Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T02:47:01.103Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Linking and Integrating Corporatism and Consensus Democracy: Theory, Concepts and Evidence

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

Hans Keman's and Paul Pennings's critique (‘Managing Political and Societal Conflict in Democracies: Do Consensus and Corporatism Matter?’, this Journal, preceding pages) of our attempt to link corporatism and consensus democracy falls essentially into three parts. Their first criticism deals with the way we measured corporatism. They reject our ‘composite’ approach on the basis that different experts have different conceptual understandings of corporatism. Hence, they argue, it is unwarranted to add up these various scores. Secondly, they claim that our central relationship between consensus democracy and corporatism is a function of our particular measure of corporatism and, in addition, driven by two outlying cases: Italy and Austria. Thirdly, they claim that corporatism and consensus democracy are two different phenomena, and that therefore, corporatism should not be integrated into the concept of consensus democracy. We shall address these three main criticisms in the order described.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Schmilter, Phillippe C., ‘Reflections on Where the Theory of Neo-Corporatism Has Gone and Where the Praxis of Neo-Corporatism May Be Going’, in Lehmbruch, Gerhard and Schmitter, Phillippe C., eds. Patterns of Corporatist Policy Making (London: Sage, 1982).Google Scholar

2 Lijphart, Arend and Crepaz, Markus M. L., ‘Corporatism and Consensus Democracy in Eighteen Countries: Conceptual and Empirical Linkages’, British Journal of Political Science, 21 (1991), 235–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 For example, Lehmbruch, Gerhard, ‘Concertation and the Structure of Corporalist Networks’, in Goldthrope, John H., ed., Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), pp. 6080 at p. 62Google Scholar, defines corporatist concertation as having two essential features: first, ‘it involves not just a single organized interest with privileged access to government but rather a plurality of organizations usually representing antagonistic interests; and second, these organizations manage their conflicts and co-ordinate their action with that of government expressly in regard to the systemic (gesamtwirtschaftliche) requirements of the national economy’. Katzenstein, Peter's (Small States in World Markets. Industrial Policy in Europe (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1985), p. 32)Google Scholar definition of ‘social partnership’ seems to be closely related to Lehmbruch's notion of concertation: ‘This ideology [social partnership] mitigates class conflict between business and unions; it integrates differing conceptions of group interest with vaguely held notions of the public interest’.

4 Manheim, Jarol B. and Rich, Richard C., Empirical Political Analysis: Research Methods in Political Science (New York: Longman. 1991), p. 62.Google Scholar

5 Keman, and Pennings, , ‘Managing Political and Societal Conflict’, p. 5.Google Scholar

6 Lijphart, and Crepaz, , ‘Corporatism and Consensus Democracy’, p. 239.Google Scholar

7 Latest scores used by Keman, Hans, obtained by personal communication in 1994.Google Scholar

8 Pryor, Frederic, ‘Corporatism as an Economic System: A Review Essay’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 12 (1988), 317–44. p. 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Lijphart, and Crepaz, , ‘Corporatism and Consensus Democracy’, p. 235–6.Google Scholar

10 Lehmbruch, Gerhard, ‘Concertation and the Structure of Corporatist Networks’, p. 61 (emphasis added).Google Scholar

11 Keman, and Pennings, , ‘Managing Political and Societal Conflict’, p. 274.Google Scholar

12 Lijphart, and Crepaz, , ‘Corporatism and Consensus Democracy’, p. 238.Google Scholar

13 Marks, Gary, ‘Neocorporatism and Incomes Policy in Western Europe and North America’. Comparative Politics, 18 (1986), 253–78 at p. 274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 Keman, and Pennings, , ‘Managing Political and Societal Conflict’, p. 6.Google Scholar

15 Belseley, David A., Kuh, Edwin and Welsch, Roy E., Regression Diagnostics: Identifying Influential Data and Sources of Collinearity (New York: Wiley, 1980).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 We used the conventional 0.05 (two-tailed t-test) as a cut-off point to determine outliers. Since residuals do not follow a hypothesized direction, two-tailed t-tests are appropriate. The two-tailed t-value for 16 degrees of freedom is ± 2.120 at the 0.05 level. Only Austria's studentized residual exceeds this critical cut-off point.

17 Belseley, , Kuh, and Welsch, , Regression Diagnostics, p. 7.Google Scholar

18 Belseley, , Kuh, and Welsch, , Regression Diagnostics, p. 17.Google Scholar

19 As indicated above, Italy's sludentized residual value (– 1.963) does not exceed the critical cut-off point of ± 2.12 (two-tailed, 16 degrees of freedom, at the 0.05 level), which does not qualify it for an outlier. However, since Keman and Pennings argue that Italy is an outlier, and since Italy is close to the cut-off point, we decided to report the effects of Italy's omission individually and in conjunction with Austria on the parameter estimates.

20 Keman, and Pennings, , ‘Managing Political and Societal Conflict’, p. 6.Google Scholar

21 Lijphart, and Crepaz, , ‘Corporatism and Consensus Democracy’, p. 235.Google Scholar