigation (N.D. Ill. 2013) (U.S.). See also Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Apple Japan LLC (IP High Ct. 2014, p.132–38) (Japan) (applying a form of top-down analysis); Unwired Planet Int’l Ltd. v. Huawei Techs. Co. (Pat 2017, ¶¶ 475–80) (UK) (applying a top-down approach as a cross-check on the FRAND royalty derived from analysis of comparables).

29 See Cotter Reference Cotter2018, 206–11.

  1. 1. The royalties received by the patentee for the licensing of the patent in suit, proving or tending to prove an established royalty.

  2. 2. The rates paid by the licensee for the use of other patents comparable to the patent in suit.

  3. 3. The nature and scope of the license, as exclusive or nonexclusive; or as restricted or nonrestricted in terms of territory or with respect to whom the manufactured product may be sold.

  4. 4. The licensor’s established policy and marketing program to maintain his patent monopoly by not licensing others to use the invention or by granting licenses under special conditions designed to preserve that monopoly.

  5. 5. The commercial relationship between the licensor and licensee, such as, whether they are competitors in the same territory in the same line of business; or whether they are inventor and promoter.

  6. 6. The effect of selling the patented specialty in promoting sales of other products of the licensee; the existing value of the invention to the licensor as a generator or sales of his non-patented items; and the extent of such derivative or convoyed sales.

  7. 7. The duration of the patent and the term of the license.

  8. 8. The established profitability of the product made under the patent; its commercial success; and its current popularity.

  9. 9. The utility and advantages of the patent property over the old modes or devices, if any, that had been used for working out similar results.

  10. 10. The nature of the patented invention; the character of the commercial embodiment of it as owned and produced by the licensor; and the benefits to those who have used the invention.

  11. 11. The extent to which the infringer has made use of the invention; and any evidence probative of the value of that use.

  12. 12. The portion of the profit or of the selling price that may be customary in the particular business or in comparable businesses to allow for the use of the invention or analogous inventions.

  13. 13. The portion of the realizable profit that should be credited to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, the manufacturing process, business risks, or significant features or improvements added by the infringer.

  14. 14. The opinion testimony of qualified experts.

  15. 15. The amount that a licensor (such as the patentee) and a licensee (such as the infringer) would have agreed upon (at the time the infringement began) if both had been reasonably and voluntarily trying to reach an agreement; that is, the amount that a prudent licensee – who desired, as a business proposition, to obtain a license to manufacture and sell a particular article embodying the patented invention – would have been willing to pay as a royalty and yet be able to make a reasonable profit and which amount would have been acceptable by a prudent patentee who was willing to grant a license.

Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.). Notice that the fifteenth Georgia-Pacific factor is the hypothetical bargain discussed above in Section 1.2. In one view, the fourteen preceding factors are best viewed as aids in determining the fifteenth. See Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 643.

31 See AlliedSignal Inc. v. DuPont Canada Inc. (Fed. Ct. 1998, ¶ 209) (Can.) (listing as potentially relevant factors in constructing a hypothetical license: (1) whether the patentee would have need to transfer technology to the implementer; (2) differences in the parties’ practice of the invention; (3) whether the patentee would have agreed to an exclusive or nonexclusive license; (4) the territory covered by the license; (5) the term of the license; (6) whether there were available competing technologies; (7) whether the patentee and the implementer are competitors; (8) the demand for the infringing product; (9) the risk that the product would not sell; (10) the novelty of the invention; (11) the compensation needed for research and development costs; (12) whether the invention would result in increased revenues accruing to the licensee; and (13) whether the patentee has the capacity to meet market demand itself). See also Jay-Lor Int’l Inc. v. Penta Farm Sys. Ltd. (Fed. Ct. 2007, ¶¶ 147, 160–73) (Can.) (approving the use of these factors).

32 See Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 268 (stating that German courts may take into account a range of factors, including the existence of noninfringing alternatives; “the terms of comparable licenses; the significance of the invention as suggested by the defendant’s profit expectations; whether the use interferes with the patentee’s monopoly position (Monopolstellung); the increase in value brought about by the use of the patented invention, including revenue from other goods that are sold and used together with it; and whether the revenue derived from the infringement is attributable in part to the infringer’s (or third parties’) technology”).

33 See Footnote id. at 321–22 (stating that Japanese courts often use as a starting point the standard rate for a given technological field as reported by the Japanese Institute of Inventors and Innovation (Hatsumei Kyokai), as well as “a variety of additional factors similar to those used in the United States and Canada, including the scope and significance of the patent and the benefits the defendant derives from its use”); Second Subcommittee of the Second Patent Committee 2014 (article, in Japanese, discussing the factors that explain the royalty rates awarded by Japanese courts); Cotter Reference 322Cotter2015 (discussing the preceding article).

34 See Ericsson, Inc. v. D-Link Sys. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1231, 1235) (U.S.) (vacating a damages judgment where the jury was instructed, among other things, on factors that were irrelevant to the facts of the case); Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 628 (stating that Georgia-Pacific “overloads the jury with factors to consider that may be irrelevant, overlapping, or even contradictory”).

35 See Contreras & Gilbert Reference Contreras and Gilbert2015, 1499 (stating that “the Georgia-Pacific fifteen-factor analysis muddied the water substantially in 1970, allowing litigants and courts to focus on any number of confounding factors that distracted from the core inquiry regarding the value of the patented technology”); Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 628.

36 See Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 631 (stating that “a non-exclusive fifteen-factor test that requires balancing and consideration of the interactions between the factors is likely to give little or no practical guidance to a jury”); Patent Reform Act of 2009: Hearing on H.R. 1260 (H. Comm. on the Judiciary 2009, p.75) (prepared statement of Professor John R. Thomas, Georgetown University Law Center) (stating that “the Georgia-Pacific factors are difficult to apply consistently” because the case “offers no recipe – that is to say, no principles for deciding whether one of the seemingly randomly ordered elements should be weighed more heavily than another in a given determination”) (quoted in Seaman Reference Seaman2010, 1703–04); Schlicher Reference Schlicher2009, 22 (stating that “juries are not given useful guidance on how to apply the so-called Georgia-Pacific factors”).

37 See Cotter Reference Cotter2018, 193 (stating that “unless the judge exerts very tight control over the presentation of evidence, a clever expert could manipulate the factors to find support for virtually any damages amount”); Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 632 (stating that “[t]he breadth of the available factors also means that it is difficult to exclude evidence or expert testimony espousing virtually any theory of reasonable royalty damages, no matter how outlandish,” and that because “Georgia-Pacific provides little guidance as to which factors must be accorded the most weight in any given case, the expert’s ultimate conclusion, no matter how extreme, can usually be justified by at least some combination of them”).

38 See Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 628, 632 (stating that “because the jury’s finding is the result of such a complex, multi-factor test, it is as a practical matter almost entirely immune from scrutiny by either district or appellate judges facing a deferential standard of review,” and that “the fifteen-factor test makes it extremely difficult for judges to review a jury damage award for substantial evidence, either on judgment as a matter of law (JMOL) or on appeal”); The Evolving IP Marketplace (Fed. Trade Comm’n 2009, p.15) (testimony of Professor Paul M. Janicke, University of Houston Law Center) (stating that Georgia-Pacific leads to “erratic results” because the test is like a “grab bag” where “the judge throws the grab bag with all the factors to the jury and says, ‘Do what you think is right’”) (quoted in Seaman Reference Seaman2010, 1704); Seaman Reference Seaman2010, 1665, 1703 (stating that “the so-called Georgia-Pacific test … has become increasingly difficult for juries to apply in lengthy and complex patent trials, resulting in unpredictable damage awards,” and that “Georgia-Pacific’s absence of guidance for balancing the various factors contributes to a lack of certainty and predictability in reasonable royalty awards”); Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 151–52. (“No doubt one contributing factor to inaccuracy, uncertainty, and unpredictability regarding reasonable royalties is the relatively unbounded expert testimony and evidence allowed by the Georgia-Pacific factors and the hypothetical negotiation construct.”)

39 See Cotter Reference Cotter2018, 168 (stating that “the greater the range of possible outcomes (that is, the greater the variance around the expected mean), the smaller the probability that the parties will settle their dispute (thus raising administrative costs), and the greater the likelihood that the more risk-averse party will be willing to settle on unfavorable terms”).

40 FCBA 2016. In a recent article, Contreras and Eixenberger advocate the uniform adoption of the Federal Circuit Bar Association’s proposed jury instructions. See Contreras & Eixenberger Reference Contreras and Eixenberger2016.

41 Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 629.

42 See Jarosz & Chapman Reference Jarosz and Chapman2013.

43 This chapter uses the term “bottom-up” to refer to approaches in which the royalties due to patent holders in separate cases are for the most part determined independently of one another. As discussed supra Footnote note 28 and accompanying text, as an alternative to such an approach courts sometimes may employ a “top-down” approach, in which they first determine the aggregate royalty burden for a specific product or standard and then apportion that burden among the patents reading on that product or standard (see TCL Commc’ns Tech. Holdings, Ltd. v. Telefonaktiebolaget LM Ericsson (C.D. Cal. 2017) (U.S.); Unwired Planet Int’l Ltd. v. Huawei Techs. Co. (Pat 2017) (UK); Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Apple Japan LLC (IP High Ct. 2014) (Japan)). Although top-down approaches may help to reduce risks of holdup and royalty stacking, they may lend themselves more to cases involving patents declared essential to the practice of standards embodying a discrete set of technologies. Outside that context, the evidence needed to employ a top-down approach may be more difficult to obtain, given the lack of both a finite set of declared patents and a defined set of technological features for which royalties are due. Given this chapter’s emphasis on complex products generally, therefore, its focus will be on improvements to the bottom-up approach, though in the end the decision whether to apply a bottom-up or top-down approach in FRAND or other complex product cases ultimately may depend on the availability and quality of the evidence before the court.

44 As a shorthand, we employ the word “use,” as in “use of the invention over alternatives,” though strictly speaking the infringer’s conduct at issue could consist of any selection or combination of the specific activities, such as manufacturing, use, or importation, that can constitute infringement.

45 See Unwired Planet Int’l Ltd. v. Huawei Techs. Co. (Pat 2017, ¶ 182) (UK). (stating that “There was ample evidence before me that … parties negotiating SEP licences in fact use methods which are based on patent counting.  That is evidence which supports a finding that a FRAND approach to assessing a royalty rate is to engage in some kind of patent counting.  Indeed when one thinks about it some sort of patent counting is the only practical approach at least for a portfolio of any size.  Trying to evaluate the importance of individual inventions becomes disproportionate very quickly.”)

46 As is also discussed above, however, there are legitimate debates over whether the focus should be on actual or only expected advantages, and on how to proceed when the next best alternative is itself patented.

47 The simplest example would be one in which the infringer has sold both comparable products, one containing the patented feature and one without that feature, under similar market conditions, such that it is possible to infer the incremental benefit conferred by the patent. See, e.g., Grain Processing Corp. v. Am. Maize-Prods. Co. (Fed. Cir. 1999) (U.S.); Carson et al. v. American Smelting & Refining Co. (W.D. Wash. 1928) (U.S.). To the extent the patented invention is complementary to other features of the infringer’s product, however, as it often will be in complex products cases, apportionment becomes more complicated. See infra Section 1.3.1 (discussing a hypothetical in which the patented invention provides 20 percent longer battery life to a smartphone).

48 See Cotter Reference Cotter2018, 192 Footnote n.133 (stating that among the most important Georgia-Pacific factors are “factors 8 through 10, all of which relate to the value of the patented technology, in terms of its effect on the implementer’s profit or cost, in comparison with alternatives,” and “factor 13, ‘the portion of the realizable profit that should be credited to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, the manufacturing process, business risks, or significant features or improvements added by the infringer’”).

49 See, e.g., Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc. (W.D. Wash. 2013) (U.S.).

50 For discussion of the use of conjoint and discrete choice analysis in litigation, see, e.g., Platt & Chen Reference Platt and Chen2013; Sidak & Skog Reference Sidak and Skog2016; Verma et al. Reference Verma, Plaschka and Louviere2002 (providing an accessible discussion of discrete-choice analysis).

51 See, e.g., Swanson & Baumol Reference Swanson and Baumol2005, 10–11; Farrell et al. Reference Farrell, Hayes, Shapiro and Sullivan2007, 610–11; Elhauge Reference Elhauge2008, 541; Denicolò et al. Reference Denicolò, Geradin, Layne-Farrar and Jorge Padilla2008, 577–78; Layne-Farrar et al. Reference Layne-Farrar, Llobet and Jorge Padilla2009, 448; Shapiro Reference Shapiro2010, 286; Gilbert Reference Gilbert2011, 864; Camesasca et al. Reference Camesasca, Langus, Neven and Treacy2013, 304; Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 128; Carlton & Shampine Reference Carlton and Shampine2013, 536, 545; Jarosz & Chapman Reference Jarosz and Chapman2013, 812; Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 95–97; Cotter Reference Cotter2014a, 357; Sedona Conference 2014, 23–24; Contreras & Gilbert Reference Contreras and Gilbert2015, 1467–69, 1499–1500; Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Cotter2017a; Lee & Melamed Reference Lee and Melamed2016, 411–12; Epstein & Marcus Reference Epstein and Marcus2003, 557–58. See also Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 91–97 (contrasting the value of the technology with the value of patent rights, where the latter might include for example the ability to use an injunction to extract holdup value.)

52 Our recommendation that royalties should be “commensurate with” the value of the technology, however, does not amount to a recommendation that courts should aspire to award patentees the entire social value of their inventions. For discussion, see, e.g., Frischmann & Lemley Reference Lemley2007; Golden Reference Golden2010, 529–39; Lemley Reference Lemley2005, 1036–37; Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 138–41.

53 See Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Apple Japan LLC (IP High Ct. 2014, p.134) (Japan).

54 In economic theory the independent value of the complementary technology is given by the Shapley value. See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Cotter2017a. However, it will rarely be possible to compute Shapley pricing directly.

55 In the standards context it also quite likely that in practice all the relevant technologies will be patented, precisely because of the incentive provided by the prospect of being included in the standard; see, e.g., Layne-Farrar Reference Layne-Farrar2014 (discussing the competition among patentees to have their technology included in the standard).

56 Consider, for example, the near-simultaneous invention of Viagra (sildenafil) and Cialis (tadalafil).

57 Swanson & Baumol Reference Swanson and Baumol2005, 10–21 (auction model).

58 Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 161.

59 Lemley & Shapiro Reference Shapiro2007a, 2039 Footnote n.153.

60 See In re Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litigation (N.D. Ill. 2013, p.20) (U.S.) (stating that the court would consider patented alternatives, but “that they will not drive down the royalty in the hypothetical negotiation by as much as technology in the public domain”).

61 For a brief discussion, see Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Cotter2017a.

62 Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2009, p.1324) (U.S.). It is also sometimes referred to as a “hypothetical bargain” or “willing licensor/willing licensee” approach.

63 Footnote Id. at 1325.

64 Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co. (Fed. Cir. 1995, p.1554 Footnote n.13) (U.S.) (en banc).

65 Panduit Corp. v. Stahlin Bros. Fibre Works Inc. (6th Cir. 1978, p.1159) (U.S.).

67 Hanson v. Alpine Valley Ski Area, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 1983, p.1081) (U.S.) (quoted with approval in Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co. (Fed. Cir. 1995, p.1554 Footnote n.13) (U.S.)).

68 TWM Mfg. Co., Inc. v. Dura Corp. (Fed. Cir. 1986, p.900) (U.S.) (quoted with approval in Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co. (Fed. Cir. 1995, p.1554 Footnote n.13) (U.S.)).

69 See similarly Janicke Reference Janicke1993, 726–27 (“The engrafted ‘assumptions’ of validity, infringement, and business information would be better viewed as reminders to the decisionmaker on reasonable royalty to help him or her reach a just result, rather than as facts artificially deemed ‘known’ at an artificial negotiation.”).

70 Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 135–36; see also Choi Reference Choi2009, 154–55 (arguing that the use of ex post information is necessary to cure this problem); Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 115–16 (reviewing the development of the law on this point, and arguing that the problem is not only one of double discounting, but circularity, because the discounted value that the parties would negotiate would itself then be reflected in the damages award, and the parties, anticipating this, would further discount the negotiated price, and so on).

71 Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 127–29.

72 See Janicke Reference Janicke1993, 726 (suggesting that “[i]n view of the increasing number of assumptions engrafted onto the underlying fiction of hypothetical negotiation, the Federal Circuit should consider whether the time has come to abolish the fiction altogether … ”); Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 125–26. Similarly, although real-world negotiations sometimes might result in a degree of royalty stacking in cases involving complex products, for purposes of awarding reasonable royalties courts could make the assumption that the parties would have bargained to avoid this outcome, in order better to align royalties with the value of the technology.

73 The main theoretical refinement is by Ariel Rubinstein, who shows that under certain conditions, a party with a higher discount rate (higher time value of money) will have less bargaining power. Rubinstein Reference Rubinstein1982.

74 See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016, 954–55:

In an actual license agreement, both parties bring something to the table in the process of turning an invention into a commercially valuable revenue-generating product. The patentee’s most obvious contribution is the invention, but bringing the final product to market generally requires further development and technical implementation, such as clinical trials, as well as marketing, manufacturing, and distribution, all of which require further investment at risk beyond the investment made by the patentee in the invention itself. Either of the parties may provide these further services, and the way the parties split the incremental profit in an actual negotiation depends on who provides what services and the relative importance and cost of those services.

75 Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.) (“13. The portion of the realizable profit that should be credited to the invention as distinguished from non-patented elements, the manufacturing process, business risks, or significant features or improvements added by the infringer.”).

76 Tights, Inc. v. Kayser-Roth Corp. (M.D.N.C. 1977, p.164) (U.S.).

77 See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016, 989–90.

78 In economic theory, “bargaining power” is used largely as a label rather than an explanatory variable. If the observed split is 80/20, and there is no evident reason for an uneven division, then we say that one of the parties has greater bargaining power than the other.

79 U.S. Frumentum Co. v. Lauhoff (6th Cir. 1914, p.617) (U.S.); see also Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.) (listing factor 12, which refers to “[t]he portion of the profit or of the selling price that may be customary in the particular business or in comparable businesses to allow for the use of the invention or analogous inventions,” and is likely based on Frumentum).

80 U.S. Patent Act, 35 U.S.C. § 284 (emphasis added); see also Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1328) (U.S.) (stating that, even when a patent owner fails to introduce admissible evidence quantifying its loss, the court is obligated to “determine what constitutes a reasonable royalty from the record evidence”); Schönknecht Reference Schönknecht2012, 311–13 (discussing the German courts’ “free discretion” to estimate damages under § 287 of the Code of Civil Procedure, and stating that “[t]he injured party is not required to prove the exact amount of its damage; rather, it is sufficient if it presents a factual basis on which the court can establish ‘at least a rough estimate’ of the damage.”) (citing BGH v. 6.3.1980 – X ZR 49/78 – Tolbutamid (Ger.)).

81 Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 97–101, 112–13 (describing this history of the development of reasonable royalties).

82 See, e.g., Cincinnati Car Co. v. New York Rapid Transit Corp. (2d Cir. 1933, p.594–95) (U.S.).

83 Such awards are no longer available in the United States other than in design patent cases, as discussed in Chapter 2.

84 See, e.g., Henrich Reference Henrich2015, 191–92, 358–59; Stout Reference Stout2011, 52–54.

85 Summit 6, LLC v. Samsung Electronics Co. (Fed. Cir. 2015, p.1297) (U.S.). Compare VirnetX, Inc. v. Apple Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1333–34) (U.S.) (disapproving of the use of the Nash Bargaining Solution on the ground that use of a 50–50 split as the proposed starting point for a damages calculation was “insufficiently tied to the facts of the case”).

86 Various bodies of law, including patent law, make use of presumptions in a variety of contexts in which a fact of interest (call it X) is difficult to prove but likely correlated with the presence of some other, more easily provable, fact (call it Y). In such cases, presuming the existence of fact X upon proof of fact Y may reduce adjudication costs and better promote the goal of accurate fact finding than would a rule requiring that, absent competent proof of fact X, the trier of fact must find not-X. Relatedly, a rebuttable presumption encourages the party against whom the presumption operates to come forward with evidence justifying a departure from the presumption, which makes sense if that party is likely to be better positioned than its counterpart to have access to such information. For discussion of the function and working of presumptions generally, see, e.g., Mueller & Kirkpatrick Reference Mueller and Kirkpatrick1999, 126–31; McGowan Reference McGowan2010, 582; Posner Reference Posner1999, 1503–04.

87 Uniloc USA, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp. (Fed. Cir. 2011) (U.S.).

89 See Lucent Techs., Inc. v. Gateway, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2009, p.1324–25) (U.S.) (stating that “the hypothetical negotiation or the ‘willing licensor-willing licensee’ approach … attempts to ascertain the royalty upon which the parties would have agreed had they successfully negotiated an agreement just before infringement began,” recreating “as best as possible …the ex ante licensing negotiation scenario and … resulting agreement”); Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.). In the SEP context, courts have begun to shift the time frame for the hypothetical negotiations, from just before the patent was infringed to just before the standard was adopted. See In re Innovatio IP Ventures, LLC Patent Litigation (N.D. Ill. 2013, p.19) (U.S.); Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc. (W.D. Wash. 2013, p.19) (U.S.); Apple, Inc. v. Motorola, Inc. (N.D. Ill. 2012, p.913) (U.S.).

90 See infra Section 1.3.5.

91 See Schönknecht Reference Schönknecht2012.

92 See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016.

93 We use the term “sunk costs” throughout in the economic sense of costs that have been incurred and cannot be recovered, rather than in the accounting sense of fixed costs.

94 See, e.g., Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 129 (noting that “[t]o avoid extraction of value from patent holdup, the time period for the hypothetical negotiation should be assumed to be just prior to any investment by the infringer in developing or using the patented technology”).

95 Unless there is some specific reason for allowing a supracompensatory remedy, such as the need to deal with the problem of opportunistic infringement, as discussed in Chapter 3.

96 Tights, Inc. v. Kayser-Roth Corp. (M.D.N.C. 1977) (U.S.).

97 See Footnote id. at 164.

98 Monsanto Co. v. E.I. DuPont De Nemours & Co. (E.D. Mo. 2013) (U.S.). No reported opinion followed the entry of judgment, and the case settled shortly thereafter. For discussion, see Chao & Gray Reference Chao and Gray2013.

99 See Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016; Sidak Reference Sidak2016a. The Sedona Conference also discusses expanded use of ex post information: see Sedona Conference 2016, 22–28. Note, however, that as discussed in the preceding subsection, there may be cases in which the timing of the hypothetical negotiation to avoid sunk costs may not be particularly relevant.

100 Sinclair Ref. Co. v. Jenkins Petroleum Process Co. (U.S. 1933, p.699) (U.S.).

101 Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (2d Cir. 1971, p.297) (U.S.).

102 See Lee & Melamed Reference Lee and Melamed2016, 414 (reviewing the cases and suggesting that “following [Fromson v. W. Litho Plate & Supply Co. (Fed. Cir. 1988, p.1575) (U.S.)], courts have regularly relied on the book of wisdom doctrine to permit the consideration of ex post developments, regardless whether those ex post developments provided any insight into the parties’ ex ante bargaining positions or whether the case involved willful infringement”).

103 See Janicke Reference Janicke1993, 725–27.

104 See Footnote id. (criticizing the court for using ex post information asymmetrically, and arguing that the appropriate response is to formally recognize that “the court should examine the business realities at the time infringement began and subsequently, independent of any theory that a hypothetical negotiation has occurred”).

105 Unless there is a bias in which cases get litigated: see Siebrasse & Cotter Reference Siebrasse and Cotter2016.

106 Durie & Lemley Reference Durie and Lemley2010, 641; see also Masur Reference Masur2015, 120 (“At first blush this approach makes sense; if the courts must reconstruct a hypothetical royalty negotiation, actual preexisting royalty agreements might well constitute the best available evidence of the contours of such a negotiation. Not surprisingly, scholars, commentators, and courts nearly unanimously bless the use of existing licenses to calculate patent damages.”).

107 The first two Georgia-Pacific factors, for example, focus specifically on prior licensing agreements. See Georgia-Pacific Corp. v. U.S. Plywood Corp. (S.D.N.Y. 1970, p.1120) (U.S.) (listing “1. The royalties received by the patentee for the licensing of the patent in suit, proving or tending to prove an established royalty” and “2. The rates paid by the licensee for the use of other patents comparable to the patent in suit”). Other factors refine the relevance of prior licenses by adding context. For example, the third and fourth factors consider the nature of the patentee’s licensing program by weighing the exclusivity of the prior licenses and any geographic restrictions or other special conditions found in them. See Footnote id. Courts outside the United States also frequently look to comparable licenses, or sometimes industry standard rates, as an aid in calculating reasonable royalties. For discussion of practice in Germany and Japan, see Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 268, 321–22; Second Subcommittee of the Second Patent Committee 2014. Our discussion in the text above to “comparables” therefore should be understood to apply to other analogous forms of evidence, such as industry standard rates.

108 Dowagiac Mfg. Co. v. Minn. Moline Plow Co. (U.S. 1915, p.648) (U.S.) (stating that where the patentee undertakes “a course of granting licenses” then those “established royalties … [afford] a basis for measuring damages”); Rude v. Westcott (U.S. 1889, p.164–65) (U.S.) (stating that, to qualify as an established royalty, the rate “must be paid or secured before the infringement complained of,” “must be paid by such a number of persons as to indicate a general acquiescence in its reasonableness by those who have occasion to use the invention,” “must be uniform at the places where the licenses are issued,” and should not be paid in settlement of another infringement claim); Nickson Indus., Inc. v. Rol Mfg. Co. (Fed. Cir. 1988, p.798) (U.S.) (“Where an established royalty exists, it will usually be the best measure of what is a ‘reasonable’ royalty.”).

109 See, e.g., Consol. Rubber Tire Co. v. Diamond Rubber Co. of NY (S.D.N.Y. 1915, p.459) (U.S.) (describing the inappropriateness of awarding established royalties in circumstances where the licensed patent was widely believed to be invalid); Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 101–04 (explaining that, “[i]n an unbroken line of succession, later courts have followed Judge Hand’s reasoning [in Consol. Rubber Tire Co.] by awarding reasonable royalties rather than diminished royalties established during periods of ‘disrepute’ and ‘open defiance’ of patents”).

110 See Masur Reference Masur2015, 123–24 (noting the difficulties with using different technologies); see also Cotter Reference Cotter2011, 748 (“Strictly speaking, then, for a license to be economically comparable it should relate to the same patent or patents at issue … ”); Weinstein et al. Reference Weinstein, Romig and Stabile2013, 553 (“In view of ResQNet and Lucent, comparable licenses can only include licenses to the patent-in-suit itself, essentially removing from consideration licenses contemplated under Georgia-Pacific Factors 2 and 12.”).

111 See, e.g., Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc. (W.D. Wash. 2013, p.79–92) (U.S.) (quantifying the value to Microsoft of access to the technology in the pool); Unwired Planet Int’l Ltd. v. Huawei Techs. Co. (Pat 2017) (UK) (awarding FRAND royalties based on adjustments to the royalties earned by the assignor of the relevant patent families).

112 See Hovenkamp & Masur Reference Hovenkamp and Masur2017, 407 Footnote n.48.

113 See, e.g., Footnote id. at 12.

114 See Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Apple Japan LLC (IP High Ct. 2014, p.134) (Japan) (awarding different royalties for the same technology to the same manufacturer of phones and tablets).

115 See Hovenkamp & Masur Reference Hovenkamp and Masur2017, 395–96.

116 See Masur Reference Masur2015, 133; Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 112–15.

117 See Shapiro Reference Shapiro2010, 314–15; Lemley & Shapiro Reference Shapiro2007a, 2021–22. As discussed in Chapter 4, the Lemley & Shapiro model assumes that a court will always grant a permanent injunction to the successful patentee, and reasonable royalties for the prejudgment infringement. The longer the trial takes as a proportion of the term of the patent, the greater the effect of the reasonable royalty on the litigation outcome, and so the larger the multiplier. In Shapiro’s formal model, if litigation always takes the same amount of time, the circularity effect will result in a multiplier that is inversely proportional to the post-trial patent term. See Shapiro Reference Shapiro2010, 314.

118 Lemley and Shapiro also argue that the probabilistic nature of patents can give rise to holdup, even when a license is negotiated ex ante: see the discussion of “probabilistic holdup” in Chapter 7.3.1. Probabilistic holdup, however, does not result in circularity, because the overcharge arises because the potential licensee’s threat point is not to use the patented technology entirely; that is to say, the licensee acts as if the patent was valid and infringed. But that is the appropriate assumption once validity and infringement have been established at trial.

119 See Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 115–16.

120 See Footnote id. at 130–31.

121 See Masur Reference Masur2015, 132 Footnote n.76; Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 144–48 (explaining why this is so). For a rare exception, see St. Lawrence (E.D. Tex. Feb. 21, 2017) (permitting St. Lawrence’s expert to offer an opinion that the royalty rate that St. Lawrence had previously negotiated with Samsung for the use of the patents in suit in the pending case against ZTE and Motorola should be increased by 50 percent to reflect a “settlement discount” and 18 percent to account for an “invalidity discount”).

122 Masur Reference Masur2015, 120; see also Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 147.

123 Though it is not unreasonable to assume the patentee’s estimated probability of liability would be in the same ballpark as the licensee’s, or they would not have been able to come to an agreement.

124 See Masur Reference Masur2015, 149–52 (arguing persuasively that an inquiry of this type would be unsatisfactory); Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 147–48 (same).

125 Masur Reference Masur2015, 131.

126 Footnote Id. at 149–52; see also Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 146 (“If infringement and validity are independent variables, then the multiplier resulting from the assumption of liability should be four; that is, the jury should multiply the negotiated royalty reflecting 50% probability of validity and 50% probability of infringement by four to obtain a reasonable royalty reflecting certainty as to liability.”).

127 A separate problem with the standard multiplier is that it would probably not be admissible in U.S. law as not being tied to the facts of the case. See Masur Reference Masur2015, 146. Regardless, even in instances of reliable evidence tied to the facts of the case, there is reason to think a jury in particular would not use an appropriate multiplier. Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 146 (“[D]oes anyone really think that in a close case a jury will multiply pre-litigation royalties by four, while in a case of blatant liability a jury will not increase pre-litigation royalties at all?”).

128 For example, if the parties to the actual negotiation thought there was a 90 percent chance of liability, the royalty in the prior comparable license will hardly be discounted at all, and a reasonable royalty based on that prior license, augmented by a standard multiplier of four, will therefore be almost four times too large. See Masur Reference Masur2015, 154.

129 See Footnote id. at 155.

130 See, e.g., Rude v. Westcott (U.S. 1889, p.164) (U.S.); but see ResQNet (Fed. Cir. 2010, p.868) (approving use of settlement as a comparable, on the facts of the case); Narechania & Kirklin Reference Narechania and Kirklin2012.

131 See Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 131 (suggesting that “to the extent settlement agreements reflect more certainty regarding liability, economists may be able to use them, rather than other agreements, to identify more easily the true value of patented technology”). This suggestion is more fully developed by Masur Reference Masur2015, 145–46. See also Prism Techs. (Fed. Cir. 2017) (approving the use of a settlement license on the facts of the case, and discussing the circumstances under which settlements are more or less likely to be probative).

132 See Masur Reference Masur2015, 145–46, 148.

133 In such a case, it may even be that the royalty will be too low, not too high. If the patent is weak, litigation value settlement may make sense, but once it is adjudged to be valid and infringed, those low-value settlements no longer reflect the true value of the patented technology.

134 As discussed in Chapter 4, awarding ongoing royalties in lieu of injunctions generates a risk of error in the calculation of such royalties – though whether such errors systematically favor one party or the other, and whether they are justified in view of the holdup risk resulting from injunctions, are debatable questions.

135 See Hovenkamp & Masur Reference Hovenkamp and Masur2017, 406.

136 Taylor Reference Taylor2014, 149.

137 See Hovenkamp & Masur Reference Hovenkamp and Masur2017, 406–09; Cotter Reference Cotter2018, 195 (noting that this seems to have been the case in Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc. (W.D. Wash. 2013) (U.S.)).

138 See Hovenkamp & Masur Reference Hovenkamp and Masur2017, 403–04.

139 See Footnote id. Note that it is not enough that the courts could make the distinction; they would have to do so in practice with sufficient predictability that the patentee would not need to worry about the low-value license affecting its recovery in a high-value lawsuit.

140 See Microsoft Corp. v. Motorola, Inc. (W.D. Wash. 2013, p.78) (U.S.) (stating that “[t]he MPEG LA H.264 patent pool charges royalties to licensees for products that incorporate an H.264 codec according to the following schedule: • the first 100,000 units are royalty-free; • for unit volumes between 100,000 and 5 million, the royalty is $0.20 per unit; and • for unit volumes above 5 million, the royalty rate is $0.10 per unit”).

141 See, e.g., Contreras et al. Reference Contreras, Chien, Cotter and Biddle2016 (proposing a study aimed at providing “researchers, litigants, judges, policy makers, regulators and the public with previously unavailable information regarding commercial patent licensing practices, including royalty rates, in a manner that does not compromise firm-level confidential information”); see also Ward Reference Ward2017 (discussing recent German case law intended to increase the disclosure, subject to confidentiality order, of comparables for use in FRAND licensing disputes).

142 In Germany, for example, even when the patent covers only a portion of an end product, courts consider what reasonable parties would have selected as the royalty base, and often though not invariably use the value of the end product, taking into account such factors as industry custom; the convenience of the parties; whether the invention accounts for all or most of the value of the end product; whether the component is often sold separately; and whether it invests the product with its own distinctive stamp (kennzeichnendes Gepräge). See Cotter Reference Cotter2013a, 268; Kühnen Reference Kühnen2015, 700–02; Schönknecht Reference Schönknecht2012, 322–24. Similarly, in Japan courts typically use the value of the end product as the base. See Second Subcommittee of the Second Patent Committee 2014; Cotter Reference 322Cotter2015; Samsung Elecs. Co. v. Apple Japan LLC (IP High Ct. 2014) (Japan).

143 Garretson v. Clark (U.S. 1884, p.121) (U.S.) (“The patentee … must in every case give evidence tending to separate or apportion the defendant’s profits and the patentee’s damages between the patented feature and the unpatented features.”).

144 See, e.g., VirnetX, Inc. v. Apple Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2014) (U.S.) (reversing a damages award based on the entire value of accused smartphone, rather than the smallest saleable infringing component); LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Comp., Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2012, p.67) (U.S.) (“[I]t is generally required that royalties be based not on the entire product, but instead on the ‘smallest salable patent-practicing unit.’”). Though the term “entire market value rule” is generally now understood to have this meaning, earlier case law gave the doctrine much broader application. See Love Reference Love2007, 272 (discussing older case law under which the entire market value rule acted as “a broad exception to the general rule of apportionment”).

145 See CSIRO v. Cisco Sys., Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2015, p.1301–04) (U.S.) (holding that it was permissible for a court to consider evidence of the parties’ previous negotiations, which were based on the entire value of the accused product).

146 See Ericsson, Inc. v. D-Link Sys. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1225–29) (U.S.) (holding that it was permissible for a court to admit evidence of comparable licenses that were based on the entire value of allegedly infringing products). See also Teece & Sherry Reference Teece and Sherry2016 (criticizing case law requiring litigants to use a smallest saleable unit royalty base on the grounds that “very few real-world licenses comport with the SSPPU doctrine, making it difficult to appeal to the terms of real-world licenses in assessing reasonable royalties”).

147 See VirnetX, Inc. v. Apple Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1327) (U.S.) (noting that the “smallest saleable unit” requirement is based on a “fundamental concern about skewing the damages horizon” by “misleadingly suggest[ing] an inappropriate range” of damages); LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Comp., Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2012, p.68) (U.S.) (“Admission of … overall revenues, which have no demonstrated correlation to the value of the patented feature alone, only serve to make a patentee’s proffered damages amount appear modest by comparison, and to artificially inflate the jury’s damages calculation beyond that which is ‘adequate to compensate for the infringement.’”).

148 See, e.g., Furnham & Boo Reference Furnham and Boo2011, 35 (defining the “anchoring effect” as “the disproportionate influence on decision makers to make judgments that are biased toward an initially presented value”).

149 See Greene & Bornstein Reference Greene and Bornstein2003, 149–73 (reviewing the literature on anchoring’s effect on juries). See also Posner & Sunstein Reference Posner and Sunstein2005, 593 (“Juries lack reference points, so their judgments will depend heavily on the presentation of evidence by lawyers, and on whatever anchors, prejudices, and expectations citizens bring to the jury box.”).

150 See Chao Reference Chao2012, 136–37 (noting that the anchoring effect of the plaintiff’s royalty base “is often exacerbated by the tactics defendants use at trial,” including failure to offer a counter-anchor due to “fear that presenting a damages case will be interpreted as an admission of liability”).

151 See Campbell et al. Reference Campbell, Chao, Roberson and Yokum2016, 546 (finding in an experimental study of mock jurors deciding a medical malpractice case that “powerful anchoring effects dominate much smaller but still statistically significant credibility effects” that result from presenting “outrageous[ly]” large anchors); Chapman & Bornstein Reference Chapman and Bornstein1996, 519 (finding in an experimental study of mock jurors deciding a personal injury case that “anchoring occurs in legal applications, and that plaintiffs would do well to request large compensation awards”); Hastie et al. Reference Hastie, Schkade and Payne1999, 445 (finding in an experimental study in which mock jurors were asked to award punitive damages that “plaintiff’s requested award values had a dramatic effect on awards: the higher the request, the higher the awards”).

152 See Lemley & Shapiro Reference Shapiro2007a, 2034 (finding in a study of fifty-eight patent verdicts awarded between 1982 and 2005 that “[t]he royalty rate for components is approximately 10.0%, compared with 13.1% for all inventions and 14.7% for integrated product claims”).

153 Generally speaking, we think it is likely that judges, by virtue of their legal training and experience, will be less susceptible to this effect than lay jurors. As a result, this concern may be particularly acute in countries in which juries award damages, and less of a concern in countries where damages are calculated by judges. However, we do not believe that judges are completely immune. Indeed, experimental studies have shown that judges are susceptible to anchoring effects when awarding damages and determining criminal sentences. See Rachlinski et al. Reference Rachlinski, Wistrich and Guthrie2015, 695 (finding “that the presence of misleading numeric reference points (or ‘anchors’) affected judges’ decisions in a series of hypothetical cases”).

154 See Love & Yoon Reference Love and Yoon2013, 1620–35 (explaining that, compared to their downstream customers, manufacturers are less susceptible to litigation cost holdup and are better positioned to both test the merits of infringement allegations and appropriately value infringed patent rights). See also Europe Economics Reference Thumm and Gabison2016, 5, 28, 48 (noting that European PAEs tend to target telecom companies, “the most vulnerable segment of the supply chain”).

155 Consider, for example, an allegedly infringing $6.50 3G wireless chipset installed in a smartphone that retails for $500. See Love & Yoon Reference Love and Yoon2013, 1634 Footnote n.104 (using the example of a new iPhone 4S in 2013).

156 Love & Yoon Reference Love and Yoon2013, 1628 (arguing that “[a]s between a similarly situated customer and manufacturer, it is virtually always the manufacturer that is best suited to vigorously litigate the case in a manner that challenges the patent’s validity and delineates its claim scope” because customers are often “compan[ies] outside the technology industry that … have no expertise in the accused technology[,] … were not involved in the design, development, or manufacture of the accused technology[, and] … have no understanding of the field of the patent and no knowledge of the prior art to the patent”). Though it is true that a patentee will generally find it more costly to sue multiple downstream parties rather than a single manufacturer, experience suggests that many patentees will nonetheless make this choice. In the United States, retailers are commonly sued for selling allegedly infringing products. For example, according to Lex Machina, Wal-Mart, Target, and Best Buy were each sued for patent infringement more than eighty times between 2012 and 2016. Moreover, some patentees have even pursued large numbers of end users of allegedly infringing products. Footnote Id. at 1610–11 (describing patent monetization campaigns undertaken by patentees like Innovatio IP Venutres, LLC, MPHJ Technology Investments, LLC, and ArrivalStar S.A., which collectively sued hundreds of end users and threatened to sue thousands more).

157 See Stern Reference Stern2015, 554 Footnote n.26 (“[C]onsider a $1 chip in a $500 smartphone. Suppose the invention contributes 10% of the value of the chip and that the reasonable royalty is half of that or 5 cents, i.e., 5% of the $1 chip price. In principle, the reasonable royalty based on the smartphone price would be the same 5 cents or 0.02% of $500. But how is a jury or judge to determine the difference between a royalty of 0.02% and 0.01% or even 0.1%? Yet the cash value of the error is multiplied greatly by starting out with an inflated royalty base. Choosing between infinitesimals is an inherently error-prone exercise.”).

158 See Petit Reference Petit2016 (arguing that use of a “smallest saleable unit” benchmark for patent damages may undervalue “general purpose technologies” that “yield countless positive production externalities”); Geradin & Layne-Farrar Reference Geradin and Layne-Farrar2010, 774–76 (arguing that a strict application of the U.S. entire market value rule may undervalue patent rights to a component of a complex product “if the component in question ‘enables’ other components but does not rise to the level of driving demand”).

159 See Geradin & Layne-Farrar Reference Geradin and Layne-Farrar2010, 775 (using this same example).

160 See Petit Reference Petit2016 (using the example of wireless technology that, when adopted for use in airplanes, led to substantial cost savings by reducing aircraft weight and, consequently, fuel costs). See also Régibeau et al. Reference Régibeau, De Coninck and Zengler2016, 77 (comparing wireless technology in a smartphone, which “do[es] appear to influence a number of important functionalities,” to wireless technology in a car, which “it would be rash to argue … contribute to a very substantial share of the value that consumers place on specific cars”); Layne-Farrar Reference Layne-Farrar2017 (recommending that courts focus on valuing the use of a technology to the implementer, not on trying to pinpoint its location in a particular component; and that they should permit experts to use as the royalty base the implementer’s properly apportioned revenue, without disclosing to the jury the infringer’s overall revenues or profits).

161 See also Baron & Pentheroudakis Reference Pentheroudakis, Baron and Thumm2017, 93–94 (noting that “[t]he practicability (and traceability) of the SSPPU is questionable in the context of portfolio licensing: it is often not possible to map a portfolio of hundreds or even thousands of diverse patents to a single SSPPU”).

162 Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharm. Inc. (U.S. 1993) (U.S.); see also Bernstein & Lasker Reference Bernstein and Lasker2015, 6 (“In 2000, the Judicial Conference of the United States … amended Federal Rule of Evidence 702 for the express purpose of resolving conflicts in the courts about the meaning of Daubert.”).

163 Fed. R. Evid. 702.

164 See, e.g., VirnetX, Inc. v. Apple Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2014, p.1329, 1333–34) (U.S.) (holding that damages expert’s testimony on the royalty base and in support of a fifty-fifty split of profits was inadmissible); LaserDynamics, Inc. v. Quanta Comp., Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2012, p.79) (U.S.) (holding that a damages expert’s testimony on the value of a reasonable royalty rate “was unreliable under Federal Rule of Evidence 702 and should have been excluded”); Uniloc USA, Inc. v. Microsoft Corp. (Fed. Cir. 2011, p.1318) (U.S.) (affirming grant of a new trial on damages where expert testimony based on a “25% rule of thumb” for the proportion of product value constituting a reasonable royalty “fail[ed] to pass muster under Daubert”).

165 See, e.g., Bernstein & Lasker Reference Bernstein and Lasker2015, 9 (reporting “continued divisions among federal courts over the proper standards for admission of expert testimony … ”); Faigman & Imwinkelreid Reference Faigman and Imwinkelreid2013, 1695 (“Even if Daubert is the right choice for the federal judiciary, a state could reasonably conclude that it is not the right path for it to take.”).

166 Cotter Reference Cotter2004, 316 (noting a “Federal Circuit decision stating that courts may not incorporate into the reasonable royalty award a damages ‘kicker’ so as to compensate the patentee for litigation and other expenses”).

167 Footnote Id. (indicating that a damages “kicker” might advance goals of deterrence).

168 Lee & Melamed Reference Lee and Melamed2016, 459 (“[S]ince the royalty may include a ‘kicker’ based on Georgia-Pacific Factor 4 (the patent holder’s policy of licensing or not licensing the patent), patent holders are generally compensated at least to some extent for their loss of market exclusivity.”); Yang Reference Yang2014, 655 (noting scholarly speculation that “[c]ourts, worried about undercompensating patentees who could not prove lost profits, added ‘kickers’ to reasonable royalty awards … ”).

169 Lemley & Shapiro Reference Shapiro2007a, 2019–20 (contending that “[c]ourts have recognized [the discount] problem and periodically seek to modify the market-based royalty data by adding ‘kickers,’ either expressly or sub rosa.”); see also supra Footnote note 15 (noting the occasional practice in France and Germany of increasing royalties to account for risks the infringer has avoided).

170 Maxwell v. J. Baker, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 1996, p.1109) (U.S.) (quoting jury instruction).

171 Whitserve, LLC v. Computer Packages, Inc. (Fed. Cir. 2012, p.34 Footnote n.18) (U.S.).

172 Golden Reference Golden2017, 274; see also Chiang Reference Chiang2017 (advocating two principles for the assignment of evidentiary burdens in damages law: (1) “courts should only require a party to produce information when the social benefit of the information … exceeds the costs of producing the information” and (2) “courts should impose the burden of proof on the party that can produce the required evidence at lower cost”).

173 Golden Reference Golden2017, 272 (observing that, in contract law, “courts have allowed for pragmatic or fairness-oriented tuning of certainty standards on a retail as well as a wholesale basis”).

174 Golden & Sandrik Reference Golden and Sandrik2017 (“The law of restitution illustrates how, in addressing difficult-to-quantify monetary relief, courts can develop a context-sensitive yet coherent approach that … deploys both [monetary-relief] measures and burdens of proof or production in ways that distinguish between levels of relative responsibility or fault.”).

175 See Golden Reference Golden2017, 271 (discussing treatments of doubts and blameworthiness in the First and Second Restatements of Contracts); Golden & Sandrik Reference Golden and Sandrik2017 (discussing how the Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment assigns evidentiary burdens in accordance with “‘the equitable disposition that resolves uncertainty in favor of the claimant against the conscious wrongdoer’” (quoting Restatement (Third) of Restitution and Unjust Enrichment § 51 cmt. i)).

176 Golden Reference Golden2017, 272.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×