Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T22:03:37.157Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Control of Nonpoint Source Pollution Through Voluntary Incentive-Based Policies: An Application to Nitrate Contamination in New York

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2016

Jeffrey M. Peterson
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics at Kansas State University
Richard N. Boisvert
Affiliation:
Department of Applied Economics and Management at Cornell University
Get access

Abstract

A voluntary program is developed to achieve environmental goals through the self-interested choices of farmers under environmental risk and asymmetric information. Farmers behave to maximize expected net returns, and environmental quality standards are formulated through chance constraints. Because the government may not know each farmer's soil type, policy options must be self-selecting. The model is applied empirically to nitrate leaching and runoff from corn production in three New York regions. Asymmetric information between producers and the government would impose additional cost burdens on society, but these costs are modest in the context of other farm programs.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 2001 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Baumol, W.J. and Oates, W.E. 1988. The Theory of Environmental Policy, Second Edition. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boisvert, R., Regmi, A. and Schmit, T. 1997. “Policy Implications of Ranking Distributions of Nitrate Runoff and Leaching from Corn Production by Region and Soil Productivity.” Journal of Production Agriculture 10(3): 477483.Google Scholar
Braden, J.B., Larson, R.S. and Herricks, E. 1991. “Impact Targets versus Discharge Standards in Agricultural Pollution Management.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(2): 388397.Google Scholar
Carpentier, C.L., Bosch, D.J. and Batie, S.S. 1998. “Using Spatial Information to Reduce Costs of Controlling Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution.” Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 27(1): 7284.Google Scholar
Collender, R.N. and Chalfant, J.A. 1986. “An Alternative Approach to Decisions Under Uncertainty using the Empirical Moment Generating Function.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68(3): 727738.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crutchfield, S.R., Ribaudo, M.O., Hanson, L.T. and Quiroga, R. 1992. “Cotton Production and Water Quality: Economic and Environmental Effects of Pollution Prevention.” Resources and Technology Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Economic Report Number 664.Google Scholar
Helfand, G.E. and House, B.W. 1995. “Regulating Nonpoint Source Pollution under Heterogeneous Conditions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77(4): 10241032.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, S.C., Adams, R.M. and Perry, G.M. 1991. “The On-Farm Costs of Reducing Groundwater Pollution.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73(4): 10631073.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelleher, M. and Bills, N. 1989. “Statistical Summary of the 1987 Farm Management and Energy Survey,” A.E. Res. 89–03, Department of Agricultural Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
Lee, D.R. and Helmberger, P.G. 1985. “Estimating Supply Response in the Presence of Farm Programs.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67(2): 193203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichtenberg, E. and Zilberman, D. 1988. “Efficient Regulation of Environmental Health Risks.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 103(1): 167178.Google Scholar
Mas-Collel, A., Whinston, M.D. and Green, J.R. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
New York State College of Agriculture and Life Science. 1987. Cornell Field Crops and Soils Handbook. Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
Paris, Q.The von Liebig Hypothesis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74(4): 10191028.Google Scholar
Peterson, J.M. and Boisvert, R.N. 1998. “Optimal Voluntary ‘Green’ Payment Programs to Limit Nitrate Contamination under Price and Yield Risk.” RB98-01, Department of Agricultural, Resource, and Managerial Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.Google Scholar
Poe, G.L. 1998. “Property Tax Distortions and Participation in Federal Easement Programs: An Exploratory Analysis of the Wetlands Reserve Program.” Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 27(1): 117124.Google Scholar
Ramaswami, B. 1992. “Production Risk and Optimal Input Decisions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74(4): 860869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ribaudo, M.O., Horan, R.D. and Smith, M.E. 1999. “Economics of Water Quality Protection from Nonpoint Sources: Theory and Practice.” Resource Economics Division, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural Economic Report Number 782.Google Scholar
Schmit, T.M. 1994. “The Economic Impact of Nutrient Loading Restrictions on Dairy Farm Profitability.” Unpublished M.S. Thesis, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
Spulber, D.F. 1985. “Effluent Regulation and Long-Run Optimality.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 12(2): 103116.Google Scholar
Teague, M.L., Bernardo, D.J. and Mapp, H.P. 1995. “Farm-Level Economic Analysis Incorporating Stochastic Environmental Risk Assessment.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77(1): 819.Google Scholar
Tegene, A., Huffman, W.E. and Miranowski, J.A. 1988. “Dynamic Corn Supply Functions: A Model with Explicit Optimization.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67(1): 193203.Google Scholar
Thomas, A.C. and Boisvert, R.N. 1995. “The Bioeconomics of Regulating Nitrates in Groundwater From Agricultural Production through Taxes, Quantity Restrictions, and Pollution Permits.” R.B. 96-06, Department of Agricultural, Resource, and Managerial Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. 1994. “Economic Indicators of the Farm Sector: Costs of Production—Major Field Crops & Livestock and Dairy, 1992.” ECIFS 12-3, August.Google Scholar
Wu, J. and Babcock, B. 1995. “Optimal Design of a Voluntary Green Payment Program under Asymmetric Information.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 20(2): 316327.Google Scholar
Wu, J. and Babcock, B. 1996. “Contract Design for the Purchase of Environmental Goods from Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78(4): 935945.Google Scholar