Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T11:06:14.743Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Information: price and impact on general welfare and optimal investment. an anticipative stochastic differential game model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 July 2016

Christian-Oliver Ewald*
Affiliation:
University of Sydney
Yajun Xiao*
Affiliation:
University of Freiburg
*
Postal address: School of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Sydney, Sydney, NSW 2006, Australia. Email address: christian.ewald@sydney.edu.au
∗∗ Postal address: Institute for Research in Economic Evolution, University of Freiburg, Platz der Alten Synagoge, KGII 79098 Freiburg i. Br., Germany.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Within an anticipative stochastic calculus framework, we study a market game with asymmetric information and feedback effects. We derive necessary and sufficient criteria for the existence of Nash equilibria and study how general welfare is affected by the level of information. In particular, we show that, under certain conditions in a competitive environment, an increased level of information may in fact lower the level of general welfare, leading to the so-called Hirshleifer effect (see Hirshleifer (1971)). Finally, we determine equilibrium prices for particular pieces of information, by extending our market game with a pre-stage, in which information is traded.

Type
General Applied Probability
Copyright
Copyright © Applied Probability Trust 2011 

References

Biagini, F. and Øksendal, B. (2005). A general stochastic calculus approach to insider trading. Appl. Math. Optimization 52, 167181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corcuera, J. M., Imkeller, P., Kohatsu-Higa, A. and Nualart, D. (2004). Additional utility of insiders with imperfect dynamical information. Finance Stoch. 8, 437450.Google Scholar
Ewald, C.-O. (2005). Optimal logarithmic utility and optimal portfolios for an insider in a stochastic volatility market. Internat. J. Theoret. Appl. Finance 8, 301319.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1971). The private and social value of information and the reward of inventive activity. Amer. Econom. Rev. 61, 561574.Google Scholar
Imkeller, P. (2003). Malliavin's calculus in insiders models: additional utility and free lunches. Math. Finance 13, 153169.Google Scholar
Jacod, J. (1985). Groissement initial, hypothese (H'), et théorème de Girsanov. In Groississements des Filtrations: Exemples et Applications (Lecture Notes Math. 118), eds Jeulin, T. and Yor, M., Springer, Berlin, pp. 1535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karatzas, I. and Shreve, S.E. (1988). Brownian Motion and Stochastic Calculus. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
Kohatsu-Higa, A. and Sulem, A. (2006). Utility maximization in an insider influenced market. Math. Finance 16, 153179.Google Scholar
León, J. A., Navarro, R. and Nualart, D. (2003). An anticipating calculus approach to the utility maximization of an insider. Math. Finance 13, 171185.Google Scholar
Nualart, D. (1995). The Malliavin Calculus and Related Topics. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
Øksendal, B. (2006). A universal optimal consumption rate for an insider. Math. Finance 16, 119129.Google Scholar
Pikovsky, I. and Karatzas, I. (1996). Anticipative portfolio optimization. Adv. Appl. Prob. 28, 10951122.Google Scholar
Russo, F. and Vallois, P. (1993). Forward, backward and symmetric stochastic integration. Prob. Theory Relat. Fields 97, 403421.Google Scholar
Russo, F. and Vallois, P. (2000). Stochastic calculus with respect to continuous finite quadratic variation processes. Stoch. Stoch. Reports 70, 140.Google Scholar