Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-94fs2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T07:14:58.737Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Mind the Gap: Why Wealthy Voters Support Brexit

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 May 2024

Jane Green*
Affiliation:
Department of Politics and International Relations, Nuffield College, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Raluca L. Pahontu
Affiliation:
Department of Political Economy, King's College London, London, UK
*
Corresponding author: Jane Green; Email: jane.green@nuffield.ox.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Wealth provides self-insurance against financial risk, reducing risk aversion. We apply this insurance mechanism to electoral behaviour, arguing that a voter who desires a change to the status quo and who is wealthy is more likely to vote for change than a voter who lacks the same self-insurance. We apply this argument to the case of Brexit in the UK, which has been widely characterized as a vote by the ‘economically left-behind’. Our results show that individuals who lacked wealth are less likely to support leaving the EU, explaining why so many Brexit voters were wealthy, in terms of their property wealth. We corroborate our theory using two panel surveys, accounting for unobserved individual-level heterogeneity, and by using a survey experiment. The findings have implications for the potential broader role of wealth-as-insurance in electoral behaviour and for understanding the Brexit case.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Many choices in political behaviour concern trade-offs between the net benefits a choice may bring and its potential risks. This is especially true in high-stakes elections that usher in major changes to the status quo: ‘in democracies, citizens can be called upon to make decisions that have profound and irreversible consequences, yet the environment in which they make these decisions is inherently uncertain, and sometimes hazardous’ (Nadeau, Martin, and Blais Reference Nadeau, Martin and Blais1999, 523). Political actors compete over alternative versions of the likely costs and benefits of such a contentious electoral choice. However, this discord increases the risk to a voter who has to decide between the two sides of a consequential decision (Alvarez and Franklin Reference Alvarez and Franklin1994; Franklin Reference Franklin1991).Footnote 1

Referendums provide such high-stakes and risky decisions (De Vries Reference De Vries2018; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2009). Voters are asked to choose between a familiar status quo and the much less certain outcome of a fundamental change. When faced with such choices, voters tend to be biased toward the status quo (Masatlioglu and Ok Reference Masatlioglu and Ok2005; Samuelson and Zeckhauser Reference Samuelson and Zeckhauser1988) – for example, as seen in the cases of independence for Quebec, Catalonia, and Scotland (Hierro and Queralt Reference Hierro and Queralt2021).

Status quo votes tend to be irreversible in the foreseeable future. They relate to profound political, economic, cultural and constitutional change and, by definition, tend to lack local or recent precedent. However, voters may perceive benefits from changing the status quo, such as greater sovereignty, economic independence, and appeals to national identity. This was the experience of former Soviet republics, the unification of East and West Germany, and decisions to join, or indeed leave, the European Union's economic area and monetary union (Abadie, Diamond, and Hainmueller Reference Abadie, Diamond and Hainmueller2015; Atikcan, Nadeau, and Belanger Reference Atikcan, Nadeau and Belanger2020; De Vries Reference De Vries2018; Hierro and Queralt Reference Hierro and Queralt2021; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2009; Reference Hobolt2016).

Yet, ‘not all voters who are disenchanted with the status quo take a chance on the less known alternative’ (Morgenstern and Zechmeister Reference Morgenstern and Zechmeister2001). As status quo changes pose potential economic risks to individuals, voters' decisions are likely affected by their tolerance to that risk (Morisi Reference Morisi2018).

Risk aversion is often linked to a stable personality trait, but a growing body of literature documents its variation with wealth. In particular, the accumulation of wealth is associated with a higher tolerance for risk (Donkers, Melenberg, and Van Soest Reference Donkers, Melenberg and Van Soest2001; Pahontu Reference Pahontu2020; Zanetti Reference Zanetti2014). This happens because wealth provides insurance for individuals (Ansell Reference Ansell2014) in case of income shocks or economic risks (Hariri, Jensen, and Lassen Reference Hariri, Jensen and Lassen2020; Tertytchnaya and De Vries Reference Tertytchnaya and De Vries2019). This should be highly relevant to electoral choice where risk aversion is a central component, such as in status quo votes (Liñeira and Henderson Reference Liñeira and Henderson2021; Morisi Reference Morisi2018; Steenbergen and Siczek Reference Steenbergen and Siczek2017). We focus on the role of wealth in informing risk aversion and its effect on decision-making to study why some individuals refrain from supporting status quo changes despite wanting to do so.

We apply this framework to the case of Brexit, a high-stakes referendum that posited the economic, cultural, and sovereignty costs and benefits of leaving the European Union against the risks of fundamentally changing the UK's relationship with its largest trading partner, the EU. The dominant explanation has been a focus on those ‘left behind’ from the economic and cultural benefits of globalization, either in the form of direct localized economic grievances (Carreras Reference Carreras2019; Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Fetzer Reference Fetzer2019) or through the relationship between economic and immigration concerns (Carreras, Irepoglu Carreras, and Bowler Reference Carreras, Irepoglu Carreras and Bowler2019; Green, Hellwig, and Fieldhouse Reference Green, Hellwig and Fieldhouse2022; Sobolewska and Ford Reference Sobolewska and Ford2020).

In reality, the Brexit vote was heterogeneous. According to British Election Study (BES) data collected immediately after the 2016 EU referendum (Fieldhouse et al. Reference Fieldhouse2016), 73 per cent of Leave voters in the referendum were homeowners (71 per cent for Remain voters); 60 per cent of Leave voters were ‘very unlikely’ or ‘unlikely’ to become unemployed (53 per cent for Remain voters); and 23 per cent of Leave voters were ‘very unlikely’ or ‘likely’ to be at risk of poverty (28 per cent for Remain voters). Older voters in Britain were substantially more likely to have voted Leave. They were also more likely to have wealth through assets and savings and more likely to have higher economic security as a result (Chrisp and Pearce Reference Chrisp and Pearce2019; Green and de Geus Reference Green and de Geus2022). There were also more Eurosceptics in the British population than voters who opted to leave the EU, suggesting that a sizeable proportion of voters might have seen greater downsides of membership of the EU but did not take the risk of voting Leave.

We argue that this pattern can be understood through a self-insurance perspective. More voters in poorer areas of the UK saw benefits to Brexit than in prosperous ones (Adler and Ansell Reference Adler and Ansell2020; Ansell Reference Ansell2019; Carreras Reference Carreras2019). But within those areas, we show that individuals lacking self-insurance in the form of personal wealth were less likely to vote to leave the EU than those within the same areas who had assets.

To identify this effect, we use a variety of individual-level data sources on wealth and public opinion, including two nationally representative panel surveys and a survey experiment. It is not common for detailed wealth measures to be combined with detailed political variables, so we took advantage of new datasets that made this possible. We present multiple sets of evidence in support of our core expectation that wealth (at the individual level) increases support for Brexit and that this effect is due to its role in decreasing risk aversion. With little or no insurance, poorer Britons are less likely to support a status quo change and vote for Brexit. We also find that this effect holds once we study these individual-level effects within areas classified as above and below local median wealth levels. At the aggregate level, we replicate the patterns highlighted by Ansell (Reference Ansell2019), Adler and Ansell (Reference Adler and Ansell2020), and Carreras (Reference Carreras2019), showing that wealthier areas exhibited higher support for Brexit overall. But within those areas, wealth was associated with higher support for Leave.

The implications of our analysis may be instructive for contexts other than referendums concerning a risky (economic) choice. While others have documented the importance of wealth as a source of economic voting (Lewis-Beck and Nadeau Reference Lewis-Beck and Nadeau2011; Nadeau, Foucault, and Lewis-Beck Reference Nadeau, Foucault and Lewis-Beck2011; Nadeau, Lewis-Beck, and Foucault Reference Nadeau, Lewis-Beck and Foucault2019), the application of the wealth-as-insurance logic might explain why, when choosing between an incumbent and uncertain hypothetical future under a challenger (Fiorina Reference Fiorina1977; Fiorina Reference Fiorina1981), some voters opt for the more predictable status quo. This might be especially important when an electoral choice could trigger a period of dramatic economic change or instability. That certainly applies to other secession referenda and may apply to electoral choices where a voter prefers certain goals (such as sovereignty, immigration, environmental protection, and public spending), but the change itself will result in economic instability. A wealthier individual may be more likely to support a radical economic change associated with, for example, rapid decarbonization if they are insured against economic disruption. This logic expands the idea that economic inequalities drive people's political preferences by showing that they also alter people's ability to act on those preferences.

Wealth as Insurance

People care about risk and are likely to demand insurance against those risks (Moene and Wallerstein Reference Moene and Wallerstein2001). Insurance typically refers to welfare state provisions that provide a last-resort financial cushion against severe misfortune. As a result of its insuring role, support for welfare spending tends to be higher among individuals who rely on social insurance, as well as those faced with higher risks of unemployment, sickness, or exposure to crime (Hacker Reference Hacker2019; O'Grady Reference O'Grady2019; Rehm, Hacker, and Schlesinger Reference Rehm, Hacker and Schlesinger2012; Rueda and Stegmueller Reference Rueda and Stegmueller2016).

However, many have increasingly documented the importance of ‘self-insurance’, which takes the form of an individual's wealth (Ansell Reference Ansell2014; Busemeyer and Iversen Reference Busemeyer and Iversen2020; Hilt and Rahn Reference Hilt and Rahn2020; Tertytchnaya and De Vries Reference Tertytchnaya and De Vries2019). Wealth provides an income buffer to individuals and their families in case of misfortune, such as job loss, inflationary pressures, and other market fluctuations. A lack of wealth in the form of savings or assets is an extremely important form of economic insecurity, as shown in a range of studies and applications (Ansell Reference Ansell2014; Conley and Gifford Reference Conley and Gifford2006; Ehrlich and Becker Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972; Pahontu Reference Pahontu2020; Tertytchnaya and De Vries Reference Tertytchnaya and De Vries2019). Those who lack wealth are more likely to support social insurance policies to insulate against income shocks (Hariri, Jensen, and Lassen Reference Hariri, Jensen and Lassen2020). Wealthier individuals are also found to be significantly less risk averse in light of their increased economic security (Donkers, Melenberg, and Van Soest Reference Donkers, Melenberg and Van Soest2001; Guiso and Paiella Reference Guiso and Paiella2008; Malmendier and Nagel Reference Malmendier and Nagel2011; Paravisini, Rappoport, and Ravina Reference Paravisini, Rappoport and Ravina2017; Zanetti Reference Zanetti2014).Footnote 2

Wealth provides a permanent stock of financial means to buffer against risk. The same cannot be said of a person's income absent wealth. If high incomes provide a buffer, they do so through the accumulation of wealth made possible by savings and asset holding. Due to its transitory nature, income does not offer the same type of economic security as wealth. This is because individuals experiencing a drop in income, in the absence of wealth, cannot smooth consumption. We note that there is only a weak empirical correlation between wealth and income (Ansell Reference Ansell2019), which supports the importance of focusing on both wealth and income to understand people's economic interests.Footnote 3 As Hariri, Jensen, and Lassen (Reference Hariri, Jensen and Lassen2020, 893) state, ‘economic vulnerability, measured by a lack of access to economic buffers, is also common among middle-class and rich households and, thus, largely unrelated to current income’. Many high-income, middle-class households lack the economic security provided by wealth. On the other hand, consistent with the life cycle model (Ando and Modigliani Reference Ando and Modigliani1963), wealth is especially high among older (retired) generations who otherwise have lower incomes, as is the case in the UK (Chrisp and Pearce Reference Chrisp and Pearce2019; Green and de Geus Reference Green and de Geus2022). This happens partly because these individuals also have lower debt levels, particularly housing debt (Wolff Reference Wolff2010).

Home ownership, in particular, increases an individual's sense of economic security (Ronald and Doling Reference Ronald and Doling2012; Weller Reference Weller2007; Williams Reference Williams2014). People buy homes for a sense of agency and as a long-term economic investment, both of which are sources of personal and economic security. Dupuis and Thorns (Reference Dupuis and Thorns1998) argue that home ownership can provide a sense of ontological security in a world that is otherwise experienced as threatening and uncontrollable. In addition, asset ownership is associated strongly with the ability to borrow, and borrowing ability provides additional economic security against short-term income losses (Aladangady Reference Aladangady2017). Home ownership is increasingly out of reach for people with unreliable income sources, unsecured debts, poor credit ratings, and without other borrowing potential, such as through family. Therefore, asset ownership reflects higher economic security, both as a proxy for greater access to potential short-term consumption smoothing through borrowing and as a source of longer-term household economic and psychological security.

The security afforded through wealth should depend on its availability, its reliability as a form of insurance against economic shocks, and how different forms of wealth might ‘de-risk’ particular electoral choices. While standard economic theory expects individuals to smooth consumption and savings over their lifetime (Browning and Crossley Reference Browning and Crossley2001), few individuals actually accumulate substantial savings in practice. Property wealth is typically substantially higher than financial wealth.Footnote 4 In the UK, this is due, at least in part, to a series of government-induced incentives to take up home ownership (Lewis-Beck, Nadeau, and Foucault Reference Lewis-Beck, Nadeau and Foucault2013). The appreciation of house prices has been far higher over a longer period than interest rates on savings or returns from the British stock market (Chrisp and Pearce Reference Chrisp and Pearce2019). Moreover, UK property wealth has been remarkably buoyant in response to major economic downturns. Ansell (Reference Ansell2014) shows how property wealth in the UK rebounded strongly after the 2008 global financial crisis, whereas the same period has been much more detrimental to savers. This property wealth accumulation offered homeowners economic security and appreciation in a protracted period of economic downturn, historically low interest rates on savings, and austerity. Moreover, post-2008 financing regulations meant that UK mortgages were far less likely to suffer from negative equity as affordability criteria were made more stringent. Those owning a home in the UK, post-2008–2009, were more likely to hold a secure asset that would remain secure against short-term income shocks, longer-term national-level recessions, or weak growth.

Our key point is that the political and economic context should determine which type of wealth is most insuring. We expect property wealth, at least within the UK, to offer considerable economic security. This should be especially true for the case we explore in this paper – Brexit – where the short-term economic shock of leaving the EU might have favoured a focus on liquid assets, but the economic debate centred on the much longer-term economic consequences of Britain's new trading partnerships and economic costs and benefits, and long-term projections about an overall loss of GDP. In this context, housing wealth gives individual households a reliable return on their assets and savings, and their borrowing ability helps smooth consumption in the shorter term.

We expect wealth to alter support for the status quo in addition to a standard cost-benefit calculation. Despite having similar preferences, a wealthier individual is more likely to support a status quo change than her less wealthy counterpart. This happens because wealth cushions individuals against risks, making wealthier individuals less risk averse. Incorporating risk aversion into the cost-benefit calculation enhances the understanding of status quo support. When calculating net benefits, a more risk averse individual should put higher weight on costs rather than benefits, dampening their decision to change the status quo. In brief, for a given set of preferences, wealthier individuals are expected to be more likely to support a change to the status quo.

The Brexit Case

The Brexit cost-benefit calculation turned on a combination of the cultural, economic and political benefits of EU independence or the opposite costs of exiting the EU (Clarke, Goodwin, and Whiteley Reference Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley2017; Evans and Menon Reference Evans and Menon2017; Green, Hellwig, and Fieldhouse Reference Green, Hellwig and Fieldhouse2022; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2016; Iakhnis et al. Reference Iakhnis2018). Much of the explanation for the Brexit vote draws on wider insights into the drivers of populism (Autor et al. Reference Autor2019; Ford and Goodwin Reference Ford and Goodwin2014; Mudde Reference Mudde2010; Van Hauwaert and Van Kessel Reference Van Hauwaert and Van Kessel2018) and mirrors the interpretation of the election of Donald Trump in the United States (Bobo Reference Bobo2017; Mutz Reference Mutz2018; Norris and Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2019; Schaffner, MacWilliams, and Nteta Reference Schaffner, MacWilliams, Nteta, Cavari, Powell and Mayer2018). In the UK, researchers pointed to the combination of cultural and economic grievances that motivated support for greater independence from the EU. The degree to which these motives are economic has been the source of considerable debate, with immigration concerns, national identity, and sovereignty being strongly related to voting Leave or Remain (Clarke, Goodwin, and Whiteley Reference Clarke, Goodwin and Whiteley2017; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2016; Iakhnis et al. Reference Iakhnis2018; Norris and Inglehart Reference Norris and Inglehart2019; Sobolewska and Ford Reference Sobolewska and Ford2020). Others have argued for the importance of local economics, either directly or via a connection between localized economic decline and immigration concerns, pointing to local factors such as import shocks (Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018), austerity (Fetzer Reference Fetzer2019), and long-term relative local economic decline (Carreras, Irepoglu Carreras, and Bowler Reference Carreras, Irepoglu Carreras and Bowler2019).

These studies provide information on the sources of people's Brexit preferences but not the risk calculation associated with a vote against the status quo. A status quo bias was evident in other referendums where the anti-EU vote was presented as entailing costly economic consequences (Born et al. Reference Born2019; Breinlich et al. Reference Breinlich2017; Dhingra et al. Reference Dhingra2017; Hobolt Reference Hobolt2016). ‘People will only be expected to risk voting for Brexit when they perceive that their country could do as well, or even better outside’ (De Vries Reference De Vries2018, 156).

Among those who have incorporated risk in the case of Brexit, researchers have pointed to three possible answers for why Britons voted by a majority to leave the EU. The first is that Leave voters and supporters of populist movements are generally less risk averse (Morisi Reference Morisi2018; Steenbergen and Siczek Reference Steenbergen and Siczek2017) and less likely to be dissuaded by the risks associated with a departure from the status quo. For example, Morisi (Reference Morisi2018) shows that levels of risk aversion are especially important for less-informed voters and applies this finding to the EU and Scottish independence referenda. This expectation could help point to the importance of lower risk aversion via higher wealth among Leave voters, which is consistent with our expectations.Footnote 5 The second is that Leave voters were persuaded against the risks associated with leaving the EU; that is to say, the Leave campaign successfully ‘de-risked’ the question of Brexit (Atikcan, Nadeau, and Belanger Reference Atikcan, Nadeau and Belanger2020). However, it was also the case that the Remain vote was much higher than the proportion of Britons who held a prior Eurosceptic preference; and economic concerns were their main reported motivation.Footnote 6 This suggests that many Remain voters might have voted for Brexit had many not been convinced of the risks associated with an exit with the EU. Figure 1 shows the relationship between Euroscepticism before the referendum (in Wave 8 of the British Election Study (BES) internet panel) and voting Leave in the referendum (Wave 9 of the BES panel). Many people who voted Remain in the referendum held strong preferences for greater independence from the EU.

Figure 1. Euroscepticism distribution among Remain voters.

The third explanation, consistent with prospect theory, is that voters who resided in areas that had experienced economic decline were willing to risk Brexit since, relatively speaking, they thought the gains to the national economy would be higher (Carreras Reference Carreras2019). These communities had little to lose and were more likely to support independence from the EU. This explanation is fundamentally a sociotropic one, rooted in the localized experiences of communities who saw that their community might do better.

We contend that individual wealth, through its role in reducing risk aversion, should be a useful addition to these accounts. We propose that people in more economically deprived areas of the UK are more likely to prefer Brexit, which is consistent with prospect theory. But, within those areas, wealthier individuals are more likely to sustain their preferences in support of a change in the status quo. By providing insurance and reducing individuals' tolerance to risk, wealth ‘de-risks’ the vote for a change in the status quo. We complement existing work by showing that individuals' economic circumstances are just as important as sociotropic or local economic experiences. In other words, we expect wealthier individuals in ‘left-behind communities’ to be more likely to vote for Brexit than less wealthy individuals in those same areas and, similarly, wealthy voters to be more likely to support Brexit than less wealthy individuals in prosperous areas.

Indeed, this is consistent with considerable heterogeneity in the Brexit vote. The majority of Leave voters were not economically deprived or insecure. Brexit voters may have been more likely to live in parts of the country that had not benefited from rapid growth through globalization, immigration, and the expansion of high-skilled labour. The vote to remain in the EU was higher in cities, which are also composed of greater numbers of younger voters, graduates, and ethnic minorities (the demographic groups most likely to support Remain). Those living outside these metropolitan hubs may have felt resentful of more prosperous areas and groups (Green, Hellwig, and Fieldhouse Reference Green, Hellwig and Fieldhouse2022). However, at the individual level, more homeowners supported Brexit (73 per cent) than those who voted Remain (71 per cent), 60 per cent of those reporting to be very unlikely or unlikely to become unemployed supported Brexit compared to 53 per cent for Remain, 23 per cent of Leave voters reported being very unlikely or unlikely to encounter issues covering day-to-day living costs compared to 48 per cent of Remain.Footnote 7 In short, Leave voters were, on average, more economically secure than Remain voters. Furthermore, economic left-right values exhibited no statistical association with Leave support, which was most strongly correlated with liberal-authoritarian and immigration attitudes, which correlate with education and age rather than income (Fieldhouse et al. Reference Fieldhouse2021). Such indicators of economic security are predominant among older generations, who favour Leave, with greater social conservatism and more negative attitudes about immigration (Green and de Geus Reference Green and de Geus2022).

Applying this logic to the Brexit vote, we derive three hypotheses. The first is that, controlling for predictors of Brexit preference (the cost-benefit part of the Brexit calculation), wealth will have a positive relationship with support for leaving the EU.

H1: At the individual level, wealth is positively associated with support for leaving the EU.

We also expect wealthier individuals to perceive themselves to have greater economic insurance, to be insulated against the economic consequences of Brexit. We can assess this through perceptions about the personal and national economic consequences of Brexit. Consistent with our insurance argument, wealth should not predict expected national-level economic circumstances, but wealth should increase perceptions that personal economic circumstances should be unaffected by leaving the EU.

H2: At the individual level, wealth is positively associated with expectations of no Brexit effects on personal economic circumstances.

Finally, to further corroborate the theorized causal argument, we expect wealth, consistent with the existing literature, to lead to lower risk aversion.

H3: An increase in wealth leads to a decrease in risk aversion.

Data and Methods

We test our expectations with observational data from the British Election Study (BES) internet panel and data from the Bank of England's 2016–2018 panel survey of income and expenditure. These data sources offer a rare opportunity since national election surveys rarely include individual wealth measures (Nadeau, Foucault, and Lewis-Beck Reference Nadeau, Foucault and Lewis-Beck2011) and federal banking datasets rarely include questions about political preferences, but include plenty of measures of individual wealth. We also designed an additional survey experiment administered as part of the BES by YouGov in 2019.Footnote 8

Most studies rely on household income to proxy wealth. However, as discussed earlier, the correlation between income and wealth is weak (Ansell Reference Ansell2019). Therefore, we try to better approximate an individual's economic circumstances and insurance leverage by relying on respondents’ reported financial and property wealth and adjusting all these measures for household size (Browning, Chiappori, and Lewbel Reference Browning, Chiappori and Lewbel2013).

We used the BES panel study to field a battery of questions on wealth. These wealth measures are available in 2018 (Wave 14). Usefully, the BES panel allows us to link individuals to their locations, thereby enabling us to examine our findings across aggregate patterns. However, the BES data only provides a snapshot into citizens' wealth in one wave of the BES panel and is limited in making broader claims about wealth accumulation and potential changes in political support. The Bank of England (BoE) data provides us with a way to tackle this shortcoming. It includes three waves of wealth measurement and Brexit support, asked to the same respondents, covering the period 2016–2018.Footnote 9

Relying on both datasets further allows us to distinguish and account for respondents' intentions and their current support for Brexit. The dependent variable in the BES asks respondents their prospective vote intention: ‘If there was a referendum on Britain's membership of the European Union, how do you think you would vote?’ This divides respondents into two groups: Leavers and Remainers. BoE respondents are asked, ‘Taking everything into account, how do you [currently – as of 2016/2017/2018] view the UK voting to leave the EU (European Union) in the recent referendum – which has become known as “Brexit”?’ Possible responses vary from ‘very positive’ to ‘very negative’. These attitudes are then mapped onto a binary Leave/Remain support scale.Footnote 10

Our main explanatory variable, wealth, is similarly defined in the two datasets. To define financial wealth, we rely on individuals' reported savings and debt accumulations and adjust this measure by the number of household members. Property wealth is defined as the respondent's home value adjusted for the number of household members and as null if she does not own a house.Footnote 11 We document all of these measurements in Table 1.

Table 1. Wealth items

We validate the BES and BoE wealth measures against official statistics in Appendix A (in the supplementary material) and document remarkable similarities between the central tendencies reported in the two surveys and those reported among the UK population. In Appendix B, we further explore the distribution of wealth in the BES and BoE samples and find few discrepancies between the two surveys. In Figure A.1, we report the relationship between an individual's voting intention in the EU referendum and her likelihood of not reporting various items pertaining to her economic circumstances. Leave status does not appear to be correlated with the likelihood of reporting these items.Footnote 12 Finally, in section C in the appendix, we document the geographical distribution of wealth (at the LSOA level) and its distribution across several individual characteristics. As Figure C.1 shows, property wealth is not confined to London; it displays greater variance across the country. Additionally, Figures C.3 and C.4 provide supportive evidence that wealth is not confined to the economically active but is positively correlated with age and education. Further suggestive of the idea that there is no predefined beneficiary of Brexit, in Figure C.2 we report the fact that there are no differences in personal wealth across Remain or Leave voters.

Based on these measures, we model the relationship between an individual's wealth and her support for Brexit in the BES sample as follows:

(1)$${\rm Leave} = \alpha + \beta _1{\rm Financial\;Wealth} + \beta _2{\rm Property\;Wealth} + \beta _3{\vector X} + \epsilon $$

where X is a vector of covariates that includes respondents' disposable income, age, gender, education, working and marital status, authoritarian values and location based on Office for National Statistics area classifications (to control for the possible effects of area on wealth and Brexit support).Footnote 13

Estimates from Equation 1 may, however, be biased if there are systematic differences in wealthy voters' unobserved characteristics that are correlated with higher support for Leave. We address this concern by modelling unobserved, time-invariant individual-level heterogeneity in the BoE panel dataset. We are able to estimate Leave support for each individual i at time t as follows:

(2)$${\rm Leav}{\rm e}_{it} = \gamma _1{\rm Financial\;Wealt}{\rm h}_{it} + \gamma _2{\rm Property\;Wealt}{\rm h}_{it} + \gamma _3{\vector X}_{it} + \xi _i + \lambda _t + \upsilon _{it}$$

where, in addition to equation 1, we account for individual ξ i and time λ t specific effects.Footnote 14

Results: British Election Study

Main Effects

Starting with the cross-sectional estimates in the BES sample, Table 2 reveals the importance of accounting for respondents' wealth to understand their support for Brexit. The wealth measures are standardized to mean 0 and one standard deviation (because respondents may experience financial shortages once accounting for outgoing payments or debts). Hence, the coefficients are interpretable as a standard deviation increase in the intention to vote Leave. We also report the wealth effects visually in Fig. 2.

Table 2. Wealth effect on leave support (BES)

Note: The dependent variable and leave vote intention, is binary (1 = Leave). Compared to model (1), model (2) includes controls for disposable income, gender, age, education, marital status, employment status, authoritarian values, and respondents’ location based on the ONS Super Area Group classification. The reference categories are as follows: Gender: male, Education: not enrolled in HE, ONS Area: Affluent England. Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Figure 2. Wealth increases leave support.

Note: The dependent variable, leave vote intention, is binary (1 = Leave). Controls include household-adjusted disposable income, gender, age, education, marital status, employment status, authoritarian values, and respondents' location based on the ONS Super Area Group classification (95% confidence intervals).

Financial wealth does not seem to account for Remain or Leave support, whereas a standard deviation increase in property wealth increases Leave support by 1.3–2.7 percentage points. Since property wealth is significantly higher in the UK than financial wealth, these differences are expected, as our foregoing discussion showed.Footnote 15 Overall, the effects are substantively important; they run in the opposite direction to those assumed in ‘left-behind’ accounts, including running in a counter direction to results at the aggregate level (Adler and Ansell Reference Adler and Ansell2020; Ansell Reference Ansell2019). In effect size terms, the effect can be benchmarked against the closeness of the referendum, tilted in favour of Leave by less than a 4 per cent difference, and by the effect sizes for other commonly cited variables, household income (as shown in Table 2), and also against the real-world size of increases in property wealth, which – in the UK case – has risen by an average of 8 percentage points over the five year period that preceded Brexit (Office for National Statistics, 2021).

Mechanism

The property wealth effect could be due to a couple of factors that relate to wealthy respondents' expectations of the economic impact of Brexit. Consistent with our insurance argument, we expect that wealthier respondents are more likely to consider that they will be unaffected economically by Britain's departure from the EU. Figure 3 explores how national and personal economic situation evaluations vary by property wealth in predicting ‘no change’ in economic circumstances.Footnote 16 Consistent with our expectations, wealthier respondents are more likely to think that Brexit will bring no change to their own economic circumstances. However, that is not true about their beliefs about the national outcomes – denoted by a flat line across the wealth distribution.

Figure 3. Expectations of Brexit effect on national vs personal finances (BES).

Note: The dependent variable is binary and takes the value 1 if the respondent believes leaving the EU will have no effect on her national or personal circumstances. Property wealth is denoted by the respondents' home value, standardized to mean 0 and standard deviation 1 (95% confidence intervals).

Aggregate and Individual-Level

Our results are, as discussed, different from aggregate-level patterns that identify the geographic relationship between wealth and higher Remain support. In what follows, we report the extent to which aggregate-level results may be unable to detect greater individual-level variations in wealth. We exploit BES data linkage to contextual data on median home prices at the Lower Super Output Areas (LSOA) level. We identify respondents who live in low-priced LSOA areas (below average median home prices) versus those in a high-priced LSOA area. The bottom panel of Figure E.1 in the online supplementary material replicates the results from the existing literature, showing that individuals living in wealthier areas are more supportive of Remain. However, we find a positive association between property wealth and Leave support when we explore the individual wealth effect, as in the top panel. Therefore, we explore heterogeneity in individual wealth by low- and high-priced LSOA areas in appendix Figure E.2. Consistent with Figure E.1 and prospect theory, we find evidence that poorer areas were more likely to support Brexit. However, within areas, wealthier individuals were more likely to support Brexit. We therefore contribute to the literature by providing evidence that, despite local conditions, personal wealth informs and increases Brexit support. These results suggest that higher sociotropic wealth is associated with higher Remain support, but individual-level wealth is associated with higher Leave support.

Results: Bank of England Data

Main Effects

We proceed by exploring changes in wealth and related preferences over time. This allows us to account for all time-invariant unobserved individual-level characteristics, such as Britishness, xenophobia, education, etc. Table 3 reports significant wealth effects on Leave support, accounting for individual-specific, unobserved characteristics. A standard deviation increase in property wealth increases Leave support by as much as 7.1 percentage points. We also report the wealth effects visually in Fig. 4.

Table 3. Wealth effect on leave support (BoE)

Note: The dependent variable is binary (1 = Leaver). Compared with model (1), model (2) includes controls for age, age squared, education, employment status, and respondent's location. The reference categories are as follows: Education: not in higher education, Region: East Anglia. Clustered robust standard errors in parentheses. ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.

Figure 4. Wealth increases leave support.

Note: The dependent variable is binary (1 = Leaver). All models include controls for age, age squared, education, employment status, and respondent's location. Models include time and individual fixed effects (95% confidence intervals).

Contrary to the cross-sectional results in Fig. 2, a standard deviation change in financial wealth also increases Leave support, though its effect is half that of property wealth. This is in line with expectations pertaining to the higher absolute value of property rather than financial wealth and also shows how different types of wealth could be more or less insuring, given the economic and political context.

Mechanism

Similar to the BES data, in Fig. 5, we explore how evaluations of national and personal economic situations vary by property wealth by predicting ‘no change’ in economic circumstances. The figure paints a similar picture to that displayed using the BES data in Fig. 3; higher wealth positively correlates with an increase in expectations of no personal economic change.Footnote 17

Figure 5. Expectations of Brexit effect on national vs personal finances (BoE).

Note: The dependent variable is binary and takes the value 1 if the respondent believes that the next 12 months will have no effect on national or her personal circumstances. Prospective evaluations are available for 2016–2018, and results are pooled across all respondents. Property wealth is denoted by the respondents' home value, standardized to mean 0 and standard deviation 1 (95% confidence intervals).

Results: Survey Experiment

We complement this observational evidence by using a survey experiment that provides a hypothetical wealth treatment.Footnote 18 In addition to bolstering our confidence in the relationship between wealth and Brexit support, we use this experimental approach to test whether a wealth win decreases risk aversion, as specified in hypothesis 3. The experiment was fielded in BES Wave 19 in the post-election survey in December 2019.

First, the experiment randomizes respondents into a treatment group with a hypothetical wealth win and a control group. Each treatment condition then receives a question about their Brexit preference and willingness to take risks. In total, there are four groups: a control group who were only asked about their Brexit preference, a treatment group who received a hypothetical wealth win and asked about their Brexit preference (the Brexit Support Treatment), a control group who were only asked their risk aversion, and a treatment group who received a hypothetical wealth win and then requested their risk aversion (the Willingness to Take Risk Treatment). The protocol is described in Table 4. To measure risk aversion, we rely on a two-question battery of questions proposed by Barsky et al. (Reference Barsky1997) to capture financial risk-taking. Similar questions have since been used in the Cooperative Congressional Election Study and the 1996 Panel Study of Income Dynamics, which have been validated in various contexts (Eckles et al. Reference Eckles2014; Hryshko, Luengo-Prado, and Sørensen Reference Hryshko, Luengo-Prado and Sørensen2011; Pahontu Reference Pahontu2020). Around 15,000 people participated in the experiment, about half of them receiving the Brexit Support Treatment and the other half receiving the Willingness to Take Risk Treatment. Figure D4 in the supplementary material gives us confidence that randomization was successful across all relevant observables.

Table 4. Experimental conditions and outcome wording

Main Effect

The BES and Bank of England results have accounted for the effect of levels and changes in wealth on Brexit support. To complement this evidence, in Fig. 6 we report the treatment effect of a hypothetical £1 million home win on the respondent's satisfaction with the UK's vote to leave the EU, as noted in Table 4.

Figure 6. Wealth increases leave support.

Note: The dependent variable is measured on a scale from 0 to 10 (10 = Leave). This question is one of two randomized outcomes that were asked of the treatment and control group. The treatment group received a hypothetical wealth win. Full results in Table D.1 (95% confidence intervals).

Consistent with the observational data, property wealth increases satisfaction with Brexit by 0.2 to 0.25 on the scale, equivalent to a 4 per cent increase compared to the control. A ‘hypothetical’ wealth increase would not be sufficient evidence of wealth's effect on voting for Brexit. However, in combination with evidence from two separate data sets, this evidence gives us greater confidence in our conclusions.

Mechanism: Wealth and Risk Aversion

The observational evidence is consistent with the proposed insurance based mechanism that wealthier respondents enjoy in their support for Brexit. We also argued that the mechanism through which wealth increases Brexit support is via wealth's effect on reducing risk aversion. Like Pahontu (Reference Pahontu2020), we test whether the insurance provided by the respondents' wealth reduces their risk aversion, thereby allowing those with underlying preferences to support a change in the status quo. Looking at the results in Fig. 7, we notice a substantial and significant increase in risk-taking among the treated, equivalent to a 5% increase in risk-taking behaviour. This is a very similar effect magnitude as in the case of Brexit support from Fig. 6.

Figure 7. Wealth treatment decreases risk aversion.

Note: The dependent variable is measured on a scale from 0 to 3 (3 = risk averse). This question is one of two randomized outcomes that were asked of the treatment and control group. The treatment group received a hypothetical wealth win. Full results in Table D.2 (95% confidence intervals).

Taken together, the observational and experimental evidence increases our confidence that the mechanism linking wealth to Brexit support works through insurance and risk aversion; this insurance and lower risk aversion allows individuals to support a change to the status quo – in this case, Brexit.

Conclusion

It is well-established that wealth provides self-insurance against economic risks, cushioning individuals from possible income shocks and other risks (Ansell Reference Ansell2014; Ehrlich and Becker Reference Ehrlich and Becker1972; Tertytchnaya and De Vries Reference Tertytchnaya and De Vries2019). Consequently, wealth leads to lower risk aversion (Pahontu Reference Pahontu2020; Zanetti Reference Zanetti2014). Despite these observations, the role of wealth has gone unstudied as a mechanism that enables voters to opt for more risky political propositions, such as large-scale changes to the status quo where voters offset costs, benefits, and risks.

Studying the effect of wealth in the Brexit case, we demonstrate that variation in personal wealth – especially property wealth – enables wealthier individuals to support Brexit and less wealthy individuals to support Remain. We provide evidence that the mechanism linking wealth and higher Leave support comes via wealthy voters' expectations that Brexit would not impact their personal finances; we also show that an increase in wealth lowers risk aversion. We explore these relationships using a rare combination of observational and experimental data across three separate contexts that include individual-level measures of wealth: a large cross-sectional electoral study, a separate panel study accounting for unobserved individual-level heterogeneity, and the use of a survey experiment. We also provide evidence that these results run contrary to aggregate-level relationships, although these findings could be complementary. We propose that wealth enables individuals to support Brexit and that sociotropic concerns also matter. This explains why our conclusions differ from those of studies of contextual economic effects on support for Brexit (Carreras Reference Carreras2019; Colantone and Stanig Reference Colantone and Stanig2018; Fetzer Reference Fetzer2019). People living in left-behind areas were more likely to support Brexit than those living in prosperous areas. The gains of Brexit were perceived to be greater in areas of the country that had experienced economic decline (Carreras Reference Carreras2019). But within those areas, given people's preferences, we show that wealthier individuals were more likely to vote for Brexit, and poorer individuals were more likely to vote for Remain. This individual-level finding is new and important for the Brexit case, which has otherwise focused on the economic determinants of preferences for Brexit rather than the role of wealth in economic risks.

Our research design, relying on observational cross-sectional panel data and experimental data, allows us to validate our results across three separate datasets and increases confidence in the validity and magnitude of the causal estimate of wealth on Brexit support. While studies on Brexit rely almost exclusively on cross-sectional comparisons, leaving room for endogeneity concerns, we are the first to identify (to the best of our knowledge), at the individual level, a causal estimate of wealth on Brexit support. We do so by exploiting the time dimension in Bank of England panel data and relying on a random variation in hypothetical wealth. We also offer a novel test of the individual-level mechanisms in the observational and experimental data.

Our findings imply that, while many poorer individuals may have held a preference for Leave, they were less likely to vote for Brexit given their lack of economic insurance. Walter (Reference Walter2021) questions why the British were willing to risk potentially imposing enormous economic self-harm on themselves. Our analysis shows that poorer individuals likely recognized a risk of economic self-harm due to their lack of economic insurance. These findings underline the importance of examining causal effects at the individual level alongside broader trends at the aggregate level. They are also important for understanding Brexit's long-term political and electoral implications. Support for Brexit might have been higher still had fewer poorer voters not perceived the economic risks associated with their lack of insurance. If the outcomes of Brexit are damaging to those who lack the insurance to withstand personal economic shocks, support for this political project may be significantly weakened.

How might our findings generalize from the Brexit case and the context of Great Britain? One variation point may be the relative importance of financial and property wealth and the ability of different types of wealth to be more or less insuring. In Britain, owning a home has become an especially reliable form of wealth. Brexit was the type of shock that would most likely disturb the economy over the long term. In future applications of a ‘wealth-as-insurance’ lens in political behaviour, it would be useful to consider the possibility that different forms of economic insurance might be more important in different contexts. Our findings may apply more broadly where political choices over changes substantially affect the economy. This applies to other referenda on national secession. It may also apply if nations confront periods of economic instability due to a different kind of democratic choice. For example, it may apply to initiatives that change existing economic models motivated by decarbonization, which entails substantial economic instability. Wealthier voters may be more able to vote with their preferences over climate change reduction and support a party and its policies because they are insured against the immediate economic consequences.

The general implications of our findings are normative, theoretical, and empirical. While there is a considerable amount of research on the relationship between inequality and redistributive preferences, we show that poorer voters do not just have different political preferences; they also lack the insurance to act on some of those preferences. Economic inequalities create inequalities in experience, preferences, and political risk-taking. Finally, supporting other research advocating for the unique role of wealth, in addition to standard predictors of economic voting (Lewis-Beck and Nadeau Reference Lewis-Beck and Nadeau2011; Nadeau, Foucault, and Lewis-Beck Reference Nadeau, Foucault and Lewis-Beck2011; Nadeau, Lewis-Beck, and Foucault Reference Nadeau, Lewis-Beck and Foucault2019), we have shown how it is important to measure economic positions in different ways, how income and wealth are weakly correlated, and, as a result, how wealth will lead to different substantive conclusions than a focus only on income. Our findings show the importance of wealth for understanding political behaviour in a new and potentially important way. By providing insurance, wealth cushions individuals from the economic risks associated with a vote for a major change to the status quo.

Supplementary Material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123423000728.

Data availability statement

Replication data for this article can be found in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/LOGVPZ.

Acknowledgements

We thank the editor and the anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments. We are grateful for the helpful feedback provided by Pablo Beramendi, Jean-François Daoust, Andy Eggers, Tim Hicks, Rob Johns, David Rueda, and seminar participants at the Universities of Montreal, Essex, the Early Career Workshop hosted by the University of Southampton, and discussions at the Bank of England. Jane Green thanks colleagues in the British Election Study team, with whom survey measures were devised.

Financial support

This work was supported by the Economic and Social Research Council funding for the British Election Study (Award ES/K005294/1) and from support provided by Nuffield College.

Competing interests

None.

Ethics standards

The research was conducted in accordance with the protocols for the British Election Study approved by the University of Manchester, UK.

Footnotes

1 In a risky situation one can assign probabilities to the various possible outcomes, whereas in a case of uncertainty one is unable to identify the relevant probabilities. Similar to Baderin and Barnes (Reference Baderin and Barnes2020), we use risk in this paper to denote intermediate cases, that are neither instances of pure risk nor of pure uncertainty.

2 Savings and home ownership ensure forms of wealth. This is in contrast to higher-risk market speculation, which is far more uncommon (Alan Reference Alan2006). Market speculation is more likely for those who have secure forms of wealth to fall back on, such that individuals with greater wealth are insured against risks (Vestman Reference Vestman2019).

3 A further distinction can be made between the economic security afforded by liquid wealth in the form of savings and illiquid wealth in the form of assets. Liquid wealth, readily available savings (net of debts), may compensate for short-term income losses, smoothing consumption in the short term. This logic is illustrated by Hariri, Jensen, and Lassen (Reference Hariri, Jensen and Lassen2020), who show that a lack of savings, as opposed to holding assets, explains support for social insurance policies in Denmark. More generally, however, asset-based and liquid wealth have been shown to offer a considerable psychological benefit to an individual (Kendall, Nguyen, and Ong Reference Kendall, Nguyen and Ong2019).

4 For the UK, see Banks, Blundell, and Smith (Reference Banks, Blundell and Smith2002); Crawford, Innes, and O'Dea (Reference Crawford, Innes and O'Dea2016). See Causa, Woloszko, and Leite (Reference Causa, Woloszko and Leite2019) for comparative evidence. The mean (median) UK property wealth is £85,000 (£50,000), in contrast to £28,000 (£4,000) in savings (Crawford, Innes, and O'Dea Reference Crawford, Innes and O'Dea2016).

5 Note that our analysis shows that Leavers are not wealthier (or significantly poorer) than Remain voters. We demonstrate this in Fig. C.2.

6 John Curtice (2016 ) How Deeply Does Britain's Euroscepticism Run? British Social Attitudes 33; Prosser, Mellon and Green (2016) What Mattered Most to You When Deciding How to Vote in the EU Referendum? British Elections Study Blog.

7 Authors' own calculations based on the raw post-EU referendum British Election Study data (Fieldhouse et al. Reference Fieldhouse2016), weighted for national representativeness.

8 See Fieldhouse et al. (Reference Fieldhouse2018) for further information about BES Wave 14 and Anderson et al. (Reference Anderson2016) about the Bank of England survey. BES data collection, in which our experiment is also conducted, is subject to ethical approval at the University of Manchester. Data are collected by YouGov, who compensate respondents with points redeemed in payments according to YouGov processes on numbers (and lengths) of surveys completed. Note that no wealth data existed prior to the EU referendum, where EU referendum preferences were included.

9 Although the data was collected after the referendum, we were reassured of the validity of our analysis as individuals' support for Brexit remained stable over time (Grynberg, Walter, and Wasserfallen Reference Grynberg, Walter and Wasserfallen2020). In fact, in BES data, about 97 per cent of people and in BoE about 90 per cent of others maintained their preference across time.

10 We exclude the undecided from the analysis and note that Brexit preferences are relatively stable over time (Grynberg, Walter, and Wasserfallen Reference Grynberg, Walter and Wasserfallen2020).

11 In our analysis, we control for whether a respondent owns their home, with or without a mortgage, and the results remain robust.

12 Leavers appear less likely to report their home value. In order to address this, we report the robustness of our results in Fig. D.1 by including those who answered ‘do not know’ in the regression.

13 Established area classifications are produced using the 2011 Census and define areas by their economic activity, density, and ethnic diversity.

14 This specification not only allows us to have a better claim at identifying a causal effect of wealth on the Leave vote, but allows us to account for the polarization in attitudes that happened as a result of the EU referendum.

15 We explore the robustness of our results in Fig. D.2 to two alternative explanations correlated with support for Leave, the risk of unemployment and Euroscepticism.

16 There may be greater heterogeneity in preferences among the wealthy such that, for example, they expect personal economic circumstances to improve after Brexit. We explore this possibility in Fig. D.3 and found no evidence that wealthier individuals expected circumstances to improve. However, as Fig. 3 shows, we find evidence that they expected no change in circumstances, consistent with an insurance mechanism.

17 An alternative narrative could suggest that wealthier voters expect their properties to appreciate in value following Britain's exit from the European Union. We entertained this possibility in Fig. D.5 across the property wealth distribution, but we do not find supportive evidence of this mechanism.

18 The hypothetical nature of this treatment ensures that the respondents are not deceived.

References

Abadie, A, Diamond, A, and Hainmueller, J (2015) Comparative politics and the synthetic control method. American Journal of Political Science 59(2), 495510.10.1111/ajps.12116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, D and Ansell, B (2020) Housing and populism. West European Politics 43(2), 344–65.10.1080/01402382.2019.1615322CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aladangady, A (2017) Housing wealth and consumption: Evidence from geographically-linked microdata. American Economic Review 107(11), 3415–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alan, S (2006) Entry costs and stock market participation over the life cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics 9(4), 588611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, RM and Franklin, CH (1994) Uncertainty and political perceptions. Journal of Politics 56(3), 671–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, G et al. (2016) The Bank of England/NMG survey of household finances. Fiscal Studies 37(1), 131–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ando, A and Modigliani, F (1963) The ‘life cycle’ hypothesis of saving: Aggregate implications and tests. The American Economic Review 53(1), 5584.Google Scholar
Ansell, B (2014) The political economy of ownership: Housing markets and the welfare state. American Political Science Review 108(2), 383402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansell, B (2019) The politics of housing. Annual Review of Political Science 22, 165–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atikcan, EO, Nadeau, R, and Belanger, E (2020) Framing Risky Choices: Brexit and the Dynamics of High-Stakes Referendums. Canada: McGill-Queen's University Press.Google Scholar
Autor, D et al. (2019) Importing Political Polarization? The Electoral Consequences of Rising Trade Exposure. Available from https://www.nber.org/papers/w22637 (accessed 30 January 2024).Google Scholar
Baderin, A and Barnes, L (2020) Risk and self-respect. British Journal of Political Science 50(4), 1419–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, J, Blundell, R, and Smith, JP (2002) Wealth portfolios in the UK and the US. National Bureau of Economic Research. Available from https://www.nber.org/papers/w9128 (accessed on 30 January 2024).Google Scholar
Barsky, RB et al. (1997) Preference parameters and behavioral heterogeneity: An experimental approach in the health and retirement study. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 537–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bobo, LD (2017) Racism in Trump's America: Reflections on culture, sociology, and the 2016 US presidential election. The British Journal of Sociology 68, S85S104.10.1111/1468-4446.12324CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Born, B et al. (2019) The costs of economic nationalism: Evidence from the Brexit experiment. The Economic Journal 129(623), 2722–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breinlich, H et al. (2017) The Consequences of the Brexit Vote for UK Inflation and Living Standards: First Evidence. CEP Technical Report. Available from https://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/brexit11_technical_paper.pdf (accessed 30 January 2024).Google Scholar
Browning, M and Crossley, TF (2001) The life-cycle model of consumption and saving. Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(3), 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browning, M, Chiappori, P-A, and Lewbel, A (2013) Estimating consumption economies of scale, adult equivalence scales, and household bargaining power. Review of Economic Studies 80, 12671303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, MR and Iversen, T (2020) The welfare state with private alternatives: The transformation of popular support for social insurance. The Journal of Politics 82(2), 671–86.10.1086/706980CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carreras, M (2019) What do we have to lose? Local economic decline, prospect theory, and support for Brexit. Electoral Studies 62, 102094.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carreras, M, Irepoglu Carreras, Y, and Bowler, S (2019) Long-term economic distress, cultural backlash, and support for Brexit. Comparative Political Studies 52(9), 13961424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Causa, O, Woloszko, N, and Leite, D (2019) Housing, Wealth Accumulation and Wealth Distribution: Evidence and Stylized Facts. Available from https://www.oecd.org/officialdocuments/publicdisplaydocumentpdf/?cote=ECO/WKP(2019)58%docLanguage=En (accessed 30 January 2024).Google Scholar
Chrisp, J and Pearce, N (2019) Grey power: Towards a political economy of older voters in the UK. The Political Quarterly 90(4), 743–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, HD, Goodwin, M, and Whiteley, P (2017) Brexit: Why Britain Voted to Leave the European Union. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colantone, I and Stanig, P (2018) Global competition and Brexit. American Political Science Review 112(2), 201–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conley, D and Gifford, B (2006) Home ownership, social insurance, and the welfare state. Sociological Forum 21(1), 55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, R, Innes, D, and O'Dea, C (2016) Household wealth in Great Britain: Distribution, composition and changes 2006–12. Fiscal Studies 37(1), 3554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Vries, CE (2018) Euroscepticism and The Future of European Integration. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhingra, S et al. (2017) The costs and benefits of leaving the EU: Trade effects. Economic Policy 32(92), 651705.10.1093/epolic/eix015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donkers, B, Melenberg, B, and Van Soest, A (2001) Estimating risk attitudes using lotteries: A large sample approach. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 22(2), 165–95.10.1023/A:1011109625844CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dupuis, A and Thorns, DC (1998) Home, home ownership and the search for ontological security. The Sociological Review 46(1), 2447.10.1111/1467-954X.00088CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckles, DL et al. (2014) Risk attitudes and the incumbency advantage. Political Behavior 36(4), 731–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, I and Becker, GS (1972) Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. Journal of Political Economy 80(4), 623–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, G and Menon, A (2017) Brexit and British Politics. Cambridge, UK: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Fetzer, T (2019) Did austerity cause Brexit? American Economic Review 109(11), 3849–86.10.1257/aer.20181164CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fieldhouse, E et al. (2016) British Election Study Internet Panel Wave 9.Google Scholar
Fieldhouse, E et al. (2018) British Election Study Internet Panel Wave 14.Google Scholar
Fieldhouse, E et al. (2021) Electoral Shocks: The Volatile Voter in A Turbulent World. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fiorina, MP (1977) An outline for a model of party choice. American Journal of Political Science 21(3), 601–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, MP (1981) Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Heaven, USA: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Ford, R and Goodwin, MJ (2014) Revolt on the Right: Explaining Support for the Radical Right in Britain. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franklin, CH (1991) Eschewing obfuscation? Campaigns and the perception of US Senate incumbents. American Political Science Review 85(4), 11931214.10.2307/1963942CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J and de Geus, R (2022) Red wall, red herring? Economic insecurity and voter intention in Britain. Available at https://politicscentre.nuffield.ox.ac.uk/media/5142/nprc-econ-insecurity-report_bridges_final.pdf (accessed 30 January 2024).Google Scholar
Green, J and Pahontu, RL (2024) Replication Data for: Mind the Gap: Why Wealthy Voters Support Brexit. Available from https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/LOGVPZ, Harvard Dataverse, V1 (accessed 30 January 2024).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J, Hellwig, T and Fieldhouse, E (2022) Who gets what: The economy, relative gains, and Brexit. British Journal of Political Science 52(1), 320–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grynberg, C, Walter, S, and Wasserfallen, F (2020) Expectations, vote choice and opinion stability since the 2016 Brexit referendum. European Union Politics 21(2), 255–75.10.1177/1465116519892328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, L and Paiella, M (2008) Risk aversion, wealth, and background risk. Journal of the European Economic Association 6(6), 1109–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, JS (2019) The Great Risk Shift: The New Economic Insecurity and the Decline of the American Dream. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hariri, JG, Jensen, AS, and Lassen, DD (2020) Middle class without a net: Savings, financial fragility, and preferences over social insurance. Comparative Political Studies 53(6), 892922.10.1177/0010414019879718CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hierro, MJ and Queralt, D (2021) The divide over independence: Explaining preferences for secession in an advanced open economy. American Journal of Political Science 65(2), 422–42.10.1111/ajps.12549CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hilt, E and Rahn, WM (2020) Financial asset ownership and political partisanship: Liberty bonds and Republican electoral success in the 1920s. The Journal of Economic History 80(3), 746–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobolt, SB (2009) Europe in Question: Referendums on European Integration. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobolt, SB (2016) The Brexit vote: A divided nation, a divided continent. Journal of European Public Policy 23(9), 1259–77.10.1080/13501763.2016.1225785CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hryshko, D, Luengo-Prado, MJ, and Sørensen, BE (2011) Childhood determinants of risk aversion: The long shadow of compulsory education. Quantitative Economics 2(1), 3772.10.3982/QE2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iakhnis, E et al. (2018) Populist referendum: Was ‘Brexit’ an expression of nativist and anti-elitist sentiment? Research & Politics 5(2). https://doi.org/10.1177/2053168018773964CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kendall, GE, Nguyen, H, and Ong, R (2019) The association between income, wealth, economic security perception, and health: A longitudinal Australian study. Health Sociology Review 28(1), 2038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis-Beck, MS and Nadeau, R (2011) Economic voting theory: Testing New dimensions. Electoral Studies 30(2), 288–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis-Beck, MS, Nadeau, R, and Foucault, M (2013) The complete economic voter: New theory and British evidence. British Journal of Political Science 43(2), 241–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liñeira, R and Henderson, A (2021) Risk attitudes and independence vote choice. Political Behavior 43(2), 541–60.10.1007/s11109-019-09560-xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malmendier, U and Nagel, S (2011) Depression babies: Do macroeconomic experiences affect risk-taking? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1), 373416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masatlioglu, Y and Ok, EA (2005) Rational choice with status quo bias. Journal of Economic Theory 121(1), 129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, KO and Wallerstein, M (2001) Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American Political Science Review 95(4), 859–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenstern, S and Zechmeister, E (2001) Better the devil you know than the saint you don't? Risk propensity and vote choice in Mexico. Journal of Politics 63(1), 93119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morisi, D (2018) Choosing the risky option: Information and risk propensity in referendum campaigns. Public Opinion Quarterly 82(3), 447469.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mudde, C (2010) The populist radical right: A pathological normalcy. West European Politics 33(6), 1167–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutz, DC (2018) Status threat, not economic hardship, explains the 2016 presidential vote. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 115(19), E4330E4339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadeau, R, Martin, P, and Blais, A (1999) Attitude towards risk-taking and individual choice in the Quebec referendum on sovereignty. British Journal of Political Science 29(3), 523–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadeau, R, Foucault, M, and Lewis-Beck, MS (2011) Assets and risk: A neglected dimension of economic voting. French Politics 9(2), 97119.10.1057/fp.2011.5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nadeau, R, Lewis-Beck, MS, and Foucault, M (2019) Wealth and voter turnout: Investigating twenty-eight democracies. Polity 51(2), 261–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, P and Inglehart, R (2019) Cultural Backlash: Trump, Brexit, and the Rise of Authoritarian Populism. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Office for National Statistics (2021) UK House Price Index. Statistical Bulletin.Google Scholar
O'Grady, T (2019) How Do economic circumstances determine preferences? Evidence from long-run panel data. British Journal of Political Science 49(4), 13811406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pahontu, RL (2020) The Democrat Disaster: Hurricane Exposure, Risk Aversion and Insurance Demand. Available from https://www.ssrn.com/abstract=3515282 (accessed 30 January 2024).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paravisini, D, Rappoport, V, and Ravina, E (2017) Risk aversion and wealth: Evidence from person-to-person lending portfolios. Management Science 63(2), 279–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rehm, P, Hacker, JS, and Schlesinger, M (2012) Insecure alliances: Risk, inequality, and support for the welfare state. American Political Science Review 106(2), 386406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ronald, R and Doling, J (2012) Testing home ownership as the cornerstone of welfare: Lessons from East Asia for the West. Housing Studies 27(7), 940–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rueda, D and Stegmueller, D (2016) The externalities of inequality: Fear of crime and preferences for redistribution in Western Europe. American Journal of Political Science 60(2), 472–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, W and Zeckhauser, R (1988) Status Quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 1(1), 759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schaffner, BF, MacWilliams, M, and Nteta, T (2018) Hostile sexism, racism denial, and the historic education Gap in support for Trump. In Cavari, A, Powell, RJ, and Mayer, KR (eds), The 2016 Presidential Election: The Causes and Consequences of a Political Earthquake. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, pp. 99116.Google Scholar
Sobolewska, M and Ford, R (2020) Brexitland: Identity, Diversity and the Reshaping of British Politics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steenbergen, MR and Siczek, T (2017) Better the devil you know? Risk-taking, globalization and populism in Great Britain. European Union Politics 18(1), 119–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tertytchnaya, K and De Vries, CE (2019) The political consequences of self-insurance: Evidence from Central-Eastern Europe, the Caucasus and Central Asia. Political Behavior 41(4), 1047–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Hauwaert, SM and Van Kessel, S (2018) Beyond protest and discontent: A cross-national analysis of the effect of populist attitudes and issue positions on populist party support. European Journal of Political Research 57(1), 6892.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vestman, R (2019) Limited stock market participation among renters and homeowners. The Review of Financial Studies 32(4), 14941535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, S (2021) The backlash against globalization. Annual Review of Political Science 33, 421–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weller, CE (2007) Need or want: What explains the run-up in consumer debt? Journal of Economic Issues 41(2), 583–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, JH (2014) Economic security and home ownership. Social Work Research 38(1), 34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolff, EN (2010) Recent trends in household wealth in the United States: Rising debt and the middle-class squeeze-an update to 2007. Available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1585409, (accessed on 30 January 2024).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zanetti, F (2014) Housing and relative risk aversion. Economics Letters 123(1), 23–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Euroscepticism distribution among Remain voters.

Figure 1

Table 1. Wealth items

Figure 2

Table 2. Wealth effect on leave support (BES)

Figure 3

Figure 2. Wealth increases leave support.Note: The dependent variable, leave vote intention, is binary (1 = Leave). Controls include household-adjusted disposable income, gender, age, education, marital status, employment status, authoritarian values, and respondents' location based on the ONS Super Area Group classification (95% confidence intervals).

Figure 4

Figure 3. Expectations of Brexit effect on national vs personal finances (BES).Note: The dependent variable is binary and takes the value 1 if the respondent believes leaving the EU will have no effect on her national or personal circumstances. Property wealth is denoted by the respondents' home value, standardized to mean 0 and standard deviation 1 (95% confidence intervals).

Figure 5

Table 3. Wealth effect on leave support (BoE)

Figure 6

Figure 4. Wealth increases leave support.Note: The dependent variable is binary (1 = Leaver). All models include controls for age, age squared, education, employment status, and respondent's location. Models include time and individual fixed effects (95% confidence intervals).

Figure 7

Figure 5. Expectations of Brexit effect on national vs personal finances (BoE).Note: The dependent variable is binary and takes the value 1 if the respondent believes that the next 12 months will have no effect on national or her personal circumstances. Prospective evaluations are available for 2016–2018, and results are pooled across all respondents. Property wealth is denoted by the respondents' home value, standardized to mean 0 and standard deviation 1 (95% confidence intervals).

Figure 8

Table 4. Experimental conditions and outcome wording

Figure 9

Figure 6. Wealth increases leave support.Note: The dependent variable is measured on a scale from 0 to 10 (10 = Leave). This question is one of two randomized outcomes that were asked of the treatment and control group. The treatment group received a hypothetical wealth win. Full results in Table D.1 (95% confidence intervals).

Figure 10

Figure 7. Wealth treatment decreases risk aversion.Note: The dependent variable is measured on a scale from 0 to 3 (3 = risk averse). This question is one of two randomized outcomes that were asked of the treatment and control group. The treatment group received a hypothetical wealth win. Full results in Table D.2 (95% confidence intervals).

Supplementary material: File

Green and Pahontu supplementary material

Green and Pahontu supplementary material
Download Green and Pahontu supplementary material(File)
File 3.4 MB
Supplementary material: Link

Green and Pahontu Dataset

Link