Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-5b777bbd6c-ks5gx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-06-25T16:11:17.360Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Evolutionary Price Theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2025

Harry Bloch
Affiliation:
Curtin University

Summary

Economic evolution involves structural change from within, so evolutionary price theory needs to address how prices facilitate and accommodate this structural change and how structural change in turn impacts on prices. Such analysis is impossible using neoclassical price theory in which endowments of inputs, production technology and consumer preferences are all treated as exogenously determined and the future is known or at least its probability distribution is known. An alternative theory of price determination outlined in this book is compatible with structural change from within and an unknown future. The theory employs an open-system ontology and a micro-meso-macro methodology. Prices have a dual informational role in evolutionary economics. As well as coordinating ongoing production and consumption activities, prices provide information to guide potential entrepreneurs and their financiers in evaluating the profitability of innovations. The latter role can substantially disrupt the order created in the former role.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781009669184
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 08 May 2025

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Element purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Acs, Zoltan J. and Audretsch, David B. (1988), ‘Innovation in large and small firms: An empirical analysis’, American Economic Review, 78(4): 678690.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen (1950), ‘Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory’, Journal of Political Economy, 58(3): 211221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almudi, Isabel and Fatas-Villafranca, Francisco (2021), Coevolution in Economic Systems, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almudi, Isabel, Fatas-Villafranca, Francisco, Palacio, Jesus and Sanchez-Choliz, Julio (2020), ‘Pricing routines and industrial dynamics’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 30(3): 705739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, Esben S. (2012), ‘Schumpeter’s core works revisited – resolved problems and remaining challenges’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 22(4): 627648.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth (1974), The Limits of Organization, New York, Norton.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian (2015), Complexity and the Economy, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Asimakopoulos, Anthony (1975), ‘A Kaleckian theory of income distribution’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 8(3): 313333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aspromourgos, Tony, Mori, Kenji, Morioka, Masashi. et al. (2022), ‘Symposium on Yoshinori Shiozawa, Masashi Morioka and Taniguchi, Kazuhisa (2019), Microfoundations of Evolutionary Economics, Springer, Tokyo: Japan’, Metroeconomica, 73: 248.Google Scholar
Bain, Joe S. (1956), Barriers to New Competition, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnard, Chester I. ([1938] 1966), The Functions of the Executive, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Barney, Jay, (1991), ‘Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage’, Journal of Management, 17, 99120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. (1958), ‘On the theory of oligopoly’, Economica, 25, 187198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J., Panzar, John C. and Willig, Robert D. (1982), Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure, New York, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Berle, Adolf A. and Means, Gardiner C. (1932), The Modern Corporation and Private Property, New York, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry (1981), ‘Determinants of the variance of market shares in Canadian manufacturing’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 29(4): 385393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (1990), ‘Price leadership and the degree of monopoly’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 12(3): 439451.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2000), ‘Schumpeter and Steindl on the dynamics of competition’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(3): 343353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2005), ‘Steindl’s analysis of firm growth and the tendency toward industry concentration’, in Mott, Tracy and Shapiro, Nina, editors, Rethinking Capitalist Development: Essays on the Economics of Joseph Steindl, London, Routledge: 2336.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2016a), ‘Prices in motion: Schumpeter’s contribution to price theory’, Metroeconomica, 67(4): 742767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2016b), ‘Post Keynesian price theory with a Schumpeterian twist’, in Courvisanos, Jerry, Doughney, James and Millmow, Alex, editors, Reclaiming Pluralism for Economics, London, Routledge: 203220.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2018a), Schumpeter’s Price Theory, London, Routledge.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2018b), ‘Neo-Schumpeterian price theory with Sraffian and post-Keynesian elements’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 28(5): 10351051.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2018c), ‘Innovation and industry evolution’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 25(1): 7383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2020), ‘Price theory historically considered: Smith, Ricardo, Marshall and beyond’, History of Economics Review, 75: 5073.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry (2022), ‘The language of pluralism from the history of the theory of price determination: Natural price, equilibrium price and administered price’, Metroeconomica, 73(4): 10941111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Finch, John (2010), ‘Firms and industries in evolutionary economics: Lessons from Marshall, Young, Steindl and Penrose’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(1): 139162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Kriesler, Peter (2023), ‘Revisiting “Pricing and the investment decision”’, Review of Political Economy, published online 12 December 2023, http://doi.org/10.1080/09538259.2023.2283750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Metcalfe, Stan (2011), ‘Complexity in the theory of the developing firm’, in Antonelli, Cristiano, editor, Handbook on the Economic Complexity of Technological Change, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar: 81104.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Metcalfe, Stan (2015), ‘Restless knowledge, capabilities and the nature of the mega-firm’, in Pyka, Andreas and Foster, John, editors, The Evolution of Economic and Innovation Systems, Heidelberg, Springer: 431453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Metcalfe, Stan (2018), ‘Innovation, creative destruction and price theory’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 27(1): 113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Metcalfe, Stan (2024), ‘Price theory in a complex and evolving economy’, in Chen, Ping, Elsner, Wolfram, Pyka, Andreas, editors, Handbook of Complexity Economics, London, Routledge: 292304.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Sapsford, David (2004), ‘Commodity prices, wages and U.S. inflation in the twentieth century’, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 26(3): 523545.Google Scholar
Bloch, Harry and Sapsford, David (2013), ‘Innovation, real primary commodity prices and business cycles’, in Andersen, Esben and Pyka, Andreas, editors, Long Term Economic Development – Demand, Finance, Organization, Policy and Innovation in a Schumpeterian Perspective, Berlin, Springer: 175189.Google Scholar
Callegari, Beniamio (2018), ‘The finance/innovation nexus in Schumpeterian analysis: Theory and application in the case of U.S. trustified capitalism’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 28(5): 11751198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chai, Andreas and Babutsidze, Zakaria (2024), ‘Evolutionary consumer theory’, in Dopfer, Kurt, Nelson, Richard R., Potts, Jason and Pyka, Andreas, editors, Routledge Handbook of Evolutionary Economics, London, Routledge: 261283.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred (1962), Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of Industrial Enterprise, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, Alfred (1977), The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chatterjee, Rabikar (2009). ‘Strategic pricing of new products and services’, in Vithala, R. Rao, editor, Handbook of Pricing Research in Marketing, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar: 169215.Google Scholar
Coad, Alex (2009), The Growth of Firms: A Survey of Theories and Empirical Evidence, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1937), ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica, 4: 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1988), ‘The nature of the firm: influence’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 4: 3347Google Scholar
Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G. (1963), Behavioral Theory of the Firm, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Dean, Joel (1969), ‘Pricing pioneering products’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 17(3): 165179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dopfer, Kurt (2001), ‘History-friendly theories in economics: Reconciling universality and context in evolutionary analysis’, in Foster, John and Metcalfe, J. Stanley, editors, Frontiers of Evolutionary Economics: Competition, Self-Organization and Innovation Policy, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar: 160187.Google Scholar
Dopfer, Kurt, Foster, John and Potts, Jason (2004), ‘Micro-meso-macro’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14(3): 263279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dopfer, Kurt and Potts, Jason (2008), The General Theory of Economic Evolution, London, Routledge.Google Scholar
Giovanni, Dosi, Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (2002), The Nature and Dynamics of Organizational Capabilities, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Downie, Jack (1958), The Competitive Process, London, Duckworth.Google Scholar
Downward, Paul (1999), Pricing Theory in Post Keynesian Economics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Duesenberry, James S. (1949), Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumption Behavior. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Earl, Peter (2022), Principles of Behavioural Economics: Bringing Together Old, New and Evolutionary Approaches, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Earl, Peter (2023), ‘Rules all the way down: Consumer behaviour from the standpoint of the “ONE behavioural” research programme’, Journal of Consumer Behavior, 22: 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eaton, B. Curtis and Lipsey, Richard G. (1980), ‘Exit barriers are entry barriers: The durability of capital as a barrier to entry’, Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2): 721729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichner, Alfred S. (1973), ‘A theory of the determination of the mark-up under oligopoly’, Economic Journal, 83: 11841200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichner, Alfred S. (1976), The Megacorp and Oligopoly, Armonk, M.E. Sharpe.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichner, Alfed S. (1985), Towards a New Economics: Essays in Post-Keynesian and Institutionalist Theory, Armonk, M.E. Sharpe.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eliasson, Gunnar (2024), ‘The firm as an experimental decision maker’, in Dopfer, Kurt, Nelson, Richard R., Potts, Jason and Pyka, Andreas, editors, Routledge Handbook of Evolutionary Economics, London, Routledge: 185196.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai (1938), ‘The cobweb theorem’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 52(2): 255280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, John (2000), ‘Competitive selection, self-organisation and Schumpeter’, Joseph A., Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 10(3): 311328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, John (2005), ‘From simplistic to complex systems in economics’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 29: 873892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foster, John (2021), The US consumption function: A new perspective’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 31(3): 773798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Christopher and Louçã, Francisco (2001), As Time Goes By – From the Industrial Revolutions to the Information Revolution, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gallegati, Marco (2019), ‘A system for dating long wave phases in economic development’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 29(3): 803822.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garegnani, Pierangelo (1990), ‘Sraffa: classical versus marginalist analysis’, in Bharadwaj, Krishna and Schefold, Bertram, editors, Essays on Piero Sraffa, London, Routledge: 112141.Google Scholar
Gustafsson, Robin, Jääskeläinen, Mikko, Mauls, Markku and Uotila, Juha (2016), ‘Emergence of industries: A review and future directions’, International Journal of Management Reviews, 18(1): 2850.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert L. and Hitch, Charles J. (1939), ‘Price theory and business behaviour’, Oxford Economic Papers, 2: 1245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harcourt, Geoffrey C. and Kenyon, Peter (1976), ‘Pricing and the investment decision’, Kyklos, 29(3): 449477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1935), Prices and Production, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1948), Individualism and Economic Order, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1997), ‘The ubiquity of habits and rules’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21: 663684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hunt, E. Kdward (1979), History of Economic Thought: A Critical Perspective, Belmont, CA, Wadsworth.Google Scholar
Innis, Harold A. (1940), ‘Review of Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of Capitalist Process by Joseph A. Schumpeter’, Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 6(1): 9096.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas (1934), ‘A classificatory note of the determinateness of equilibrium’, Review of Economic Studies, 1(2): 122136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas (1985), Economics without Equilibrium, Cardiff, University College Cardiff Press.Google Scholar
Kalecki, Michał (1937), ‘The principle of increasing risk’, Economica, 3, 440447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalecki, Michał (1971), Selected Essays on the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kay, John (2018), ‘Theories of the firm’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 25(1): 1117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John M. (1930), ‘Economics possibilities for our grandchildren’, The Nation and Anthenaeum, 48(2): 3637, 48(3): 9698. Reprinted in Keynes, John M. (1932), Essays in Economic Persuasion, New York, Harcourt Brace: 358373.Google Scholar
Kirman, Alan (2011), Complex Economics: Individual and Collective Rationality, London, Routledge.Google Scholar
Knell, Mark (2015), ‘Schumpeter, Keynes and the financial instability hypothesis’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 25(1): 293310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank H. ([1921] 1971), Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kondratieff, Nikolai D. (1935), ‘The long waves of economic life’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 17(6): 105115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kriesler, Peter (1987), Kalecki’s Microanalysis, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kurz, Heinz D. (2008), ‘Innovations and profits: Schumpeter and the classical heritage’, Journal of Economic and Behavioral Organization, 67(1): 263278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, Simon (1940), ‘Schumpeter’s Business Cycles’, American Economic Review, 30: 257271.Google Scholar
Lavoie, Marc (2022), Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, Frederic S. (1999), Post Keynesian Pricing Theory, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leontief, Wasily (1986), ‘Input-output analysis’, in Leontief, Wasily, editor, Input-Output Economics, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Levine, David P. (1997), ‘Knowing and acting: On uncertainty in economics’, Review of Political Economy, 9: 517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G., Carlaw, Kenneth I. and Bekar, Clifford T. (2005), Economic Transformations, Oxford, Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loasby, Brian J. (1999), Knowledge, Institutions and Evolution in Economics, London, Routledge.Google Scholar
Loasby, Brian J. (2003), ‘Efficiency and time’, in Arena, Richard and Quere, Michel, editors, The Economics of Alfred Marshall: Revisiting Marshall’s Legacy, London, Palgrave Macmillan: 202220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Louçã, Francisco (2021), ‘As time went by – why is the long wave so long?’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 31(3): 749771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malerba, Franco, Nelson, Richard R., Orsenigo, Luigi and Winter, Sydney G. (1999), ‘History-friendly models of industry evolution: The computer industry’, Industry and Corporate Change, 8(1): 34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, Thomas ([1798] 1991), An Essay on the Principle of Population, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Markey-Towler, Brendan (2016), ‘Law of the jungle: Firm survival and price dynamics in evolutionary markets’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26(3): 655696.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marris, Robin (1964), The Theory of Managerial Capitalism, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1920), Principles of Economics, 8th ed., London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred (1923), Industry and Trade, 4th ed., London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl ([1887] 1954), Capital, Volume 1, Moscow, Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Melmiès, Jordan (2023), ‘Unit profit margins along post-Keynesian lines: From Sraffa, Kalecki, Robinson to Eichner, Wood, Harcourt and Kenyon’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 30(1): 121. https://doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2022.2098998.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Metcalfe, J. Stanley (1998), Evolutionary Economics and Creative Destruction, London, Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Metcalfe, J. Stanley (2001), ‘Consumption, preferences and the evolutionary agenda’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(1): 3758.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Metcalfe, J. Stanley (2007), ‘Alfred Marshall’s Mecca: Reconciling the theories of value and development’, Economic Record, 83(supplement): S1S22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Metcalfe, J. Stanley (2008), ‘The broken thread: Marshall, Schumpeter and Hayek on the evolution of capitalism’, in Shinoya, Yuichi and Nishizawa, Tomatsu, editors, Marshall and Schumpeter on Evolution, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar: 116144.Google Scholar
Metcalfe, Stan (2025), ‘The innovation-competition connection’, in Dopfer, Kurt, editor, Elgar Research Agenda for Evolutionary Economics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Minsky, Hyman P. (1990), ‘Schumpeter: Finance and evolution’, in Heertje, Arnold and Perlman, Mark, editors, Evolving Technology and Market Structure, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press: 5174.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (1991), ‘Why do firms differ; and how does it matter’, Strategic Journal of Management, 12, 6174.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (2008), ‘Why do firms differ and how does it matter? A revisitation’, Seoul Journal of Economics, 21(4): 607619.Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (2013), ‘Demand, supply, and their interaction on markets, as seen from the perspective of evolutionary economic theory’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 23(1): 1738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (2020), ‘A perspective on the evolution of evolutionary economics’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 29(5): 11011118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. and Consoli, Davide (2010), ‘An evolutionary theory of household consumption behavior’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(3): 665687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Oakley, Allen (1990), Schumpeter’s Theory of Capitalist Motion: A Critical Exposition and Reassessment, Aldershot, Hants, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, Luigi (1977), Lectures in the Theory of Production, New York, Columbia University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pasinetti, Luigi L. (1981), Structural Change and Economic Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Penrose, Edith (1959), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Perez, Carlota (2002), Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, Edmund and Winter, Sidney (1970), ‘Optimal price policy under atomistic competition’, in Phelps, Edmund, editor, Micro Economic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory, New York, W. Norton: 309337.Google Scholar
Pigou, Alfred C. (1920), The Economics of Welfare, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Porter, Michael (1985), Competitive Advantage, Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, New York, Free Press.Google Scholar
Potts, Jason (2000), The New Evolutionary Microeconomics, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Potts, Jason (2001), ‘Knowledge and markets’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(4): 413431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Potts, Jason (2017), ‘Institutions hold consumption on a leash: An evolutionary approach to the future of consumption’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 27(2): 239250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ricardo, David ([1821] 1973), The Principles of Political Economy, London, Dent.Google Scholar
Robinson, Edward A. G. (1931), The Structure of Competitive Industry, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, Alessandro (1978), Sraffa and the Theory of Prices, Chichester, UK, John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Roncaglia, Alessandro (2006), The Wealth of Ideas: A History of Economic Thought, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Hans (1940), ‘Review of Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of Capitalist Process by Joseph A. Schumpeter’, American Historical Review, 46(1): 9699.Google Scholar
Salter, Wilfred E. G. (1966), Productivity and Technical Change, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. ([1934] 1961), The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle, translation of second German edition of Schumpeter (1926) by Redvers Opie, London, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1939), Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process, Volumes 1 and 2, New York, McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1947), ‘The creative response in economic history’, Journal of Economic History, 7(2): 149159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1949), ‘The historical approach to the analysis of business cycles’, Universities-National Bureau Conference on Business Cycle Research, November 25–27. Reprinted in Schumpeter (1951): 308315.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. ([1950] 1976), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 3rd ed., New York, Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1951), Essays of J.A. Schumpeter, edited by Richard, V. Clemence, Cambridge, MA, Addison-Wesley Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1954), History of Economic Analysis, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1970), Das Wesen des Geldes, edited by Mann, Fritz from a 1930 unpublished manuscript, Gottingen, Vandenhoeck and Ruprecht.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (2014), Treatise on Money, English translation by Reuben Alvarado of Schumpeter (1970), Aalten, Woodbridge.Google Scholar
Shackle, George L. S. (1959), ‘The complex nature of time as a concept in economics’, Economia Internazionale, 7(4): 743757.Google Scholar
Shackle, George L. S. (1970), Expectation, Enterprise and Profit, London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J. (2000), Irrational Exuberance, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Shiozawa, Yoshinori, Morioka, Masashi and Taniguchi, Kazuhisa (2019). Microfoundations of Evolutionary Economics, Tokyo, Springer Japan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1955), ‘A behavioural model of rational choice’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69: 99118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert (1964), ‘On the concept of an organizational goal’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 9: 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam ([1776] 1937), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, New York, Random House.Google Scholar
Sraffa, Piero (1960), Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Steindl, Josef (1945), Small and Big Business: Economic Problems of the Size of Firms, Oxford, Blackwell.Google Scholar
Steindl, Josef (1976), Maturity and Stagnation in American Capitalism, 2nd ed., New York, Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Sutton, John (1991), Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising, and the Evolution of Concentration, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sutton, John (1998), Technology and Market Structure: Theory and History, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Sylos-Labini, Paolo (1962), Oligopoly and Technical Progress, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sylos-Labini, Paolo (1984), The Forces of Economic Growth and Decline, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Syverson, Chad (2011), ‘What determines productivity?Journal of Economic Literature, 49(2): 326365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, Frederick W. (1911), The Principles of Scientific Management, New York, Harper and Brothers.Google Scholar
Teece, David (2009), Dynamic Capabilities and Strategic Management, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Teece, David (2024), ‘Evolutionary economics, routines and dynamic capabilities’, in Dopfer, Kurt, Nelson, Richard R., Potts, Jason and Pyka, Andreas, editors, Routledge Handbook of Evolutionary Economics, London, Routledge: 197214.Google Scholar
Tylecote, Andrew (1992), The Long Wave in the World Economy, London, Routledge.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorsten (1899), The Theory of the Leisure Class: an Economic Study of Institutions, London, Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wang, Yangyuzi (2024), ‘Stability of price and quantity to a long-run equilibrium: A dynamic Leontief model with bounded rationality’, Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, published online 26 April 2024, https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-024-00282-2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, Sidney (2006), ‘Toward a neo-Schumpeterian theory of the firm’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 15: 125141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich (2001), ‘Learning to consume – a theory of wants and the growth of demand’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 11(1): 2336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, Adrian (1975), A Theory of Profits, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ziman, John (1978), Reliable Knowledge: An Exploration of the Grounds for Scientific Belief, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Evolutionary Price Theory
  • Harry Bloch, Curtin University
  • Online ISBN: 9781009669184
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Evolutionary Price Theory
  • Harry Bloch, Curtin University
  • Online ISBN: 9781009669184
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Evolutionary Price Theory
  • Harry Bloch, Curtin University
  • Online ISBN: 9781009669184
Available formats
×