Article contents
Policy Innovation and Institutional Stability in Sweden
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 27 January 2009
Extract
Despite the greatly enhanced interest in processes of political change that political scientists have shown in recent years, there are still areas that have received attention in only the most speculative manner. Modernization, political development and comparative history are becoming established subdisciplines, reflecting ‘the change to change’. But the political processes involved in the transformation of advanced industrial societies have as yet received only cursory empirical treatment.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1976
References
1 See Huntington, Samuel P., ‘The Change to Change’, Comparative Politics, 111 (1971). 282–322.Google Scholar
2 Toffler, Alvin, Future Shock (London: Pan Books, 1971), pp. 27–41.Google Scholar
3 Benn, Anthony Wedgwood, quoted in Observer, 26 05 1968.Google Scholar
4 Huntington, Samuel P., ‘Post-industrial Politics: How Benign Will It Be?’ Comparative Politics, VI (1974), 163–91, pp. 164–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
5 Lasch, Christopher, ‘Towards a Theory of Post-industrial Society’, in Hancock, M. Donald and Sjoberg, Gideon, eds., Politics in the Post-welfare State (New York: Columbia University Press, 1972), p. 36.Google Scholar
6 Bell, Daniel. ‘The Measurement of Knowledge and Technology’ in Sheldon, Eleanor and Moore, Wilbert, eds., Indicators of Social Change (New York: Russell Sage, 1968), p. 152.Google Scholar
7 The division between ‘primary’ (agricultural), ‘secondary’ (industrial) and ‘tertiary’ (service) economies is discussed in Fourastie, J.. Le Grand espoir du XXe siècle (Paris: Gallimard. 1949).Google Scholar
8 Galbraith, John Kenneth. The New Industrial State (London: Hamish Hamilton, 1967).Google Scholar
9 Huntington, , ‘Post-industrial Polities’, pp. 166, 190.Google Scholar
10 Reich, Charles A., The Greening of America (London: Allen Lane, 1971).Google Scholar
11 Marcuse, Herbert. One-Dimensional Man (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1964).Google Scholar
12 See Hayward, Jack, ‘Institutional Inertia and Political Impetus in France and Britain’ (Political Studies Association conference paper, Oxford, 1975).Google Scholar
13 Bell is the originator of the term ‘post-industrial’ society, Brzezinski's choice is ‘technetronic’ society, and Toffler, prefers ‘super-industrial’Google Scholar society. Despite differences in emphasis, their descriptions of socio-economic change are not radically different.
14 The Times, ‘Special Report on Sweden’, 24 10 1974.Google Scholar
15 Edgren, G., Faxen, K.-O. and Odhner, C.-E., ‘Wage, Growth and the Distribution of Income’. Swedish Journal of Economics, LXXI (1969), 133–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar The fact that the authors of this article are the chief economists of the three main industrial pressure groups, representing wage labourers, salaried workers and employers, is itself a fascinating example of Swedish elite consensus to be discussed below.
16 Data cited in Wheeler, Christopher W., ‘The Decline of Deference: The Tension between Participation and Effectiveness in Organized Group Life in Sweden’ (unpublished paper, Beloit College, 11 1972), pp. 13–14.Google Scholar
17 Russe, Bruce M. et al. , World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1964), pp. 184–6.Google Scholar
18 Field, G. Lowell and Higley, John. Elites in Developed Societies: Theoretical Reflections on an Initial Stage in Norway, Sage Professional Papers (London: Sage, 1972), p. 37.Google Scholar
19 Tomasson, Richard F., Sweden: Prototype of Modern Society (New York: Random House. 1970). pp. 291–2.Google Scholar
20 Wheeler, . ‘The Decline of Deference’, pp. 12–31.Google Scholar
21 Meidner, Rudolf, ‘The Trade Union Movement and the Public Sector’Google Scholar, speech delivered at the twentieth convention of Public Services International (PSI), New York, 1973.
22 Meidner, , ‘The Trade Union Movement and the Public Sector’.Google Scholar
23 See Hancock, M. Donald. ‘Post-welfare Modernization in Sweden: The Quest for Cumulative Rationality and Equality’Google Scholar, in Hancock, and Sjoberg, , eds., Politics in the Post-welfare StateGoogle Scholar, and Hancock, M. Donald. Sweden: The Politics of Post-industrial Change (Hinsdale, Ill.: Dryden Press. 1972).Google Scholar
24 Hancock, M. Donald, ‘Elite Images and System Change in Sweden’, in Lindberg, Leon, ed., Politics and the Future of Industrial Society (New York: David McKay, 1976).Google Scholar
25 Toffler, , Future Shock, pp. 105–7.Google Scholar
26 Samuelsson, K., From Great Power to Welfare State (London: Allen and Unwin, 1968), chap. 5.Google Scholar
27 Mukherjee, Santosh, Making Labour Markets Work, PEP Broadsheet 532 (London: Political and Economic Planning, 1972), p. 88.Google Scholar
28 Quoted in Heclo, Hugh, Modern Social Politics in Britain and Sweden (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1974), p. 139.Google Scholar
29 Rehn, Gosta, Arbetet, 5 09 1959.Google Scholar
30 Myrdal, Alva, Towards EqualityGoogle Scholar, First Report of the Working Party on Equality set up by the Swedish Social Democratic party and the Swedish Confederation of Trade Unions (Stock holm: Prisma, 1971), p. 56.
31 Myrdal, , Towards Equality, p. 62.Google Scholar
32 Mukherjee, , Making Labour Markets Work, p. 133.Google Scholar
33 See Castles, Francis G., ‘The Political Functions of Organized Groups: The Swedish Case’, Political Studies, XXI (1973), 26–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34 Anton, Thomas J., ‘Policy-making and Political Culture in Sweden’, Scandinavian Political Studies, IV (1969), p. 93.Google Scholar
35 For a polemic against the supposed socialism of Sweden, see Hufford, Larry, ‘Sweden: the Myth of Socialism’, Young Fabian Pamphlet (London: Fabian Society, 1973).Google Scholar
36 This and the following paragraph are based on Castles, Francis G., ‘Swedish Social Democracy: The Conditions of Success’, Political Quarterly, XLVI (1975), 171–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
37 Stjernquist, N., ‘Sweden: Stability or Deadlock?’, in Dahl, Robert A., ed., Political Opposition in Western Democracies (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1966), pp. 116–46.Google Scholar
38 The peculiarities of Swedish political development are discussed in Castles, ‘Swedish Social Democracy: The Conditions of Success’, and also in Castles, ‘Harrington Moore's Thesis and Swedish Political Development’, Government and Opposition, VIII (1973), 313–31.Google Scholar
39 This term is suggested by Stein Rokkan in his description of the Norwegian political system as one in which policy-making is as much a product of corporate pressures exerted through organized groups as of electoral pressures exerted through the ballot box. See Rokkan, Stein, ‘Norway: Numerical Democracy and Corporate Pluralism’Google Scholar, in Dahl, , ed., Political Opposition in Western Democracies, pp. 105–10.Google Scholar
40 Ruin, Olof, ‘Participatory Democracy and Corporativism: The Case of Sweden’, Scandinavian Political Studies, IX (1974), 171–84, p. 180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
41 Hancock, , ‘Elite Images and System Change in Sweden’.Google Scholar
- 11
- Cited by