Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-30T21:35:55.787Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

INSURANCE LOSS COVERAGE UNDER RESTRICTED RISK CLASSIFICATION: THE CASE OF ISO-ELASTIC DEMAND

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 February 2016

MingJie Hao
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics, Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Kent, Canterbury, CT2 7NF, UK E-Mail: mh586@kent.ac.uk
Angus S. Macdonald
Affiliation:
Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, and the Maxwell Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, UK E-Mail: A.S.Macdonald@hw.ac.uk
Pradip Tapadar*
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics, Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Kent, Canterbury, CT2 7NF, UK
R. Guy Thomas
Affiliation:
School of Mathematics, Statistics and Actuarial Science, University of Kent, Canterbury, CT2 7NF, UK E-mail: R.G.Thomas@kent.ac.uk

Abstract

This paper investigates equilibrium in an insurance market where risk classification is restricted. Insurance demand is characterised by an iso-elastic function with a single elasticity parameter. We characterise the equilibrium by three quantities: equilibrium premium; level of adverse selection (in the economist's sense); and “loss coverage”, defined as the expected population losses compensated by insurance. We consider both equal elasticities for high and low risk-groups, and then different elasticities. In the equal elasticities case, adverse selection is always higher under pooling than under risk-differentiated premiums, while loss coverage first increases and then decreases with demand elasticity. We argue that loss coverage represents the efficacy of insurance for the whole population; and therefore that if demand elasticity is sufficiently low, adverse selection is not always a bad thing.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Astin Bulletin 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Blumberg, L., Nichold, L. and Banthin, J. (2001) Worker decisions to purchase health insurance. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 1, 305325Google Scholar
Buchmueller, T.C. and Ohri, S. (2006) Health insurance take-up by the near-elderly. Health Services Research, 41, 20542073Google Scholar
Butler, J.R.G. (1999) Estimating elasticities of demand for private health insurance in Australia. Working Paper, 43, National Centre for Epidemiology and Population Health, CanberraGoogle Scholar
Cardon, J.H. and Hendel, I. (2001) Asymmetric information in health insurance: Evidence from the National Medical Expenditure Survey. Rand Journal of Economics, 32, 408427Google Scholar
Chernew, M., Frick, K. and McLaughlin, C. (1997) The demand for health insurance coverage by low-income workers: Can reduced premiums achieve full coverage?. Health Services Research, 32, 453470Google Scholar
Chiappori, P.-A. and Salanie, B. (2000) Testing for asymmetric information in insurance markets. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 5678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, A. and Siegelman, P. (2010) Testing for adverse selection in insurance markets. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77, 3984Google Scholar
De Jong, P. and Ferris, S. (2006) Adverse selection spirals. ASTIN Bulletin, 36, 589628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dionne, G. and Rothschild, C.G. (2014) Economic effects of risk classification bans. Geneva Risk and Insurance Review, 39, 184221Google Scholar
Finkelstein, A. and McGarry, K. (2006) Multiple dimensions of private information: Evidence from the long-term care insurance market. American Economic Review, 96, 938958CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Finkelstein, A. and Poterba, J. (2004) Adverse selection in insurance markets: Policyholder evidence from the UK annuity market. Journal of Political Economy, 112, 183208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoy, M. (2006) Risk classification and social welfare. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 31, 245269Google Scholar
Hoy, M. and Polborn, M. (2000) The value of genetic information in the life insurance market. Journal of Public Economics, 78, 235252CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macdonald, A.S. and Tapadar, P. (2010) Multifactorial disorders and adverse selection: epidemiology meets economics. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77, 155182Google Scholar
Pauly, M.V., Withers, K.H., Viswanathan, K.S., Lemaire, J., Hershey, J.C., Armstrong, K. and Asch, D.A. (2003) Price elasticity of demand for term life insurance and adverse selection. NBER Working Paper, 9925, http://www.nber.org/papers/w9925. Accessed on February 5, (2016).Google Scholar
Thomas, R.G. (2008) Loss coverage as a public policy objective for risk classification schemes. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 75, 9971018Google Scholar
Thomas, R.G. (2009) Demand elasticity, risk classification and loss coverage: When can community rating work?. ASTIN Bulletin, 39, 403428Google Scholar
Viswanathan, K.S., Lemaire, J. K., Withers, K., Armstrong, K., Baumritter, A., Hershey, J., Pauly, M. and Asch, D.A. (2007) Adverse selection in term life insurance purchasing due to the BRCA 1/2 Genetic Test and elastic demand. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 74, 6586Google Scholar