Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T00:37:59.414Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

16 - Market Anti-naturalisms

from Part II - Images of the Legal Contemporary?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 December 2017

Justin Desautels-Stein
Affiliation:
University of Colorado School of Law
Christopher Tomlins
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley School of Law
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Works Cited – Chapter 16

Boydston, Jo Ann (ed.) 1988. John Dewey. The Later Works, 1925–1953. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 2012 [1924]. The Legal Foundations of Capitalism. Clark, NJ: The Lawbook Exchange.Google Scholar
Deakin, Simon, Gindis, David, Hodgson, Geoffrey M, Kainan, Huang, and Pistor, Katharine 2017. “Legal institutionalism: capitalism and the constitutive role of law,” Journal of Comparative Economics 44: 188200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewey, John 1988 [1939]. “Theory of valuation” in Boydston, (ed.) pp. 189354.Google Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1923. “Coercion and distribution in a supposedly non-coercive state,” Political Science Quarterly 38: 470–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1935. “Force and the state: a comparison of ‘political’ and ‘economic’ compulsion,” Columbia Law Review 35: 149201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1943. “Bargaining, duress, and economic liberty,” Columbia Law Review 43: 603–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1952. Freedom Through Law. London: Geoffrey Cumberlege.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. 2006 [1960]. The Constitution of Liberty. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. 2013 [1976]. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 2: The Mirage of Social Justice. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1991. “The stakes of law, or Hale and Foucault!Legal Studies Forum 15: 327–65.Google Scholar
March, James G. 1982. “Theories of choice and making decisions,” Transaction/Society 21: 2939.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 1998. “Wandering the road form pluralism to Posner: the transformation of law and economics in the twentieth century,” The Transformation of American Economics: From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism: History of Political Economy Annual Supplement 30: 202–24.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. and Mercuro, Nicholas 2006. Economics and the Law: From Posner to Post Modernism and Beyond, 2nd edition. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Newman, Peter (ed.) 1998 The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
North, Douglas C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. St. Louis: Washington University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglas C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pistor, Katharina 2013. “A legal theory of finance,” Journal of Comparative Economics 41: 315–30.Google Scholar
Polanyí, Karl 1957 [1944]. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 2014. Economic Analysis of Law (9th ed.). New York: Wolters Kluwer Law and Business.Google Scholar
Samuels, Warren J. 2007. The Legal-Economic Nexus. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Vanberg, Viktor J. 1998. “Freiburg school of law and economics,” in Newman, (ed.) Volume 2 pp. 172–9.Google Scholar
Vanberg, Viktor J. 2001. The Constitution of Markets Essays in Political Economy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Vanberg, Viktor J. 2011. “Liberal constitutionalism, constitutional liberalism and democracy,” Constitutional Political Economy 22: 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×