Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T05:49:37.291Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Collective Action with Uncertain Payoffs: Coordination, Public Signals, and Punishment Dilemmas

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 November 2011

MEHDI SHADMEHR*
Affiliation:
University of Miami
DAN BERNHARDT*
Affiliation:
University of Illinois
*
Mehdi Shadmehr is Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Miami, 5250 University Drive, Coral Gables, FL 33146 (shad@miami.edu).
Dan Bernhardt is IBE Professor of Economics and Finance, Department of Economics, University of Illinois, David Kinley Hall, Urbana, IL 61801 (danber@illinois.edu).

Abstract

How can one analyze collective action in protests or revolutions when individuals are uncertain about the relative payoffs of the status quo and revolution? We model a “calculus of protest” of individuals who must either submit to the status quo or support revolt based only on personal information about their payoffs. In deciding whether to revolt, the citizen must infer both the benefit of successful revolution and the likely actions of other citizens. We characterize conditions under which payoff uncertainty overturns conventional wisdom: (a) when a citizen is too willing to revolt, he reduces the incentives of others to revolt; (b) less accurate information about the value of revolution can make revolt more likely; (c) public signals from other citizens can reduce the likelihood of revolt; (d) harsher punishment can increase the incidence of punishment; and (e) the incidence of protest can be positively correlated with that of repression.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Abrahamian, Ervand. 1982. Iran between Two Revolutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abrahamian, Ervand. 1989. The Iranian Mojahedin. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Abrahamian, Ervand. 1999. Tortured Confessions: Prison and Public Recantation in Modern Iran. Berkeley: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abrahamian, Ervand. 2008. A History of Modern Iran. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2006. Economic Origins of Democracy and Dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Athey, Susan. 2001. “Single Crossing Properties and the Existence of Pure Strategy Equilibria in Games of Incomplete Information.” Econometrica 69 (4): 861–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep, and Sjostrom, Thomas. 2004. “Arms Races and Negotiations.” Review of Economic Studies 71: 351–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and Redistribution. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, Carles, and Svolik, Milan. 2009. “The Foundations of Limited Authoritarian Government: Institutions and Power-sharing in Dictatorships.” Princeton University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Brinton, Crane. [1938] 1965. The Anatomy of Revolution. New York: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and Downs, George W.. 2005. “Development and Democracy.” Foreign Affairs 84: 7786.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2010a. “Multiplicity and Uniqueness in Games of Regime Change.” University of Chicago. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2010b. “Regime Change and Revolutionary Entrepreneurs.” American Political Science Review 104: 446–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan, and Landa, Dimitri. 2008. “An Equilibrium Theory of Clarity of Responsibility.” University of Chicago. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Bulow, Jeremy I., Geanakoplos, John D., and Klemperer, Paul D.. 1985. “Market Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements.” Journal of Political Economy 93: 488511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, Hans, and van Damme, Eric. 1993. “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection.” Econometrica 61: 9891018.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamley, Christophe. 1999. “Coordinating Regime Switches.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 869905.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chassang, Sylvain, and Miquel, Gerard Padro i. 2010. “Conflict and Deterrence under Strategic Risk.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125: 1821–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chwe, Michael S. 2000. “Communication and Coordination in Social Networks.” Review of Economics Studies 67: 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chwe, Michael S. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Conquest, Robert. 1990. The Great Terror: A Reassessment. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Davenport, Christian. 1996. “The Weight of the Past: Exploring the Lagged Determinants of Political Repression.” Political Research Quarterly 49: 377403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davenport, Christian. 2007. “State Repression and Political Order.” Annual Review of Political Science 10: 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewan, Turon, and Myatt, David P.. 2007. “Leading the Party: Coordination, Direction, and Communication.” American Political Science Review 101: 827–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewan, Turon, and Myatt, David P.. 2008. “The Qualities of Leadership: Direction, Communication, and Obfuscation.” American Political Science Review 102: 351–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edmond, Chris. 2008. “Information Manipulation, Coordination and Regime Change.” New York University. Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, Guriev, Sergei, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2009. “Why Resource-poor Dictators Allow Freer Media: A Theory and Evidence from Panel Data.” American Political Science Review 103: 645–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Sonin, Konstantin. 2011. “Incumbency Advantage in Non-democracies.” Northwestern University. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy J., and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. 1998. “Convicting the Innocent: The Inferiority of Unanimous Jury Verdicts under Strategic Voting.” American Political Science Review 92: 2335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fitzpatrick, Sheila. 1994. The Russian Revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fortescue, William. 2005. France and 1848: The End of Monarchy. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Frankel, David M., Morris, Stephen, and Pauzner, Ady. 2003. “Equilibrium Selection in Global Games with Strategic Complementarities.” Journal of Economic Theory 106: 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark. 1978. “Threshold Models of Collective Behavior.” American Journal of Sociology 83: 1420–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, R. J. 1978. Political Repression in Modern America: From 1870 to the Present. Cambridge, UK: Schenkman.Google Scholar
Goldstein, Itay, and Pauzner, Ady. 2005. “Demand-deposit Contracts and the Probability of Bank Runs.” Journal of Finance 60 (3): 12931327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellwig, Christian. 2002. “Public Information, Private Information, and the Multiplicity of Equilibria in Coordination Games.” Journal of Economic Theory 107: 191222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalyvas, Stathis N., and Kocher, Matthew. 2007. “How ‘Free’ Is Free Riding in Civil Wars? Violence, Insurgency, and the Collective Action Problem.” World Politics 59: 177216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlin, Samuel. 1968. Total Positivity, Volume I. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1991. “Now out of Never: The Element of Surprise in the East European Revolution of 1989.” World Politics 44 (1): 748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichbach, Mark I. 1995. The Rebel's Dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichbach, Mark I. 1998. “Contending Theories of Contentious Politics and the Structure–action Problem of Social Order.” Annual Review of Political Science 1: 401–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. “The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East Germany 1989–91.” World Politics 47: 42101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magaloni, Beatriz. 2010. “The Game of Electoral Fraud and the Ousting of Authoritarian Rule.” American Journal of Political Science 54: 751–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCauley, Martin. 2008. Stalin and Stalinism. 3rd ed. Harlow, UK: Pearson Education Limited.Google Scholar
Merriman, John M. 1978. The Agony of the Republic: The Repression of the Left Revolutionary in France, 1848–1851. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Milani, Mohsen M. 1994. The Making of Iran's Islamic Revolution. Boulder, CO: Westview.Google Scholar
Moore, Will H. 2000. “The Repression of Dissent: A Substitution Model of Government Coercion.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 44: 107–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 1998. “Unique Equilibrium in a Model of Self-fulfilling Currency Attacks.” American Economic Review 88: 587–97.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2003. “Global Games: Theory and Application.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics, Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, Volume I, ed. M. Dewatripont, L. P. Hansen, and S. J. Turnovsky. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Muller, Edward N., and Weede, Erich. 1990. “Cross-national Variation in Political Violence.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 34: 624–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsa, Misagh. 2000. States, Ideologies, and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of Iran, Nicaragua and the Philippines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. 2009. “Democratic Capital: The Nexus of Political and Economic Change.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1: 88126.Google Scholar
Poe, Steven C., and Tate, C. Neal. 1994. “Repression of Human Rights to Personal Integrity in the 1980s: A Global Analysis.” American Political Science Review 88: 853–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
PowellG. Bingham, Jr. G. Bingham, Jr. 2000. Elections as Instruments of Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Riasanovsky, Nicholas V., and Steinberg, Mark D.. 2005. A History of Russia. 7th ed. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Royden, H. L. 1988. Real Analysis. 3rd ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Sampford, M.R. 1953. “Some Inequalities on Mill's Ratio and Related Functions.” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics 24: 130–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1969. “Models of Segregation.” American Economic Review 59: 488–93.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1971. “Dynamic Models of Segregation.” Journal of Mathematical Sociology 1: 143–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi. 2010. “The Repression Puzzle.” University of Miami. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Shadmehr, Mehdi, and Bernhardt, Dan. 2011. “Coordination Games with Common Values.” University of Illinois. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Svolik, Milan. 2010. “Learning to Love Democracy: Electoral Accountability, Government Performance, and the Consolidation of Democracy.” University of Illinois. Mimeo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tarrow, Sydney. 1998. Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Politics, 2nd ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavits, Margit. 2007. “Clarity of Responsibility and Corruption.” American Journal of Political Science 51: 218–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1978. From Mobilization to Revolution. Indianapolis. IN: Addison–Wesley.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1986. The Contentious French. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles, and Lees, Lynn H.. 1975. “The People of June 1848.” In Revolution and Reaction: 1848 and the Second French Republic, ed. Roger Price. New York: Barnes and Noble.Google Scholar
Traugott, Mark. 1985. Armies of the Poor: Determinants of Working-class Participation in the Parisian Insurrection of June 1848. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1971. “The Paradox of Revolution.” Public Choice 11: 8999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Belle, Douglas A. 1996. “Leadership and Collective Action: The Case of Revolution.” International Studies Quarterly 40: 107–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vives, Xavier. 1999. Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Vives, Xavier. 2005. “Complementarities and Games: New Developments.” Journal of Economic Literature 43: 437–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.