Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-14T22:44:33.840Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Organizing of the European Parliament: Committees, Specialization and Co-ordination

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2009

Extract

This article addresses the issue of specialization and committee formation in the European Parliament in the light of the largely US-centred debates on these issues. Clear evidence is found of specialization of behaviour, both with regard to committee assignment and the use of parliamentary questions. This is also accompanied by a trend towards a greater role for the party groups in co-ordinating and controlling behaviour across these specializations.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Pinder, John, European Community: The Building of a Union (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991)Google Scholar; Spinelli, Altiero, The Eurocrats (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966).Google Scholar

2 Corbett, Richard, ‘Testing the New Procedures: The European Parliament's First Experiences with its New “Single Act” Powers’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 27 (1989), 359–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jacobs, Francis, Corbett, Richard and Shackleton, Michael, The European Parliament, 2nd edn (Harlow, Essex: Longman, 1992)Google Scholar; Lodge, Juliet, ‘The European Parliament–from “Assembly” to Co-Legislature: Changing the Institutional Dynamics’, in Lodge, Juliet, ed., The European Community and the Challenge of the Future (London: Pinter, 1989), 5879.Google Scholar

3 Attin´, F., ‘The Voting Behaviour of the European Parliament Members and the Problem of the Europarties’, European Journal of Political Research, 18 (1989), 557–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bardi, Luciano, Il Parlamento della Communità Europea (Bologna: II Mulino, 1989)Google Scholar; Bardi, Luciano, ‘Transnational Party Federations in the European Community’, in Katz, Richard S. and Mair, Peter, eds, Party Organizations: A Data Handbook on Party Organizations in Western Democracies, 1960–90 (London: Sage, 1992), pp. 931–73.Google Scholar

4 Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament.Google Scholar

5 Cooper, Joseph, The Origins of Standing Committees and the Development of the Modern House (Houston, Tex.: Rice University Press, 1970).Google Scholar

6 Tsebelis, George, ‘The Power of the European Parliament as a Conditional Agenda Setter’, American Political Science Review, 88 (1994), 128–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Tsebelis, George, Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics (Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1990).Google Scholar

8 Smith, Gordon, Politics in Western Europe, 5th edn (Aldershot, Hants: Gower, 1989), p. 207.Google Scholar

9 Ward, A., ‘Parliamentary Procedures and the Machinery of Government in Ireland’, Irish University Review, 4 (1974), 234–5.Google Scholar

10 Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B., ‘The Institutional Foundation of Committee Power’, American Political Science Review, 81 (1987), 85104CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Shepsle, K. and Weingast, B., ‘Why are Congressional Committees Powerful?’, American Political Science Review, 81 (1987), 935–45.Google Scholar

11 Krehbiel, Keith, Information and Legislative Organization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Krehbiel, Keith, ‘Where's the Party?’, British Journal of Political Science, 23 (1993), 256–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 Loewenberg, G., Parliament in the German Political System (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1967), p. 149.Google Scholar

13 Fitzmaurice, John, The Politics of Belgium (London: Hurst, 1983), p. 96.Google Scholar

14 Tsebelis, , ‘The Power of the European Parliament’.Google Scholar

15 For an exception, see Krehbiel, , ‘Where's the Party?’Google Scholar, which looks at parties in legislatures, as opposed to just individuals.

16 Cox and McCubbins develop an explanation of developments within the US Congress along similar lines. They seek to downplay the image of ‘committee government’ within the House and to place renewed emphasis on the ways in which parties manage the legislature as a whole, and specifically the ways in which the majority party manages the legislature, committee system included, to its own benefit. See Cox, G. and McCubbins, M., Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1993).Google Scholar

17 For comparative assessments of parliamentary committees, see Lees, J. D. and Shaw, M., eds, Committees in Legislatures (Oxford: Martin Robertson, 1979)Google Scholar; Norton, Philip, ‘Legislatures in Perspectives’, West European Politics, 13 (1990), 143–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Strom, K., ‘Minority Governments in Parliamentary Democracies: The Rationality of Non-Winning Cabinet Solutions’, Comparative Political Studies, 17 (1984), 199227CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Strom, K., Minority Governments and Majority Rules (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).Google Scholar

18 To an extent, it reflects the fact that (uniquely in Europe), to date, the Union's governmental system is characterized by a separated system of powers, allowing the EP greater freedom of action in running its own affairs. Whether this will be maintained in the future–and the recent decision in the Maastricht Treaty to grant the EP investiture powers over the Commission raises doubts–is debatable. See Bowler, Shaun and Farrell, David M., ‘The Internal Organization of the European Parliament’ (paper given at the Western Political Science Association, Pasadena, 1994).Google Scholar

19 Another way of assessing the importance of committees is to examine their role in the Union's policy process. See Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament.Google Scholar

20 Bowler, Shaun and Farrell, David M., ‘Legislator Shirking and Voter Monitoring: Impacts of European Parliament Electoral Systems upon Legislator-Voter Relationships’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 31 (1993), 4569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21 Even US Senators from some states in the upper Midwest can be said to have relatively small constituencies.

22 Weil, G., The Benelux Nations: The Politics of Small-Country Democracies (New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1970), p. 143.Google Scholar

21 The following discussion is based on three sets of data: an analysis of parliamentary questions in 1989; information on leadership and committee positions gathered from the EP's List of Members (Luxembourg: Official Publications, 19891991)Google Scholar; material on MEPs' personal backgrounds obtained from The Times Guide to the European Parliament (London: Times Publications, 1989)Google Scholar. The membership of the EP's committees is renewed in the mid-term. Therefore, this discussion relates to the first half of the 1989–94 term.

24 Krehbiel, , ‘Where's the Party?’Google Scholar

25 Unfortunately, we do not have the data to assess the degree of procedural protection enjoyed by EP committees, nor, for that matter, the issue of what happens to committee proposals on the floor of the House (i.e. at plenary). On the latter point, however, anecdotal evidence suggests that it is quite uncommon for committee proposals to be rejected or radically altered; certainly the absence of any attention to this question in the highly detailed study by Jacobs and his colleagues, suggests that it is generally uncontentious. If anything, the tendency in recent years, as described by these authors (all senior staff members), has been towards a more influential role for committees in the parliamentary process. Jacobs et at. describe two decision-making procedures which have been introduced as time-saving devices, but which have amounted to a growth in committee influence. First, committees, when presenting a report, increasingly request that it be adopted without debate at the plenary. Secondly, there is the Rule 37 procedure–derived from Italian legislative practice–which allows a report to be adopted by a committee on behalf of the EP and without involving a vote in plenary. According to Jacobs and his colleagues, the application of this rule has become more widespread in recent years. See. Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament, pp. 123–4.Google Scholar

26 See also Bowler, Shaun and Farrell, David M., ‘The Greens at the European Level’, Environmental Politics, 1 (1992), 132–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

27 Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament, p. 244.Google Scholar

28 Rules of Procedure of the European Parliament (Luxembourg: Official Publications, 1989), 24.2Google Scholar. For extended discussion of a similar process within the US Congress, see Cox, and McCubbins, , Legislative Leviathan.Google Scholar

29 Rules, 18.2.Google Scholar

30 Rules, 86–88.Google Scholar

31 Rules, 115.1.Google Scholar

32 Rules, 110.1.Google Scholar

33 Currently there are three subcommittees: Security and Disarmament (twenty-five members); Human Rights (twenty); Fisheries (twenty-four). In general, see Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament, chap. 7.Google Scholar

34 Rules, 111.Google Scholar

35 Rules of Procedure of the European Parliament (Luxembourg: Official Publications, 1972), 40.3.Google Scholar

36 Cocks, B., The European Parliament (London: HMSO, 1973), p. 118.Google Scholar

37 Rules, 1989, 111.1Google Scholar. This also formalized the rights to speak and vote; Rule 111.2 incorporated the earlier wording.

38 Loewenberg, , Parliament in the German Political System, p. 200.Google Scholar

39 That farmers are attracted to the Agriculture Committee may strike one as obvious: it is easily supported by impressionistic evidence. However, the fact is that we have shown this to be the case across the board, i.e. this is systematically the case across a range of committees and interests.

40 Of course, it is always possible that the committee membership is unable to agree on anything!

41 The fact that we accord a great deal of importance to the position of party groups as a co-ordinating mechanism suggests that we are in broad agreement with the approach of Cox, and McCubbins, (Legislative Leviathan)Google Scholar. However, the predominance of the majority party, which is a feature of their analysis, is not an issue here since the EP conforms more closely to mainland European, rather than Anglo-American, practice.

42 ‘Appoints’ is, perhaps, too simple a word for the actual process involved. The appointment of rapporteur usually involves a bidding process between groups which entails a points system, where each report is valued at a given number of points, and each group within the committee has a number of points to spend in bidding for rapporteurships. Rapporteurs are used in Belgium, the Netherlands and Italy, and have been used in the earlier French Republics. Rapporteurs are sometimes used in the German Bundestag (Section 70 of the Bundestag's Rules of Procedure), and they were common in the Imperial Reichstag. See DiPalma, G., ‘Institutional Rules and Legislative Outcomes in the Italian Parliament’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 1 (1976), 147–80Google Scholar; Krugar, F-K., Government and Politics of the German Empire (New York: World Books, 1915)Google Scholar; Meny, Y., Government and Politics in Western Europe: Britain, France, Italy and Germany (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990)Google Scholar; Sait, E., Government and Politics of France (New York: World Books, 1926)Google Scholar; Trossman, H., The German Bundestag: Organization and Operation (Neue Darmstadter Verlagsanstalt, 1965)Google Scholar; Weil, , The Benelux Nations.Google Scholar

43 It is a position which some rapporteurs have found difficult to deal with, and, hence, they were removed by a vote of the committee. In general, see Jacobs, et al. , The European Parliament, pp. 115 ff.Google Scholar