We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
We present a modified version of the well-known geometric Lorenz attractor. It consists of a $C^1$ open set ${\mathcal O}$ of vector fields in ${\mathbb R}^3$ having an attracting region ${\mathcal U}$ satisfying three properties. Namely, a unique singularity $\sigma $; a unique attractor $\Lambda $ including the singular point and the maximal invariant in ${\mathcal U}$ has at most two chain recurrence classes, which are $\Lambda $ and (at most) one hyperbolic horseshoe. The horseshoe and the singular attractor have a collision along with the union of $2$ codimension $1$ submanifolds which split ${\mathcal O}$ into three regions. By crossing this collision locus, the attractor and the horseshoe may merge into a two-sided Lorenz attractor, or they may exchange their nature: the Lorenz attractor expels the singular point $\sigma $ and becomes a horseshoe, and the horseshoe absorbs $\sigma $ becoming a Lorenz attractor.
A dynamical system is a mechanical, electrical, chemical, or biological system that evolves in time.Dynamical systems theory provides one of the most powerful and pervasive applications of matrix methods in science and engineering.These qualitative and quantitative tools and methods allow for the determination and characterization of the number and types of solutions, including their stability, of complex, often nonlinear, systems.These methods include phase-plane analysis, bifurcation diagrams, stability theory, Poincare diagrams illustrated using linear and nonlinear physical examples, including the Duffing equation and the Saltzman-Lorenz model.
We consider a certain two-parameter family of automorphisms of the affine plane over a complete, locally compact non-Archimedean field. Each of these automorphisms admits a chaotic attractor on which it is topologically conjugate to a full two-sided shift map, and the attractor supports a unit Borel measure which describes the distribution of the forward orbit of Haar-almost all points in the basin of attraction. We also compute the Hausdorff dimension of the attractor, which is non-integral.
We study dynamics and bifurcations of three-dimensional diffeomorphisms with nontransversal heteroclinic cycles. We show that bifurcations under consideration lead to the birth of Lorenz-like attractors. They can be viewed as attractors in the Poincare map for periodically perturbed classical Lorenz attractors and hence they can allow for the existence of homoclinic tangencies and wild hyperbolic sets.
Economic theory indicates the need for nonlinear structural
models to study medium-term and long-run dynamic behavior of an
economy. This paper argues that economic systems can be better
specified and estimated using differential-equation rather than
difference-equation systems and briefly reviews the estimators of
continuous models. This approach of specifying structural models on
the basis of economic theory and institutional structure explicitly
and then testing the underlying hypothesis to verify the structural
form is contrasted with a general-to-specific approach of
successively more restricted VARMAX processes. Previous analyses of
stability about the steady state or fixed point in phase
space are extended to more general attractors to allow
an investigation of complexity in economic
systems. The critical dependence of some attractors, and
particularly strange attractors, on parameter values
emphasizes the need for consistent, efficient
estimation. A structural approach
provides a rigorous alternative to using single time series to
determine whether economic systems exhibit aperiodic or chaotic
dynamical behavior.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.