Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T04:41:09.078Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Informational Theory of Legislative Committees: An Experimental Analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 December 2018

MARCO BATTAGLINI*
Affiliation:
Cornell University and EIEF
ERNEST K. LAI*
Affiliation:
Lehigh University
WOOYOUNG LIM*
Affiliation:
The Hong Kong University of Science and Technology
JOSEPH TAO-YI WANG*
Affiliation:
National Taiwan University
*
*Marco Battaglini, Edward H. Meyer Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Cornell University and EIEF, mb2457@cornell.edu.
Ernest K. Lai, Associate Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, Lehigh University, kwl409@lehigh.edu.
Wooyoung Lim, Associate Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, The Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, wooyoung@ust.hk.
§Joseph Tao-yi Wang, Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, National Taiwan University, josephw@ntu.edu.tw.

Abstract

We experimentally investigate the informational theory of legislative committees (Gilligan and Krehbiel 1989). Two committee members provide policy-relevant information to a legislature under alternative legislative rules. Under the open rule, the legislature is free to make any decision; under the closed rule, the legislature chooses between a member’s proposal and a status quo. We find that even in the presence of biases, the committee members improve the legislature’s decision by providing useful information. We obtain evidence for two additional predictions: the outlier principle, according to which more extreme biases reduce the extent of information transmission; and the distributional principle, according to which the open rule is more distributionally efficient than the closed rule. When biases are less extreme, we find that the distributional principle dominates the restrictive-rule principle, according to which the closed rule is more informationally efficient. Overall, our findings provide experimental support for Gilligan and Krehbiel’s informational theory.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are grateful to Andreas Blume, Colin Camerer, Yuk-fai Fong, Jean Hong, David Huffman, Navin Kartik, Joel Sobel, Lise Vesterlund, Joel Watson, Emanuel Vespa, Jonathan Woon, the editor, and four anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. We also express our gratitude to the conference and seminar participants at the 3rd Haverford Meeting on Behavioral and Experimental Economics, the 2015 ESA North American Meeting, the 12th International Conference of the Western Economic Association International, HKUST, UCSD, the Institute of Economics at Academia Sinica, the University of Arizona, the University of Pittsburgh, and the Kiel Institute of Economics for their helpful comments and suggestions. We thank Amanda Eng for excellent research assistance. This study is supported by a grant from the Research Grants Council of Hong Kong (Grant No. GRF-16502015). Replication materials can be found on Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/OWQNVF.

References

REFERENCES

Battaglini, Marco. 2002. “Multiple Referrals and Multidimensional Cheap Talk.” Econometrica 70: 1379–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battaglini, Marco. 2004. “Policy Advice with Imperfectly Informed Experts.” Advances in Theoretical Economics, 4 (1): 1–32. doi:10.2202/1534-5963.1100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, and Makarov, Uliana. 2014. “Cheap Talk with Multiple Audiences: An Experimental Analysis.” Games and Economic Behavior 83: 147–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, Andreas, DeJong, Douglas V., Kim, Yong-Gwan, and Sprinkle, Geoffrey B.. 1998. “Experimental Evidence on the Evolution of the Meaning of Messages in Sender-Recevier Games.” American Economic Review 88: 1323–40.Google Scholar
Blume, Andreas, DeJong, Douglas V., Kim, Yong-Gwan, and Sprinkle, Geoffrey B.. 2001. “Evolution of Communication with Partial Common Interest.” Games and Economic Behavior 37: 79–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, Hongbin, and Wang, Joseph Tao-yi. 2006. “Overcommunication in Strategic Information Transmission Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 56: 7–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1994. “Bonding, Structure, and the Stability of Political Parties: Party Government in the House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 19: 215–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Vincent, and Sobel, Joel. 1982. “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica 50: 1431–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickhaut, John W., McCabe, Kevin A., and Mukherji, Arijit. 1995. “An Experimental Study of Strategic Information Transmission.” Economic Theory 6: 389–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Myerson, Roger B.. 1999. “Bicameralism and Its Consequences for the Internal Organization of Legislatures.” American Economic Review 89: 1182–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dion, Douglas, and Huber, John D.. 1997. “Sense and Sensibility: The Role of Rules.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 945–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs. 2007. “z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-Made Economic Experiments.” Experimental Economics 10: 171–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, Uri. 2005. “Deception: The Role of Consequences.” American Economic Review 95: 384–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groseclose, Tim, and King, David C.. 2001. “Committee Theories Reconsidered.” In Congress Reconsidered. Vol. 7. Washington, DC: CQ Press, 191–216.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Thomas W., and Krehbiel, Keith. 1987. “Collective Decision-Making and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 3: 287–335.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Thomas W., and Krehbiel, Keith. 1989. “Asymmetric Information and Legislative Rules with a Heterogeneous Committee.” American Journal of Political Science 33: 459–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1990. “Are Congressional Committees Composed of Preference Outliers?American Political Science Review 84: 149–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1997a. “Restrictive Rules Reconsidered.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 929–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1997b. “Rejoinder to Sense and Sensibility.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 958–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 2001. “Plausibility of Signals by a Heterogeneous Committee.” American Political Science Review 95: 453–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, Vijay, and Morgan, John. 2001. “Asymmetric Information and Legislative Rules.” American Political Science Review 95: 435–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lai, Ernest K., Lim, Wooyoung, and Wang, Joseph Tao-yi. 2015. “An Experimental Analysis of Multidimensional Cheap Talk.” Games and Economic Behavior 91: 114–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Londregan, John, and Snyder, James M. Jr. 1994. “Comparing Committee and Floor Preferences.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 19: 223–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minozzi, William, and Woon, Jonathan. 2016. “Competition, Preference Uncertainty, and Jamming: A Strategic Communication Experiment.” Games and Economic Behavior 96: 97–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1991. “Patterns of Congressional Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 35: 228–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sánchez-Pagés, Santiago, and Vorsatz, Marc. 2007. “An Experimental Study of Truth-Telling in Sender-Receiver Game.” Games and Economic Behavior 61: 86–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sánchez-Pagés, Santiago, and Vorsatz, Marc. 2009. “Enjoy the Silence: An Experiment on Truth-Telling”. Experimental Economics 12: 220–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Weingast, Barry R., eds. 1995. Positive Theories of Congressional Institutions . Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sinclair, Barbara. 1994. “House Special Rules and the Institutional Design Controversy.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 19: 477–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vespa, Emanuel, and Wilson, Alistair J.. 2016. “Communication with Multiple Senders: An Experiment.” Quantitative Economics 7: 1–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Joseph Tao-yi, Spezio, Michael, and Camerer, Colin F.. 2010. “Pinocchio’s Pupil: Using Eyetracking and Pupil Dilation to Understand Truth Telling and Deception in Sender-Receiver Games.” American Economic Review 100: 984–1007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., and Marshall, William J.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress or Why Legislatures Like Firms are Not Organized as Market.” Journal of Political Economy 96: 132–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: Link

Battaglini et al. Dataset

Link
Supplementary material: PDF

Battaglini et al. supplementary material

Online Appendices

Download Battaglini et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.4 MB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.