We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Edited by
Seth Davis, University of California, Berkeley School of Law,Thilo Kuntz, Heinrich-Heine-Universität Düsseldorf,Gregory Shaffer, Georgetown University Law Center, Washington DC
This chapter explores the intersection of transnational law with contemporary corporate governance laws and principles. Corporate governance, with its complex array of public and private actors, fits naturally within the modern concept of transnational law as a species of law that "can no longer be viewed through a purely national lens." Financial markets today are global and interconnected and events, such as the 2007-2009 global financial crisis and the COVID-19 crisis, exemplify the risk of contagion across those markets. Not only can corporate governance problems transcend national boundaries, so too can their solutions, which often involve regulatory efforts that operate at a transnational level. The chapter explores, from a transnational perspective, the transmission of laws and norms that are designed to constrain directors’ conduct and enhance corporate accountability. It focuses on two key examples of such accountability mechanisms-fiduciary duties and corporate codes. The chapter examines, for example, the global transmission of corporate governance and shareholder stewardship codes. These codes, which are a relatively recent phenomenon, play an important role as “norm creators.” The chapter assesses the transmission of laws and norms against the backdrop of convergence and path dependence theories of corporate governance.
The take-up of mandatory human rights due diligence (HRDD) initiatives by states is continuously gaining momentum. There are now numerous states adopting some form of HRDD laws. While corporations being duly diligent in respecting human rights is a positive step towards addressing problems of business and human rights, these HRDD initiatives on their own may only be a form of window-dressing, that is, enabling states to put a smart spin on their efforts to address business and human rights issues without addressing some of the root causes of that predicament. As a result, HRDD laws are likely to be a helpful, but insufficient tool for addressing corporate abuse of human rights. One reason for this is because the root cause of many business and human rights problems is the structural elements and goals of corporate law facilitates corporate violations of human rights. So long as states fail to transform the way in which corporations operate – in part, by reconceptualizing corporate law – even the best drafted HRDD laws will be inadequate to halt corporate harms.
The chapter argues that socially responsible investment (SRI) can be linked to long-term financial success and therefore should be part of the corporate social responsibility (CSR) strategy of investors. It shows how capital providers, including ordinary shareholders, institutional investors and socially responsible investors, can provide the stimulus for improvements in CSR standards and performance. The chapter traces the origins of SRI and investigates the range of powers and responsibilities, procedures and opportunities that can be applied to encourage a greater degree of participation of different kinds of investor, particularly institutional investors, in SRI.
Increasing regulatory oversight to control shareholders is bound to underperform. This is because it rests on an invalid assumption, namely that shareholders are better controlled and better steered when regulatory stringency is increased. The assumption runs counter to the conditions that a regulation must require of shareholders, owing to those conditional requirements being unevenly matched by shareholders. Specifically, since shareholders vary in what is required of them by a regulation, the increase of regulatory oversight necessitates that some shareholders will fail to respond, some will comply with what is required, and others will do more. Increasing regulatory oversight does not therefore address the fundamental problem of there being pre-existing deficiencies in stakeholder capacities to comply. To better address the problem, a minmax approach to regulation is proposed. The main benefit of minmax is that it aligns itself to shareholder differences, helping to reduce non-compliance while simultaneously encouraging beyond-compliance behaviour.
This chapter argues that beneficiaries of social enterprises should be given decision-making powers. I examine two problems with restricting the decision-making powers to shareholders, that is, shareholders can exercise the governance rights to benefit themselves but at the expense of the constituencies that the social enterprise is set up to benefit; and it is odd for a social enterprise to claim that it seeks to pursue social welfare and to promote public benefit, and yet its beneficiaries have absolutely no say in how the social enterprise is being run. I then analyze three objections in giving beneficiaries decision-making powers, that is, it will be disruptive and inefficient; beneficiaries can act opportunistically; and only shareholders have the incentive and ability to monitor. Finally, I assess five different decision-making mechanisms, that is, beneficiary advisory panel; director appointed from the beneficiary advisory panel; appointing independent nonexecutive directors; beneficiaries as shareholders; appointing a regulator and public enforcement.
This article examines the infusion of information communication technology (ICT) into Nigeria's new company legislation to promote corporate democracy. While the initiative is laudable, especially in the age of the COVID-19 pandemic, the article argues that the reform is of limited value, as only private companies are empowered to deploy ICT in the conduct of general meetings. By excluding public companies, the article argues, inter alia, that the reform overlooks the role that ICT could play in addressing the assumed passivity of latent, large groups, which typify the shareholders of public companies. In making a case for inclusive reform, the article examines the reforms already undertaken by some countries in the common law jurisdictions, whose templates on the subject may inform the changes Nigeria needs to effect in her law.
The aim of the article is to analyse the functions that dividends perform in contractual relationships between public companies’ executives and shareholders. The author analyses the income function of dividend, but also considers its sociological aspects. Talcott Parsons' social system theory is the main point of reference, especially, the concept of contract institution. The article justifies the thesis on the relevance of dividends in shaping the equilibrium of power, information policy and the composition of shareholders in a joint-stock company. Dividend policy has a great regulatory potential, which is important in the face of various crises occurring in contemporary capitalism.
During the last decade, discussion on shareholder activism concentrated on hedge funds, some seeing them as agents for passive institutional shareholders, bridging the separation of ownership and control, others believing their short-term value-maximization interests differing fundamentally from those of other shareholders. Some have seen hopes for long-term activism in institutional shareholders such as pension funds. In the European Union, activism is seen positively, encouraging proposals to enhance shareholders’ rights against the boards’ discretion. The purpose of this chapter is to focus on institutional investor activism and its impact on both their ultimate beneficiaries and their target companies, and how investors could be incentivised to more sustainable behaviour in their activism. Albeit the focus is on the European Union, institutional investors are global. A broader perspective including North America and Asia is therefore taken. The most important impact of institutional activism is arguably normative, causing changes in corporate governance. Specific attention is therefore given to governance questions.
The current business context of disruptive, accelerated change requires a new framework for understanding how boards of directors can best support their organizations. In this book, Professor Jordi Canals presents a new model of effective governance, positioning the board of directors as the steward of the firm's future development, and focusing on the notion of corporate purpose. Canals argues that boards of directors should focus on strategy and corporate transformation, CEO and senior management development and succession, the board and the firm's culture, the board as a team, the engagement of shareholders and critical stakeholders, and the firm's overall impact. Moreover, for boards to be effective, directors must develop new competencies. Drawing on well-grounded theory and international case studies, this book outlines a new, holistic model of boards of directors, offering a pathway to effective governance that will enhance companies' reputation and success.
In Chapter 8, the spotlight is shareholder and stakeholder engagement. Boards that govern for the long term should actively engage shareholders – or oversee the interaction with them – learn from their suggestions and assure that the company has an adequate shareholder structure to carry out its activities and purpose. Boards should also understand how key stakeholders interact and create joint-value with the company, and how it can learn from them. Among the board’s responsibilities is to ensure the company has the right type of shareholders to pursue its purpose. A major assumption in many corporate governance studies is that shareholders are homogeneous and have the same preferences. The evidence indicates the contrary: Shareholders are heterogeneous. There is a wide variety of shareholders: family offices, pension funds, passive investors, private equity firm, hedge funds or governments, among others. Each shareholder is unique, with distinct time horizons and motivations. The board of directors needs to consider this diversity.
Clear understanding of artificial intelligence (AI) usage risks and how they are being addressed is needed, which requires proper and adequate corporate disclosure. We advance a legal framework for AI Fairness Reporting to which companies can and should adhere on a comply-or-explain basis. We analyse the sources of unfairness arising from different aspects of AI models and the disparities in the performance of machine learning systems. We evaluate how the machine learning literature has sought to address the problem of unfairness through the use of different fairness metrics. We then put forward a nuanced and viable framework for AI Fairness Reporting comprising: (1) disclosure of all machine learning models usage; (2) disclosure of fairness metrics used and the ensuing trade-offs; (3) disclosure of de-biasing methods used; and (d) release of datasets for public inspection or for third-party audit. We then apply this reporting framework to two case studies.
Research into the organization of the firm typically contrasts family businesses with impersonal corporate structures, and kinship ties among corporate elites are often associated with inefficiency and corruption. This analysis of over 14,000 equity investors and executive officers finds that familial networks were embedded in early corporations, not just among directors but also among small shareholders in the firm. Related investing was especially prominent among women and other relatively disadvantaged groups. Personal ties in newer, riskier enterprises encouraged capital mobilization in emerging ventures and persistence in shareholding, and related investing was significantly associated with lower risk of corporate bank failures. The results support a more positive view of family networks in business organizations and in overall economic development.
The authors analyze corporate governance and competition sanctions. Despite their extensive powers, shareholders cannot (legally) interfere directly in the management of a company. It is hard to imagine that any competition law infringements attributed to the company could happen without the knowledge, or even more the active participation, of its directors or other executives. Consequently, if a competition law fine or other sanction is applied on the company, directors appear to be particularly well placed to be sued for compensation for this harm caused in their management activity. On the other hand, shareholders are the main beneficiaries of successfully completed cartels, i.e. those which remain undetected by competition authorities. The chapter investigates whether the financial burden of infringement sanctions should be borne by the company as the main potential beneficiary of excess profits, or should be fully, or at least partially, transferred to the directors who effectively committed or overlooked the breaches. Clarifications are gained from the study of managerial liability in the context of competition law infringements, followed by a deeper analysis of the consequences of the damages suffered by the company in the form of competition law fines or compensations paid as a result of private enforcement
Business history and theory reflect a tension between public and private conceptions of the corporation. This is embodied in the famous Berle-Dodd debate, which provides the basis for contemporary clashes between “different visions of corporatism,” such as the conflict between shareholder primacy and stakeholder-centered versions of the corporation. This chapter examines a number of recent developments suggesting that the pendulum, which swung so clearly in favour of a private conception of the corporation from the 1980s onwards, is in the process of changing direction. The chapter provides two central insights. The first is that there is not one problem, but multiple problems in corporate law, and that different problems may come to the forefront at different times. The second insight is that corporate governance techniques (such as performance-based pay), which are designed to ameliorate one problem in corporate law, such as corporate performance, can at the same time exacerbate other problems involving the social impact of corporations.
This chapter explains that a central feature of private equity governance mechanisms is a system designed to improve decision-making. Through an explanation of the typical structures seen in practice, it considers the main ways in which better decision-making is facilitated. These structures – most importantly, the board of directors of the company – differ according to the size, type and stage of development of the company, as well as the skills and expertise of the relevant stakeholders. This chapter also looks at the ways in which private equity firms seek to protect their own interests, as distinct from those of the underlying company. That question is examined from a number of perspectives, including the need for a private equity investor to sell the company within a defined time frame, and its need to protect its own reputation with a wide variety of stakeholders. Building on this analysis, and connecting in particular with the various objectives of private equity firms, this chapter considers how, if at all, private equity firms design governance mechanisms with a view to protecting external stakeholders.
The recognition of the profound impact of corporations on the economies and societies of all countries of the world has focused attention on the growing importance of corporate governance. There is an ongoing diversity of corporate governance systems, based on historical cultural and institutional differences that involve different approaches to the values and objectives of business activity. Sound corporate governance is universally recognised as essential to market integrity and efficiency, providing a vital underpinning for financial stability and economic growth. As the adequacy of the existing dominant paradigms of corporate governance are increasingly challenged, the search for coherent new paradigms is a vital task for corporate governance in the future.
I argue that none of the current explanations of why shareholders should be given voting powers are persuasive. I then explain the exercise of informal power through the exertion of influence.
I argue that none of the current explanations of why shareholders should be given voting powers are persuasive. I then explain the exercise of informal power through the exertion of influence.