Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-q99xh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T14:13:05.507Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Timing is everything: Evaluating behavioural causal theories of Britain's industrialisation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 November 2019

Judy Z. Stephenson*
Affiliation:
Bartlett School, University College London, London WC1H 0QB, United Kingdom. j.stephenson@ucl.ac.uk

Abstract

Baumard's thesis that the English Industrial Revolution can be explained by Life History Theory's predictions for psychological development is a progression of much literature in economic and social history. However, the theory suffers from its reliance on increasingly fragile data indicators for “wealth” and its focus on “innovation” as new research begins to explore sectoral dynamics in long run growth.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Allen, R. C. (2009b) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cannadine, D. (1984) The present and the past in the English Industrial Revolution 1880–1980. Past and Present (103):131–72.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. (2010) Explaining the first industrial revolution: Two views. CAGE Online Working Paper Series, No.10/2010. Available at: http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/44710/1/WRAP_Carfts_10.2010_craftsindustrial.pdf.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. & Mills, T. C. (2017) Six centuries of British economic growth: A time-series perspective. European Review of Economic History 21:141–58.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (2008) The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hewitt, R. (2017) A revolution of feeling: The decade that forged the modern mind. Granta BooksGoogle Scholar
Humphries, J. & Schneider, B. (2019) Spinning the Industrial Revolution. The Economic History Review 72(1):126–55.Google Scholar
López Losa, E. (2016) Spanish real wages in the northern-western European mirror, 1500–1800. On the timings and magnitude of the Little Divergence in Europe. Asociacion Espã nola de Historia Economica Working Paper, No. 1607.Google Scholar
Mocarelli, L. (2019) What is wrong with the history of wages: Or the divide in economic history—A reappraisal suggested by eighteenth-century Milan. In: Seven centuries of unreal wages, ed. Hatcher, J. & Stephenson, J., pp. 95116. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1996) Economics and cognitive science. IDEAS working papers.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. (2014) Capital, trans. Goldhammer, A.. Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Reddy, W. (2001) The navigation of feeling: A framework for the history of emotions. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stephenson, J. Z. (2018) Looking for work? Or looking for workers? Days and hours of work in London construction in the eighteenth century (January 22, 2018). Available at: SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3128189 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3128189.Google Scholar
Stephenson, J. Z. (2019) The pay of labourers and unskilled men in London 1660–1770. forthcoming in: Seven centuries of unreal wages (2019), ed. Hatcher, J. & Stephenson, J. Z.. Palgrave.Google Scholar
Styles, J. (2016) Fashion, textiles and the origins of Industrial Revolution. East Asian Journal of British History 5:161–90.Google Scholar