No CrossRef data available.
Article contents
What came first, the chicken or the egg?
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 20 November 2019
Abstract
Current empirical evidence does not seem to confirm that an improvement in living conditions is the cause of the shift in the human mindset toward innovation and long-term risky investment. However, it may well be one of the conditions for greater tolerance of income inequality in exchange for a steady increase in average income.
- Type
- Open Peer Commentary
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019
References
Broadberry, S., Campbell, B. M. S., Klein, A., Overton, M. & van Leeuwen, B. (2015) British economic growth, 1270–1870. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2007) A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (2012) Review essay: The enlightened economy. An economic history of Britain, 1700–1850 by Joel Mokyr. Journal of Economic Literature 50(1):85–95.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (2008) The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Goldstone, J. A. (2015) The great and little divergence: Where lies the true onset of modern economic growth? George Mason University and Woodrow Wilson Center, working paper, Center for Global Policy.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2007) The world economy: Vol. 1: A millennial perspective, Vol. 2: Historical statistics. Academic Foundation.Google Scholar
Meisenzahl, R. R. & Mokyr, J. (2012) The rate and direction of invention in the British industrial revolution: Incentives and institutions. In: The rate and direction of inventive activity revisited, ed. Lerner, J. & Stern, S., pp. 443–79. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (1999) Editor's introduction: The new economic history and the Industrial Revolution. In: The British Industrial Revolution: An economic perspective, second ed., ed. Mokyr, J., pp. 1–127. Westview.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. (2016) A culture of growth: The origins of the modern economy. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. E. (1990) Institutions, institutional change and public performance. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. (2008) The long road to the Industrial Revolution. The European economy in a global perspective, 1000–1800. Brill.Google Scholar
Wootton, D. (2015) The invention of science. A new history of the scientific revolution. Allen Lane/Penguin.Google Scholar
Wootton, D. (2018) Power, pleasure and profit: Insatiable appetites from Machiavelli to Madison. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Target article
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution
Related commentaries (24)
A claim for cognitive history
A needed amendment that explains too much and resolves little
Affluence boosted intelligence? How the interaction between cognition and environment may have produced an eighteenth-century Flynn effect during the Industrial Revolution
Are both necessity and opportunity the mothers of innovations?
Cultural interconnectedness and in-group cooperation as sources of innovation
Energy, transport, and consumption in the Industrial Revolution
England first, America second: The ecological predictors of life history and innovation
Environmental unpredictability, economic inequality, and dynamic nature of life history before, during, and after the Industrial Revolution
Explaining historical change in terms of LHT: A pluralistic causal framework is needed
Interrelationships of factors of social development are more complex than Life History Theory predicts
Life History Theory and economic modernity
Life History Theory and the Industrial Revolution
Many causes, not one
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution: Why we need causal methods and historians
Psychology and the economics of invention
Slowing life history (K) can account for increasing micro-innovation rates and GDP growth, but not macro-innovation rates, which declined following the end of the Industrial Revolution
The affective origins of the Industrial Revolution
The other angle of Maslow's pyramid: How scarce environments trigger low-opportunity-cost innovations
The wealth→life history→innovation account of the Industrial Revolution is largely inconsistent with empirical time series data
There is little evidence that the Industrial Revolution was caused by a preference shift
Timing is everything: Evaluating behavioural causal theories of Britain's industrialisation
Using big data to map the relationship between time perspectives and economic outputs
What came first, the chicken or the egg?
What motivated the Industrial Revolution: England's libertarian culture or affluence per se?
Author response
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution: More work is needed!