Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T09:28:11.428Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Rush to Personalize: Power Concentration after Failed Coups in Dictatorships

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 March 2023

Joan C. Timoneda*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, Purdue University, West Lafayette, IN, USA
Abel Escribà-Folch
Affiliation:
Department of Political and Social Sciences, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, and Institut Barcelona d'Estudis Internacionals, Barcelona, Catalonia, Spain
John Chin
Affiliation:
Institute for Politics and Strategy, Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA, USA
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: joan.timoneda@gmail.com
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

How do failed coups influence power personalization in dictatorships? While scholars have studied the mechanisms of personalism in dictatorships in detail, little attention has been paid to the timing and determinants of surges in personalism levels. In this article, we propose that personalism can evolve non-linearly, and show that large, quite rapid increases in personalization by dictators occur after a failed coup attempt. The logic is that failed coups are information-revealing events that provide the dictator with strong motives and ample opportunities to accumulate power. The leader uses this window of opportunity to rapidly consolidate his power at the expense of the ruling coalition. We test the theory using time-series, cross-sectional data on dictatorships in 114 countries in the period between 1946 and 2010. Two placebo tests indicate that disruptive events by regime outsiders – failed assassination attempts and civil war onsets – do not promote the rush to personalize.

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

Some dictators manage to usurp control of decision-making and political appointments at the expense of their top allies. Personalism, the result of this process, is a crucial underlying dimension of autocratic rule that varies across regimes and, importantly, can rise (or fall) during a dictator's tenure (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (GWF) 2018; Wright Reference Wright2021). Scholars have convincingly shown that personalist regimes lead to a panoply of dangers.Footnote 1 With elites increasingly unable to constrain them, these leaders often become more erratic, internationally belligerent, corrupt, and brutal. Muammar Gaddafi, Libya's former leader, for example, sponsored international terrorism, intervened militarily in Chad, sought to acquire nuclear weapons, and increasingly relied on extrajudicial executions and torture. He was eventually ousted (and killed) in a bloody civil war.

Far from being a Cold War relic, personalist rule is on the rise today (Kendall-Taylor, Frantz, and Wright Reference Kendall-Taylor, Frantz and Wright2017). However, our understanding of the conditions under which dictators such as Gaddafi manage to concentrate power is still limited; many questions linger about how and, especially, ‘when’ dictators personalize power. The main obstacle to dictators’ ambitions is that elites, interested in maintaining collegiality, try to deter them by staging (or threatening to stage) a coup. Accounts for the emergence of personalism must then provide explanations about how dictators can escape such control. Some suggest that dictators can circumvent it by concentrating power gradually through cumulative, subtle power grabs (Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Yet, many personalizing moves, such as appointing loyalists or creating paramilitary units, are highly noticeable to elites. Others focus on structural factors that put the dictator in an advantageous position vis-à-vis the elites, such as the conditions at the time the ruler takes over (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018; Meng Reference Meng2020; Sudduth Reference Sudduth2017), the availability of oil rents (Fails Reference Fails2019), or the support of foreign allies (Boutton Reference Boutton2019; Casey Reference Casey2020). These approaches, however, cannot inform us about the impact of contextual changes in internal power dynamics and, hence, about the timing of rapid, sharp increases in power concentration even years after the dictator seized power.

We address these gaps and claim that personalism can also emerge via punctuated equilibrium following certain disruptive events. In particular, we argue that failed coups – being overt and irregular challenges originating from inside the regime normally involving members of the security forces – are unique shocks that can usher in an advantageous context for visible and sharp increases in personalism. Coups thus represent ‘critical junctures’ (Capoccia and Kelemen Reference Capoccia and Kelemen2007) that, by altering the power dynamics between the dictator and the ruling coalition, reshape the political and institutional trajectories of the polities where they occur. By contrast, other threats emanating from outside the regime (such as failed assassination attempts and civil war onsets) do not create the same opportunities for dictators to rush to personalize.

In recent years, a lively scholarly debate has emerged about the potential democratizing effects of successful coups (Derpanopoulos et al. Reference Derpanopoulos2016; Marinov and Goemans Reference Marinov and Goemans2014; Miller Reference Miller2021; Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016; Varol Reference Varol2017). However, more often than not, coup makers fail to seize power. According to the Colpus dataset (Chin, Carter, and Wright Reference Chin, Carter and Wright2021), about half of all coup attempts staged since 1946 failed to unseat the incumbents. Despite this, and the fact that nearly three-quarters of coup attempts occur in dictatorships, scholars have only started to examine the consequences of failed coups. A few prior studies explored how failed coups influenced outcomes such as state repression and elite purges (Bokobza et al. Reference Bokobza2022; Curtice and Arnon Reference Curtice and Arnon2020; Oztig and Donduran Reference Oztig and Donduran2020). Less attention was paid to whether failed coups can have lasting consequences that reshape the nature, power distribution, and functioning of autocratic regimes.

After failed coups, some suggest that dictators will broaden their coalition to placate opposition (Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016), while others show that a regime change rarely follows a failed attempt (Derpanopoulos et al. Reference Derpanopoulos2016). In contrast, we argue that failed coups can (and often do) lead dictators to transform the structure of autocratic regimes in the opposite direction, a power accumulation process that research, using data on full regime transitions (to democracy or a new dictatorship) or repression, cannot capture. Specifically, we posit that failed coups in autocratic regimes act as strong contingent catalysts of personalization.

Consider, again, the case of Libya. In September 1969, a group of young army officers led by Muammar Gaddafi toppled the ruling monarchy in a coup. Gaddafi initially ruled as the chairman of a collegial body, the Revolutionary Command Council (RCC), which had twelve members, all of whom were military officers whose membership remained more or less fixed through the mid-1970s. In 1972, Gaddafi relinquished the premiership to another RCC member, Major Jallud: In 1974, Gaddafi even gave up his remaining administrative portfolio to focus on revolutionary theorizing. Though he remained the armed forces’ commander-in-chief, Gaddafi's power appeared to be on the wane (Berry Reference Berry and Metz1989, 45–6). This dynamic completely changed in 1975, when an anti-Qaddafi RCC faction and several army officers organized a coup that failed. Gaddafi's reaction was swift and drastic. He proceeded to marginalize the RCC, the regime's official party since 1971, and the Arab Socialist Union (ASU), the two institutions that had the collective capacity to constrain him. With its technocratic wing purged (St. John Reference St. John2015), the RCC was reduced in number from twelve to five members. After creating a more pliant General People's Congress (St. John Reference St. John2014, 161, 247), the RCC was formally abolished in 1977 (Feliu and Aarab Reference Feliu and Aarab2019, 79). As for the security apparatus, the 1975 coup ‘marked the end of professional and technical criteria for military recruitment and was the beginning of a steady but noticeable influx of individual members of Qadhafi's tribe – and later of his family – into sensitive security and army positions’ (Vandewalle Reference Vandewalle1998, 88). Still, in August 1980, Gaddafi was only able to crush a bloody coup attempt by an air force unit, based at Tobruq, with the help of East German military advisers (Cooley Reference Cooley1982, 282). In response, in the early to mid-1980s Gaddafi counterbalanced the regular armed forces by mobilizing armed ‘revolutionary committees’ (Pollack Reference Pollack2002, 386) and by creating multiple overlapping paramilitary units such as the Jamahiriyyah Guard and a special brigade led by his son (Lutterbeck Reference Lutterbeck2013). Following yet another failed coup in October 1993, which implicated members of the previously-allied Warfalla tribe, Qaddafi relied exclusively on the Jamahiriyyah Guard for regime protection (Gaub Reference Gaub2013, 229). He further emphasized tribal loyalty to cement his hold on power (Baxley Reference Baxley2011, 6). Through these actions taken largely in the wake of failed coups, Gaddafi successfully and completely personalized power, and ruled largely unconstrained until 2011.

Our argument rests on the premise that dictators have an interest in accumulating power while the ruling coalition seeks the opposite. In this tug-of-war, failed coups alter the information environment and create both incentives and opportunities for the dictator to escape the elites’ control. First, by signalling the existence of inside threats, failed coups incentivize rulers to take action to prevent further challenges and avoid costly post-exit punishments. Second, surviving a coup attempt undermines, at least temporarily, the credibility and deterrent effect of elite threats. By revealing information about the loyalty of members and factions in the ruling coalition, failed coups allow dictators to identify and eliminate rivals while also limiting the remaining elites' motives to challenge their position. Using new data on coups and a time-varying latent measure of personalism in dictatorships in 114 countries worldwide between 1946 and 2010, our empirical analyses support our theoretical expectations. We provide descriptive, quantitative evidence and probe the causal effect of failed coups on personalization using a synthetic control approach. Further, we illustrate the plausibility of our arguments with three case studies of post-coup trajectories in Algeria (1967), Sierra Leone (1971), and Benin (1975).

By examining the coup-personalism relationship, this article bridges and contributes to two strands of literature within comparative authoritarianism. First, we expand our understanding of the pathways to personalist rule. Most existing work focuses on constant or slow-moving factors that create favourable conditions for dictators. We also show that certain shocks can alter the dynamic structure of incentives and opportunities for the relevant actors and explain the substantial variation over time in personalism and, concretely, the occurrence of large surges within leaders' tenure. Second, we expand the burgeoning literature examining the impact of failed coups. Existing works have so far focused on repression, (elite or military) purges, or discrete regime changes but not on the full extent to which the dictator has individual discretion over the key levers of power. Repression, an outcome endogenous to regime structures, is conceptually different from personalism. And purges, while often viewed as entailing power consolidation, are just one among several items used in constructing the latent measure of personalism we use in this article. The measure, rather than regime change, captures an evolving trait of all autocracies.

Extant Work

Prior work on personalism mostly relied on the Geddes (Reference Geddes1999) and Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2014) regime typology, which comparativists have used extensively to explore how different forms of dictatorship affect a wide range of political and economic outcomes. Because they are time-invariant within a given regime, these categories are less useful for studying how different forms of authoritarian rule emerge and how levels of personalism change within regimes.Footnote 2 New work by Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) and Wright (Reference Wright2021) reconceives personalism as a continuous trait of all autocratic rule, not just one regime type. As such, personalization may occur in varying degrees in any regime and, importantly, can vary over time.

The literature on the emergence of personalism is rather limited despite the dangers associated with this form of rule and its growing global importance. The consensus is that power aggrandizement only happens when some factor gives the dictator a bargaining advantage over the elites so that the latter are less able to monitor or punish him via a coup. Thus, the first pathway to personalist rule, according to Svolik (Reference Svolik2009, Reference Svolik2012), opens when the threat of a coup lacks sufficient credibility because costly coups might be reconsidered due to the imperfect nature of observed signals of a dictator's opportunism. Personalism, under such circumstances, occurs gradually and is abetted by secrecy.

According to some highly structural accounts, a second pathway opens when dictators' advantages stem from time-invariant or slow-moving factors such as initial conditions, natural resources, or foreign support. Concerning initial conditions, Meng (Reference Meng2020) argues that strong leaders, namely post-colonial founding presidents and those coming to power via a coup, are unlikely to institutionalize their regimes due to their higher popularity and their control over the security forces, respectively. Similarly, Sudduth (Reference Sudduth2017) claims that leaders who seize power via a coup – and head a loyal coalition that replaces entirely the prior one – are more likely to purge rivals in the first few years of their tenure. Alternatively, Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) focus on the initial internal cohesion of seizure groups. They claim that factionalized elites cannot obstruct ‘the dictator's drive to concentrate power’ while ‘the dictator can bargain separately with each member of a factionalized seizure group’, inducing competition and driving down the price of support (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018, 78–9). As for other structural factors, Fails (Reference Fails2019) shows that increases in oil rents lead to higher personalism levels. Ample unearned resources allow rulers to finance patronage networks and reduce the need to share power (Chehabi and Linz Reference Chehabi and Linz1998; Meng Reference Meng2020). Although not focusing directly on personalization, some suggest the influence of foreign countries promotes power consolidation. Soviet sponsorship facilitated the adoption of coup prevention strategies (Casey Reference Casey2020), while defence alliances make elite purges more likely as dictators anticipate military support (Boutton Reference Boutton2019; Decalo Reference Decalo1989).

The works above leave three important points unaddressed. First, many critical steps toward power concentration are often highly visible and are unlikely to go unnoticed, so the conditions under which such moves can be made need further investigation. Second, at the empirical and conceptual level, many prior studies did not focus on (or measure) personalism directly but on partial reforms and other outcomes. Finally, by examining the impact of structural or time-invariant factors, prior studies can inform us about cross-country differences in levels of personalism emerging from distinct conditions, but less about surges during the tenure of a given leader. This leaves unexplored the timing of power concentration and, particularly, how intra-elite interactions and opportunity structures can be transformed so that surges in personalism can occur. Noticeable changes in the organization of autocracies normally take place when a shock, such as an irregular intervention, alters the underlying balance of power. Indeed, regime or leader changes are key observable outcomes of ‘successful’ coups. The direction of those changes has sparked an intense scholarly debate about the impacts of coups in autocracies and their potential democratizing effects (Derpanopoulos et al. Reference Derpanopoulos2016; Derpanopoulos et al. Reference Derpanopoulos2017; Miller Reference Miller2016; Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016; Varol Reference Varol2017).Footnote 3 Others find that coups are followed by significant increases in repression (Curtice and Arnon Reference Curtice and Arnon2020; Lachapelle Reference Lachapelle2020).

This literature has almost exclusively centred on the consequences of successful coups. Failed coups, constituting half of all coup attempts, did not receive scholarly attention until recently. Using individual data on cabinet members in autocracies, Bokobza et al. (Reference Bokobza2022) find that failed coups lead to cabinet purges, especially of higher-ranking members and those holding strategic positions. Country-level evidence also shows that coup-surviving rulers are likely to rely on purges (Easton and Siverson Reference Easton and Siverson2018). Similarly, scholars have found that failed coups are followed by higher levels of both violent and low-intensity repression (Curtice and Arnon Reference Curtice and Arnon2020; Oztig and Donduran Reference Oztig and Donduran2020). However, a post-coup increase in repression, or the leaders' tenure, may also be a by-product of other underlying, more profound changes in the organization of a regime. In fact, as Frantz et al. (Reference Frantz2019) show, personalization in dictatorships leads to more violent repression. So the documented long-lasting effects on repression or survival might be in part explained by increased personalism levels brought about by a failed coup. Furthermore, although a logical immediate response, purges are just a partial, momentary tactic, which cannot solidify a dictator's power in the long-term, as some studies posit, unless accompanied by other measures. Extensive purges can alienate remaining elites and spur retaliation, do not guarantee their long-term loyalty, and may leave some co-conspirators undetected and unpunished (Easton and Siverson Reference Easton and Siverson2018; Sudduth Reference Sudduth2017; Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016; Woldense Reference Woldense2022).

Although most of the ‘good coup’ debate focuses on successful coups, Thyne and Powell (Reference Thyne and Powell2016) notably found that failed attempts may also promote democratization as coup-surviving leaders may be prompted to share power to remain in office. Post-coup liberalization, they aver, removes ‘the underlying conditions that precipitated the coup’ and may enable leaders to reap the benefits of a strengthened economy, political legitimacy, and foreign relations (Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016, 199). Their focus, however, is on regime transitions (rare events) not on changes of a continuous, underlying trait within an autocratic spell. Furthermore, a qualitative re-evaluation of cases in Africa suggests that the positive effect of failed coups on democratization may be due to false positives in cross-national data. Failed coups may bolster a state's pre-coup political trajectory, spurring democratization in some contexts or further autocratization in others (Powell, Chacha, and Smith Reference Powell, Chacha and Smith2018, 240).Footnote 4

The Argument: Why Leaders Personalize After Failed Coups

Rather than spurring democratic reforms, we contend that failed coups in dictatorships are much more typically followed by personalization. Power relations between the dictator and the ruling coalition are zero-sum, making intra-regime bargains potentially conflictual (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018; Roessler Reference Roessler2011; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). Any increase in the dictator's power risks aggrieving elite members. Specifically, ‘[w]hen the members of the ruling coalition suspect that the dictator is making steps toward strengthening his position at their expense, they may stage a coup d’état in order to stop him’ (Svolik Reference Svolik2009, 479). Certain shocks can alter such bargains and cause the balance of power to favour the autocrat and reduce temporarily the credibility of that threat. Particularly, failed coups uncover four types of information that create incentives and opportunities for dictators to usurp power. First, failed coups inform leaders about the existence of internal threats, motivating them to adopt measures to secure their survival. Second, failed coups inform the ruler about the elites' loyalty and expose opposing factions. Third, failed coups inform the elites about the existence of a risk of exclusion – encouraging them to back the ruler's protective reforms. Finally, under certain circumstances, failed coups can reveal information about the dictator's strength, which impels the elites to reconsider challenging his position.

Incentives

Failed coups are eye-opening shocks from inside the regime that signal to dictators that their position is insufficiently entrenched and that the existing arrangements guiding the relationship with the support coalition are not effective in deterring elite rebellions. In Easton and Siverson's (Reference Easton and Siverson2018) words, ‘[a] coup attempt is visible evidence that people close to the leader have made an estimate that the leader is weak enough to be removed by the use of force and/or they are dissatisfied enough with the status quo that an attempt is worthwhile’. Leaders are, therefore, prompted to take action to eradicate further challenges and, hence, are not only able to cling to power but also avoid the typical post-exit consequences of being ousted forcefully – namely, execution, prison, or exile (Escribà-Folch Reference Escribà-Folch2013; Goemans Reference Goemans2008).

Some suggest that dictators will often respond to coup attempts or threats by adopting liberalizing reforms (Thyne and Powell Reference Thyne and Powell2016) or by making concessions in the form of institutionalized power sharing (Boix and Svolik Reference Boix and Svolik2013). Such tactics, however, do not address the ‘underlying conditions’ that make coups possible. Redistributing power enhances insiders' (and even outsiders') ability to coordinate against the ruler, which would render the elites' promise not to stage a coup in the future incredible while constraining the ruler's future ability to protect himself. As Meng (Reference Meng2020, 4) puts it, ‘[i]nstitutions that empower and identify specific challengers help to solve elite coordination problems, therefore better allowing them to hold incumbents accountable’.Footnote 5

Failed coups should thus encourage dictators to capitalize on their (temporary) advantage and lock in reforms that consolidate their position in the long term and effectively prevent insiders from staging another coup in the future. Rather than empowering elites, personalization seeks to reduce elites' incentives to act against the dictator and, importantly, to undermine their ability to do so. Therefore, while we agree with Thyne and Powell (Reference Thyne and Powell2016) that failed coups urge leaders to enact ‘meaningful political reforms’, we disagree on the form and direction of those reforms. Such direction is influenced by the unique opportunities a failed coup opens for dictators.

Opportunities

Personalization does not result from increased incentives alone. Post-coup environments also create the necessary opportunities to expand executive power. As said, personalism involves gaining personal control over the security apparatus and the party executive, and over appointments to high office, as well as installing loyalists while purging other officers (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018). Many such moves cannot be subtle or kept secret so, in normal times, usurping power is likely to trigger a backlash (Sudduth Reference Sudduth2017).Footnote 6 As said, the credible threat of a coup is the ultimate instrument elites have to prevent the dictator from sidelining them. If that threat is realized but fails, such credibility is temporarily undermined, which allows leaders to adopt measures aimed at transforming this temporary advantage over the support coalition into a more permanent one. We thus concur with Sudduth (Reference Sudduth2017: 1769) who argue that autocrats' attempts at undermining the elites' capability are more likely ‘when the probability that elites can successfully remove the dictator via coup is temporarily low’. For Sudduth, this advantage stems from taking over in a successful coup. In her argument, heading a coup allows the new ruler to convey information to potential rival groups about the strength and loyalty of his allies (Sudduth and Bell Reference Sudduth and Bell2018). Surviving a coup, we posit, also discloses helpful information and reshapes the dynamics between the dictator and two sets of groups: Those involved in the coup and those who were not. The failure thus creates opportunities for personalization to surge because it weakens elites' ability and willingness to strike again.

First, while informational incompleteness is paramount before (and even during) a coup (Little Reference Little2017; Singh Reference Singh2014), it decreases after an attempt in ways that undermine the inside opponents' capacity to launch another attack. The attempt puts the dictator on full alert, which hinders any potential new plots and, especially, the element of surprise that coups require due to a higher risk of detection. But most importantly, while screening for loyalty can be difficult in political environments where there is a lack of transparency in elite interactions, the use of material inducements to buy loyalty and the use of repression to mute discontent create monitoring costs and impede observing the elites' real preferences and identify challengers (Sudduth and Bell Reference Sudduth and Bell2018; Svolik Reference Svolik2012; Timoneda Reference Timoneda2020); in the aftermath of a failed coup, internal opponents are exposed as coups force high-ranking officials and groups within the ruling coalition to make their preferences public and choose sides.Footnote 7 This improves the dictator's ability to out rivals and opposing factions (Powell, Chacha, and Smith Reference Powell, Chacha and Smith2018) and, in turn, exclude or eliminate them and weaken (if not eradicate) their organizational capacity (Bokobza et al. Reference Bokobza2022; Curtice and Arnon Reference Curtice and Arnon2020; Easton and Siverson Reference Easton and Siverson2018).Footnote 8 Failed coups can lead to more extensive purges of elites who are known (or suspected) to have joined or supported the plot, and can also serve as a pretext to sideline other powerful elites and military units deemed untrustworthy or prone to defect (Bokobza et al. Reference Bokobza2022; Easton and Siverson Reference Easton and Siverson2018).

Second, the new post-coup information environment reshapes the incentive structure of insiders who did not join the attempt. A failed attempt informs elites about the possibility of regime breakdown due to another faction's takeover and, in turn, about the credible risk of losing their privileged inside positions. This mechanism is consistent with a dynamic version of the Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) argument because, despite failing, a coup attempt may signify a public manifestation of (previously latent or non-existent) factionalism within the ruling coalition. Intra-elite competition and the risk of being replaced by a rival faction induce loyalty to the incumbent dictator from other members of the ruling coalition, who become more likely to acquiesce to personalization since remaining inside the inner circle still leaves them better off than being excluded or risking failure in a new challenge.Footnote 9 Therefore, personalizing measures that safeguard the leader and the regime also protect insiders' positions within the inner circle, although at the cost of diminished influence. Also, the elimination of coup makers' forces leads to the narrowing of the dictator's support coalition. Thus, the loyalty norm increases for remaining backers as the chance of exclusion from a subsequent winning coalition also increases (Bueno De Mesquita et al. Reference Bueno De Mesquita2003).

Finally, under certain circumstances, failed coups can also influence elites' incentives by revealing previously unknown information about the relative strength of the ruler, allowing both actors to update their beliefs downward about the likelihood of success of a new coup attempt (Bokobza et al. Reference Bokobza2022; Sudduth and Bell Reference Sudduth and Bell2018).Footnote 10 The realization that the leader is strong should dissuade elites from challenging him again and pave the way for power accumulation. It is important to note, though, that inferring such strength from a failed putsch may not always be possible unless the outcome is the result of clear military opposition to plotters. The causes of coup failure are oftentimes merely random, circumstantial, or fortuitous ( Kebschull Reference Kebschull1994), so clear information on relative strength is not necessarily disclosed.Footnote 11

In sum, with the opponents' ability to resist decimated and the remaining elites' reduced interest in challenging them, a temporary window of opportunity opens for dictators to accumulate power. Purging foes is one clear measure leaders are most likely to adopt, but effective personalization (and preventing further coups) also makes dictators likely to take further steps. To ensure loyalty, one is gaining personal discretion over the power to appoint and promote high-level officers and officials, which gives leaders control over the composition of their inner circle.Footnote 12 A second one entails putting key institutions that could constrain them under their direct command or creating new (especially recruited) organizations to counterbalance existing ones. In light of this, we therefore hypothesize that ‘personalization in dictatorships will increase sharply after a failed coup’.

Personalizing power is a multifaceted process comprising potentially alternative sequences of manoeuvres. Indeed, the Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) personalism measure that we employ includes items that capture the extent of the leader's control over the two institutions that could limit his power: The military and the ruling party executive (if one exists). Coups are not only threats hailed from inside the regime but, crucially, in an overwhelming majority of them (over 96 per cent of all attempts since 1946), current active members of the security apparatus were involved (Chin, Carter, and Wright Reference Chin, Carter and Wright2021). It thus seems logical that dictators are more likely to prioritize securing the dependability and control of the agents of repression to ‘coup-proof’ their regimes.Footnote 13 We thus further hypothesize that ‘the effect of failed coups should be stronger on the part of personalization having to do with the security forces rather than the party executive’.

Data and Research Design

To measure failed coups, we use two sources of data. The first is the Powell-Thyne dataset, which records successful and failed coups in 200 countries between 1950 and 2019 (Powell and Thyne Reference Powell and Thyne2011). We also use data on failed coups from the novel Colpus dataset (Chin, Carter, and Wright Reference Chin, Carter and Wright2021), which also includes accompanying historical narratives and data on coup types and characteristics for all countries in the Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) sample since 1946. The correlation between the two measures in our sample is 0.701. The Powell-Thyne data codes coup attempts against ruling executives, largely aligning with Archigos' list of ‘de facto’ leaders (Goemans, Gleditsch, and Chiozza Reference Goemans, Gleditsch and Chiozza2009). The Colpus dataset, by contrast, is fully compatible with the slightly different list of regime leaders of Wright (Reference Wright2021) as well as Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018), for which we have personalism data.Footnote 14

Our dependent variable is the latent measure of personalism from Wright (Reference Wright2021) and Geddes, Wright, and Frantz (Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018), who derived continuous scores from an item-response theory model based on eight observable indicators. The first four indicators capture personalism in the security forces: (1) personal control over the security apparatus, (2) the creation of a paramilitary group or presidential guard loyal only to the dictator, (3) promotions of officers based on loyalty (from the leader's ethnic, tribal, regional, or partisan group), and (4) extrajudicial arrests and killings of officers from other groups (purges). The last four indicators capture personalism in the party executive: (5) exclusive personal control over appointments to high office, (6) whether the dictator has created a support party, (7) exclusive power to choose the support party's executive committee, and (8) whether the party's executive committee is absent or rubber stamps policy decisions. The decision to include these measures is informed theoretically and validated through factor analysis. The resulting score ranges between 0 (no personalism) and 1 (maximal personalism).

We take advantage of the fact that data on failed coups is available at a monthly level so allowing us to expand our personalism data from yearly to monthly values,Footnote 15 though our results will still hold if we keep all data at the yearly level.Footnote 16 In our initial descriptive quantitative tests, the main explanatory variable is ‘Failed Coup’, which is coded as 0 for all those group-month observations that have not experienced a failed coup before, and 1 for all observations after a failed coup.Footnote 17 If more than one failed coup occurs, our main model also codes these observations as 1. The final sample consists of 139 failed coups.

We run two separate sets of tests to probe our main hypothesis. The first set of models (Table 1) restricts the data to the three years before and after a failed coup only. This provides a direct test of our hypothesis; namely, that personalism levels should increase rapidly after a failed coup. For this first set of models, we run five different specifications using each failed coup variable separately (for a total of ten models). We first run a naive model to ensure that results are not spuriously generated by a model specification. Second, we run the main model with all controls plus leader spell fixed effects. Third, we add leader spells that suffered a successful coup to the sample, since there is a positive probability that the coup could have failed due to the randomness of coup outcomes (Lachapelle Reference Lachapelle2020).Footnote 18 The final two models add regime and country fixed effects, respectively, instead of leader spell fixed effects.

Table 1. Immediate effect of failed coups on latent personalization (DV) using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

All models show OLS regression estimates with leader spell fixed effects. Models (a) and (f) are naïve specifications, (b) and (g) add controls, (c) and (h) also include regimes that suffered a successful coup, models (d) and (i) use regime fixed effects instead of leader spell fixed effects, and models (e) and (j) use country fixed effects in place of leader spell fixed effects. The sample covers only 3 years before and after a failed coup.

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Clustered standard errors in parentheses.

The second set of models (Table 2) uses the full sample and thus provides a general view of the long-run effects of failed coups on personalism. We expect that the short-term effects in the first set of models should be much stronger than the long-run effects, but both should be positive. We also run five different specifications using both Colpus and P&T. The first model is again a simple bivariate specification. The second restricts the sample to only leader spells that experienced at least one failed coup. The third model uses the full sample, including cases that experienced a failed coup, a successful coup, and no coup at all. The last two models again replace leader spell fixed effects with regime and country fixed effects, respectively.

Table 2. Long-term effect of failed coups on latent personalization (DV) using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

All models show OLS regression estimates with leader spell and year fixed effects. Models (a) and (f) are naïve specifications, (b) and (g) add controls, (c) and (h) also include regimes that suffered a successful coup, models (d) and (i) use regime fixed effects instead of leader spell fixed effects, and models (e) and (j) use country fixed effects in place of leader spell fixed effects. These models include the full sample.

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Clustered standard errors in parentheses.

As for our second hypothesis, we construct additional latent variables to capture party executive personalization and personalization of the security forces. We use the four constituent measures of party personalism to create our latent party personalism score and the four constituent measures of personalism in the security forces to create our latent score for security forces personalism. Lastly, to ensure that purges are not driving the results, we create a separate latent variable for personalism in the security forces without the constituent variable for military purges. These results are presented in Table 3 below, with the expectation that the impact of the failed coups will be stronger for the personalization of the security apparatus rather than the party executive.

Table 3. Immediate effect of a failed coup on the different dimensions of personalism (Hypothesis 2), using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

All models show OLS regression estimates with leader spell and year fixed effects. The sample covers three years before and after a failed coup.

*p < 0.1, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01. Clustered standard errors in parentheses.

Regarding control variables, our models include military spending (Easton and Siverson Reference Easton and Siverson2018), oil income (Fails Reference Fails2019), GDP per capita, and economic growth.Footnote 19 In models with a longer time horizon (Table 2) we also include a time trend yWiN8GI3, constructed at the group-month level and starting at 1 in the first month a leader spell is observed, increasing sequentially by one unit each month thereafter until the leader exits the dataset. The variable allows us to model changes in predicted personalism over time. Including leader spell fixed effects makes it unnecessary to control for mean levels of personalism before the coup. Since our dependent variable is continuous, our method of choice is a linear OLS model with standard errors clustered by leader spell.

Results: Failed Coups and Personalization

We begin by presenting some descriptive statistics.Footnote 20 The average year-on-year increase in personalism for dictators who do not face a coup attempt in the intervening year is 0.009 (or just under 1 per cent, given that the personalism scale runs from 0 to 1). By contrast, the average year-on-year increase in personalism when a dictator survives a failed coup attempt is 0.06 (6 per cent). In other words, personalism jumps more than six-fold after a failed coup.

The main results are reported in Tables 1 and 2, where the dependent variable is the latent level of personalism in all models. Table 1 shows the results for the ‘immediate’ effect of failed coups on personalism, while the models in Table 2 use the full temporal sample. In both Tables, models (a) through (e) use the Colpus failed coups measure while models (f) through (j) use Powell & Thyne's measure. Standard errors are clustered by leader spell in all models.Footnote 21

The coefficient for the dichotomous failed coups variable in Table 1 is positive and statistically significant in all models, including those with the strictest specifications using leader spell fixed effects – models (b) and (g). The effect also exists in the naive models (a) and (f), which ensures that it is not spuriously created by adding extra parameters.Footnote 22 The coefficients are robust to different model specifications and different samples. Models (b) and (g) provide strong evidence that personalism increases sharply after a failed coup in those leader spells that experience at least one failed coup. Models (c) and (h) confirm that the finding obtains even when leader spells that experienced a successful coup are added to the sample. Lastly, models (d), (e), (i), and (j) show that the model is robust to country and regime fixed effects specifications. As for the control variables, their expected long-run effects do not necessarily apply equally in the short term, which explains some of the variations between the Colpus and P&T measures. Note that models with leader spell fixed effects explain a large amount of the variation in personalism – between 84.3 and 88.7 per cent.

Table 2 reports the results for the full sample of cases and years. The results provide further evidence that failed coups lead to greater levels of personalism, but that the effect is weaker in the long run than in the short term. Besides the naive models, the coefficients are all in the expected direction but all are either close to statistical significance (using COLPUS) or statistically significant only at the 0.1 level (using P&T). The coefficients for the control variables are consistent with our theoretical expectations. The time trend is positive and statistically significant across most models. GDP per capita is negatively associated with increases in personalism. Greater military spending generally leads to more personalism, as do increases in oil income. Lastly, it is worth noting that failed coups (in a model with group fixed effects) explain a large majority of the variation in the model using Colpus data – 73.8 per cent.Footnote 23

To examine how personalization evolves both before a failed coup and after it, we plot the predicted values of personalism by month, for the three years before and after the failed coup. The results are shown in Fig. 1. The plot uses data from Colpus.Footnote 24 The red vertical line represents the month when a failed coup happened and the black line plots the predicted personalism score before and after the failed coup for all the leader spells that experienced at least one event.Footnote 25 The model predicts relatively stable, if slightly declining, levels of personalism before the failed coup, and then a sudden, substantial spike in the period after the failed coup. A majority of the increase takes place in the first two years and stabilizes in year three. More specifically, personalism decreases slightly before a failed coup, from 0.385 three years out to 0.36 one year before. After the failed coup, the increase in personalism is substantial, going from a predicted value of personalism of 0.366 to 0.497 within twenty-four months after the failed coup event. This represents a large, substantively significant increase in personalism of 35.8 per cent in the two years following a failed coup.

Figure 1. Predicted personalism before and after a failed coup (x = 0) based on model (b) from Table 1. Personalism variable scaled between 0 and 1. 95% confidence intervals shown.

Two well-known examples illustrate the model's large predicted increase in personalism. On June 30, 1973, Ahmed Hassan al-Bakr and his deputy Saddam Hussein faced an attempted coup (and an assassination plot) by mostly junior elements within the public security department, led by Col. Nadhim Kazzar (Chin, Wright, and Carter, forthcoming, Reference Chin, Wright and Carter2022, 611–2). After a set of purges and reshuffling, Hussein tightened his grip on the regime, and the predicted level of personalism went from 0.521 before the attempted coup to 0.782 the year after it. The attempted coup led to a 50 per cent increase in personalism in the Iraqi case.Footnote 26 In contrast, another leader who personalized power but did not face an unsuccessful coup attempt, Vladimir Putin, in the 2000s, increased his level of personalism from 0.541 to 0.606, a jump of only 12 per cent over a full decade. Other examples of rapid personalism after a failed coup as predicted by the model were Burma (Myanmar) in 1976 (a 42 per cent increase), Libya under Gaddafi in 1975 (a 62 per cent increase), and Mali in 1978 (a 46 per cent increase). In addition to these examples, we provide three full case studies – Algeria, Sierra Leone, and Benin – to further illustrate the mechanisms of increases in personalism after failed coups.

These results are congruous with our theoretical expectations regarding how dictators operate after failed coups. Failed coups act as a shock, one that allows for the quick restructuring of institutions and personnel practically without backlash.

Table 3 reports the results of our second hypothesis. The evidence strongly supports the idea that rapid increases in personalism are concentrated primarily on the security apparatus, but they are not solely driven by purges. The failed coup coefficients in models (b) and (d), where the dependent variable is a latent measure including all four constituent terms for security personalism, are both substantively and statistically significant at the 0.01 level. When the latent variable is constructed without military purges, the coefficient remains significant at the 0.05 level. It also remains substantively significant, even though the size of the coefficient decreases slightly. Conversely, personalism around civilian institutions is not as strong immediately after a coup, as shown in models (a) and (d). The coefficients in these models are positive but their effect is weaker and not statistically significant at conventional levels. That said, some constituent terms on their own show some evidence of statistical and substantive significance: For example, the control of appointments to high office and the creation of a new party, which serves to counterbalance the military (Tables A1 and A2 in the Appendix).

A Synthetic Control Approach

The quantitative evidence presented above remains largely descriptive. To determine the causal nature of failed coups on increases in personalization, we employ a synthetic control approach. Synthetic controls were introduced to allow researchers to estimate causal relationships in situations where a small number of units experienced a given event or intervention (treatment). By generating a donor pool from similar cases where no treatment occurred, we can estimate the counterfactual response by the treated unit absent the treatment (Abadie and Gardeazabal Reference Abadie and Gardeazabal2003). Synthetic controls use a data-driven process to determine the weights that make the control group closely resemble the treatment group before the treatment occurs. The response by the control group can then be considered as the counterfactual response for the treatment group. Recent work has extended the application of synthetic controls to multiple units. Synthetic controls are useful in comparative case studies because they provide a data-driven formalization of the selection of comparison units and the assignment of weights to each unit in the control group, which is an innovation over difference-in-differences methods (Abadie Reference Abadie2021). In recent years, this approach has become increasingly common in the social sciences, with particularly promising applications in comparative politics (Abadie, Diamond, and Hainmueller Reference Abadie, Diamond and Hainmueller2015).

We provide one such novel application of synthetic controls to failed coups and their effects on personalization. In our sample, twenty-three unique leader spells experienced at least one failed coup that was not preceded or followed by a successful coup within three years. This sampling approach ensures leader continuity. It also allows us to map personalization trajectories before and after a failed coup for a longer period.Footnote 27 We then centre all units in the treatment group at the time when the failed coup took place and use the failed coup as treatment.Footnote 28 We apply a synthetic control to a non-synchronous event, one of the first applications of this kind in the authors' knowledge. We pre-select our control sample to include leader spells that experienced at least one successful coup and no failed coup. Our logic is that there is a certain randomness to coup success (Lachapelle Reference Lachapelle2020; Singh Reference Singh2014), thus units that experience a successful coup have a similar latent probability of experiencing a coup regardless of the outcome. There are thirty-nine such groups, among which the algorithm selects the control sample that most resembles the treatment sample before the failed coup (treatment) and assigns a placebo.Footnote 29

Figure 2 plots the results of the multiple synthetic control.Footnote 30 The solid line represents the evolution of personalism in leader spells that suffered a true failed coup, while the dashed line reflects personalism over time in leader spells that were assigned a placebo failed coup. The trend before the failed coup (vertical line; x-axis = 0) is similar for both groups, with a slight but non-significant positive tendency. The lines then begin to diverge after the failed coup, with the sharpest increase during the first year. Again, the lack of smoothness in the trends is due to the fact that the monthly means for personalism are the averages of the yearly scores across cases. At twelve months ‘after’ the failed coup, the treatment and control groups diverge by 0.06 points in the personalism scale. The average yearly increase in personalism in the sample is 0.009 points, making a large one-time change of 0.06 substantively significant. This matches our descriptive results and confirms the finding in Table 1 that personalism is higher after a failed coup. Moreover, it also shows that failed coups have a strong and ‘immediate’ causal effect on increases in personalization.

Figure 2. Predicted personalism before and after a failed coup attempt, based on the synthetic control model. The personalism variable is scaled between 0 and 1. 95% confidence intervals shown.

To add more evidence to the synthetic control analysis, we provide a more traditional application of synthetic controls to six cases: Sierra Leone under Siaka Stevens, Algeria under Houari Boumédiène, Mathieu Kérékou in Benin, Zia Rahman in Bangladesh, Saddam Hussein in Iraq, and Heydar Aliyev in Azerbaijan. As case studies, we describe the first two cases in depth in the final section of the article. Figure 3 plots the evolution of personalism over time for each of these examples. As noted, the lack of smoothness in the trend is due to the underlying structure of the data. In all three cases, we observe a similar trend between the treated unit and the control group pre-treatment and a sharp divergence post-treatment. Personalism rises the sharpest in Sierra Leone, from 0.25 before the coup to 0.58 afterwards. The yearly personalism data takes a few months to reflect the change, due to the coup occurring in early 1971, with the data only increasing in 1972. In the case study we show how personalization was linked to the failed coup directly.

Figure 3. Synthetic control results for Algeria, Sierra Leone, Bangladesh, Benin, Iraq, and Azerbaijan, based on synthetic control models for each individual case. The personalism variable is scaled between 0 and 1.

Robustness Checks

Four robustness checks are included in the Appendix. First, we confirm in Tables A1 and A2 that purges are not driving the results, thus complementing our evidence from Table 3. Second, in Tables A3 and A4, we replicate the analysis in Tables 1 and 2 using yearly data, and the results are consistent. Third, in Table A6, we explicitly address reverse causality by adding one, two, and three-year lags and leads for our failed coup variable, where we find substantive and statistical significance only in the lagged models. Lastly, to probe our argument further, we conduct two placebo tests using assassination attempts and civil war onsets. Significant increases in personalism after a failed assassination attempt could shed doubt on our argument that failed coups are not a mere pretext but change the information game for the regime's main actors. Similarly, higher levels of personalism after civil war onsets would mean that violent events, not just failed coups, trigger periods of rapid personalization. We find that neither assassination attempts nor civil wars have a strong, positive impact on personalism in the short term (Figures 1 and 2 in the Appendix).Footnote 31

Personalizing After Failed Coups in Algeria, Sierra Leone, and Benin

We now illustrate our arguments by presenting brief case studies of the evolution of personalism surrounding three failed coups in Algeria, Sierra Leone, and Benin.

Algeria-Boumédiène 1967. After ousting Ahmed Ben Bella in a bloodless coup in 1965, Houari Boumédiène, who had been defence minister and vice-president, led an initially collegial ‘collective executive’ called the Council of the Revolution (Naylor Reference Naylor2015). Twenty-two out of twenty-six council members were officers of the Armée Nationale Populaire (ANP), the direct successor to the armed wing of the ruling party, the Front de Libération Nationale (FLN) (Evans and Phillips Reference Evans and Phillips2007). The council was an alliance of two factions. The mujahidin, the old-line wilaya commanders who had led the independence struggle were led by Col. Tahar Zbiri, who took command of the military from Boumédiène after 1965. Then there was the ‘Oujda Group’, led by Boumédiène himself and supported by technocrats in the cabinet and the FLN (Zartman Reference Zartman and Welch1970, 242). As Col. Zbiri, whose support was critical for the 1965 coup's success, gained control over the military, his faction increasingly controlled the Council of the Revolution. To compensate for his increasing weakness, in June 1967 Boumédiène began to make key decisions within his cabinet where he controlled a majority and refused to convene the council where he was outnumbered (New York Times 1967). When Zbiri protested, Boumédiène tried to sideline Zbiri's faction and, on 10 December 1967, reassigned or dismissed five council members, including four wilaya commanders and Col. Zbiri's deputy, Youssef Khatib. Boumédiène also named his close Oudja Group ally, Finance Minister Kaid, to reorganize the FLN (Associated Press 1967). Misjudging his military support, Zbiri launched a coup on 14–15 December 1967 (Quandt Reference Quandt1972). However, the advance of several tank battalions on Algiers was repelled by loyal gendarmerie and air force units, and Boumédiène neutralized political support for the coup by coopting other opposition (Lenze Reference Lenze2016, 29). In the wake of the failed coup, Zbiri and his collaborators were forced into hiding. Zbiri organized several clandestine assassination attempts in hopes of returning to power but fled to Tunisia in June 1968 (Ottaway and Ottaway Reference Ottaway and Ottaway1970, 254–5).

The coup attempt allowed Boumédiène to take ‘complete control over Algeria’ (Naylor Reference Naylor2015, 148). Within days of the attempt, Boumédiène controlled all appointments to high office within the Council of the Revolution, the ANP, and the FLN. First, Zbiri's failed coup ‘gave Boumediène the opportunity to suppress the General Staff altogether’. With the general staff dissolved, ‘the armed forces possessed no institutional expression of their collective interests outside Boumediène's Ministry of Defense’ (Roberts Reference Roberts1984). Boumédiène immediately placed the country's armed forces under his command, ‘assuming personally many staff responsibilities’ (Tartter Reference Tartter and Metz1994, 254). He also tightened his grip on the secret service, the Sécurité Militaire (Evans and Phillips Reference Evans and Phillips2007), which was headed by his head henchman, Lt Col. Kasdi Merbah. Second, Boumédiène ethnically narrowed the regime in Arab hands. He purged several former guerilla leaders, especially Kabyle and Shawiya (Zbiri himself was a Shawiya Berber). After Zbiri's coup attempt, Berber's military power was curtailed (Horowitz Reference Horowitz1985, 517). Finally, Boumédiène ‘excluded ANP leadership from day-to-day policy making but remained close to the army commanders whose support he needed to maintain political control’ (Tartter Reference Tartter and Metz1994, 254). Boumédiène ensured men personally loyal to him commanded key posts in the defence ministry, including the ANP Secretary General, Col. Abdelkader Moulay, and the head of the ANP Political Commissariat, El Hachemi Hadjerès, (Roberts Reference Roberts1984). Many of Boumédiène's favoured remaining elites lacked an independent base of support, ensuring they had neither the incentive nor the capability to challenge him.Footnote 32

The 1967 failed coup, in short, ensured the victory of the Oudja Group in general and Boumédiène in particular and marked the demise of the mujahidin in the regime's inner circle. The Council of the Revolution shrank to only fourteen members by 1970; only eight Council members survived by the time Boumédiène became terminally ill in 1978 (Tartter Reference Tartter and Metz1994, 254). These bold personalization moves are reflected in Wright's (Reference Wright2021) latent personalism score for Algeria under Boumédiène, which stood at 0.427 before the coup and 0.59 afterwards, an increase of 38 per cent.

Sierra Leone – Stevens 1971. Siaka Stevens, leader of the All People's Congress party, had won elections in March 1967 but was prevented from taking office as prime minister due to a veto coup by the then-army commander, Brig. John Lansana. In April 1968, Col. John Bangura, then military attaché in Washington, led the so-called Sergeants' Coup that ousted the post-1967 coup military regime and paved the way for Stevens to finally come to office (Kline Reference Kline and Danopoulos1992, 218–20). In late 1968, Stevens began to recruit 80 per cent of new army recruits from northern ethnic groups, not just from his co-ethnic Limba but also many Temne (Harkness Reference Harkness2018, 119). Bangura was promoted to Brigadier and made Force Commander in May 1969. By 1971, Bangura, an ethnic Temne, had grown uneasy about Steven's apparent desire to ethnicize the regime into a Limba-dominated one-party state. First, Stevens pensioned off Mende officers in 1969 (Harris Reference Harris2014, 64). In September 1970, several Temne ministers left Stevens' cabinet and the APC to found the United Democratic Party (UDP), led by Bangura's close Temne associate, John Karefa-Smart. In October 1970, Stevens banned the UDP and began purging Temne officers (Horowitz Reference Horowitz1985, 478) with the support of Limba soldiers and the allied Yalunka and Koranko; Stevens also began to contract Guinean bodyguards to provide for his protection (Harkness Reference Harkness2018, 120). On 23 March 1971, Major Falawa Jawara led a failed attack on President Siaka Steven's residence. Bangura took over leadership of the coup, urging on troops from the Wilberforce Barracks and announcing the putsch on the radio (Fyle Reference Fyle2006, 14, Vidler Reference Vidler1998, 178–9). The coup attempt, which sought to reverse Stevens' campaign against the UDP and Temne officers very nearly succeeded (Harris Reference Harris2014, 64). ‘With Stevens in hiding, the military split into factions with Creole and Limba soldiers refusing to follow the northern coup leaders’ orders’ (Harkness Reference Harkness2018, 120). However, after the army's third-in-command, Lt. Col. Sam King, publicly broadcast a denunciation of the coup, other senior officers turned on Bangura and arrested him (Associated Press 1971), and Stevens emerged from hiding.

With this new information, Stevens took immediate action to secure his rule after the failed coup. Having lost faith in the loyalty of his military, Stevens rushed to neutralize internal army opposition. First, he struck a defence pact with Guinean President, Sekou Touré, on March 26 to consolidate his control. Two days later, the first of 200 to 300 Guinean troops arrived in Sierra Leone to protect him (Hughes Reference Hughes, Macadam, Grindrod and Boas1971). Stevens compensated the remaining loyal soldiers with some 40,000 leones (Sierra Leone's currency) to convince them ‘not only to accept this influx of foreign troops, but to allow their own disarmament’ (Harkness Reference Harkness2018, 121). Second, Stevens accelerated the ethnic narrowing of the regime, ensuring state, party, and army leaders were all Limba. Temne were purged from the army officer corps (Horowitz Reference Horowitz1985, 478). Bangura was tried and executed for treason in June 1971 (Fyle Reference Fyle2006, 14). Stevens installed Colonel Joseph S. Momoh, a 34-year-old fellow Limba, as army head (Harris Reference Harris2014). During the coup attempt, Momoh, a political outsider, had proved his loyalty by providing intelligence to Stevens (Luke Reference Luke1988, 76). Finally, Stevens counter-balanced the army by creating the Internal Security Unit (ISU). He first proposed a paramilitary force on April 4, only eleven days after the failed coup, as a cost-saving measure. He claimed the government could not afford a large army (Kaplan Reference Kaplan1976). In the following months, Cuban, British, and Israeli instructors trained ISU units (Krogstad Reference Krogstad2012). The ISU became Stevens' executive police force, using it to repress, gather information, and ensure favourable election results. The ISU helped the APC win 84 out of 85 contested seats in the 1973 election (Reno Reference Reno and Rotberg2003, 80). Col. Momoh did not object to the new ISU, due to his personal loyalty and his knowledge that other senior officers supported Stevens – the failed coup had revealed their preferences.

In addition to personalizing the security forces, Stevens made institutional moves that ushered in an era of ‘virtually personal rule’ (Fyle Reference Fyle1994, 128). He had parliament rubber stamp a new republican constitution in mid-April 1971, and then promptly amended it to create an executive presidency giving him more power over political and military appointments (Clapham Reference Clapham1972; Luke Reference Luke1988). Two aspects of the new constitution are noteworthy. First, a new republican constitution had been debated for some time since Albert Margai (Sierra Leone's second prime minister) had introduced a draft during his 1964–67 tenure. Yet right after the 1971 coup attempt, Stevens saw a political opportunity to enact it, as factionalism within the government and the army was reduced (Clapham Reference Clapham1972). Second, he made key modifications, among them his personal designation as executive president, a position that was not considered in the original. In all, Stevens eliminated powerful opposition members, personalized and ethnically narrowed the military, enacted a constitution that gave him full political powers, and created a parallel military force – all within one month of the failed coup. Wright's data show personalism under Stevens rose from 0.251 before the coup to 0.585 after, a 133 per cent increase. These personalizing moves succeeded in bringing an end to the cycle of coups and counter-coups since 1967. Stevens retired in 1985 in favour of his hand-picked successor, Momoh.

Benin-Kérékou 1975. In October 1972, a military coup by a quartet of southern (Fon) junior officers ousted the civilian government of Justin Ahomadégbé and installed a military junta led by Major Mathieu Kérékou, a northerner (Somba), who had been the army deputy chief-of-staff. The army's senior officers (mostly southerners) were purged (Houngnikpo and Decalo Reference Houngnikpo and Decalo2013, 7, 102). In the new junta, cabinet portfolios were initially divided between junior officers with ‘some attempt at regional representation . . . Key appointments were Captains Michel Aikpe (minister of interior and security) and Janvier Assogba (minister of civil service), both young militant Fon from the Abomey region’ (Decalo Reference Decalo1973, 477). On 21 January 1975, Captain Assogba, calling Kérékou corrupt, led part of the key Quidah para-commando armed division in a ‘murky and ill-prepared assault’ that ultimately failed (Houngnikpo and Decalo Reference Houngnikpo and Decalo2013, 121).

In the wake of the failed coup, Assogba was imprisoned, seven plotters were sentenced to death, and a further five were given life sentences in March 1975 (United Press International 1975). Kérékou seized the opportunity to personalize the regime and transform the country. He first removed remaining potential rivals within the junta. In June 1975, Kérékou purged Major Aikpe, the popular and powerful minister of interior, who was shot on the pretext that he had been caught having an affair with Kérékou's wife, though in reality Kérékou was concerned that Aikpe's faction of militant officers posed a continuing coup threat (Martin Reference Martin1985, 70). In November 1975, a new constitution was adopted, Dahomey was renamed Benin, and a new support party, the Parti Revolutionnaire du Peuple Beninois (PRPB), became the country's sole legal party (Wilton-Marshall and Shaw Reference Wilton-Marshall, Shaw, Hodson, Hoffman and Bose1975). Kérékou became head of the six-man PRPB politburo, whose next most powerful figures were military officers, Major Michel Alladaye and Lt. Martin Azonhiho (Decalo Reference Decalo and Szajkowski1981, 94–5), who strengthened their positions by demonstrating loyalty to Kérékou by suppressing the general strike and student protests that broke out following Aikpe's murder in the summer of 1975 (Martin Reference Martin1985, 75).

In addition to tightening his control over civilian institutions, Kérékou ‘took overall command of the armed forces and militia’ (Allen Reference Allen1992, 44). He first moved to neutralize the Fon threat in the regular army. In 1975, senior officers from the older Fon generation were purged (Martin Reference Martin1985, 75). Meanwhile, more northerners were promoted to the officer corps and new paramilitary organizations were created (Morency-Laflamme Reference Morency-Laflamme2018, 9).Footnote 33 In addition, Kérékou built up a previously small, ceremonial Fulani-dominated bataillon de la garde présidentielle. ‘Trained by North Korea and with the best weapons in the country, it became the true military prop of the regime against domestic foes and mutinies from within the army’ (Houngnikpo and Decalo Reference Houngnikpo and Decalo2013, 57). The army was reformed to recruit police, gendarmerie, and forestry officers into a ‘People's Revolutionary Army’. By early 1976, the new army was tasked with training a new people's militia (Akindes Reference Akindes, Rupiya, Moyo and Laugesen2015, 50). As measured by the Wright data, the level of personalism under Kérékou nearly tripled, from only 0.23 on the eve of the Assogba coup attempt to 0.65 by the end of 1975. The failed coup thus facilitated Kérékou's domination of an increasingly Marxist single-party regime that would rule until the end of the Cold War.

Conclusion

Despite the global decline in their incidence after the end of the Cold War, coups are still a persistent feature in the politics of the Global South. In fact, 2021 has seen a spike in the number of instances, with seven attempts as of November. Such disruptive, irregular events draw much international attention, typically when they succeed in upending elected, civilian governments. This article shows that coups in dictatorships can have negative, long-lasting consequences even when they fail. In particular, a failed coup creates both incentives and opportunities for the dictator to personalize power by revealing crucial information to both the regime leader and regime elites. Our empirical results confirm the main hypothesis: Failed coups lead to surges in personalism levels in dictatorships, especially those concerning the control of the security apparatus.

This evidence contributes to several strands of literature on comparative authoritarianism and contentious politics. First, we contribute to the growing literature on the consequences of coups. In contrast to the view that failed coups often spur democratization in dictatorships, we find that an opposite trajectory consisting of power concentration takes place more often than not. Second, we further our understanding of the emergence of personalist rule. Failed coups can be seen as early warnings of personalistic rule. Our findings also point researchers in these areas to new research questions; for example, about what other shocks may promote or hinder personalization. We found no evidence that failed assassination attempts or civil war onsets promote personalization, although it is possible that other events other than coups may create ‘critical junctures’ in the life of autocratic regimes.

Supplementary Material

Online appendices are available at https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123422000655.

Data Availability Statement

Replication data for this article can be found in Harvard Dataverse at: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/NJFAQV.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Milan Svolik, Joseph Wright, the participants at Purdue University's Political Science Research Workshop (November 2020), and three anonymous reviewers for their valuable feedback on previous versions of the paper.

Financial Support

None

Conflicts of Interest

None.

Footnotes

1 These include international conflict (e.g. Colgan and Weeks Reference Colgan and Weeks2015; Weeks Reference Weeks2012), nuclear proliferation (Way and Weeks Reference Way and Weeks2014), civil war (e.g. Roessler Reference Roessler2011), and violent repression (Frantz et al. Reference Frantz2019).

2 Most works have focused on explaining the creation of formal pseudo-democratic institutions; namely, legislatures, parties, and elections (Gandhi Reference Gandhi2008; Magaloni Reference Magaloni2008; Svolik Reference Svolik2012). The existence of institutions is often assumed to signify the presence of effective constraints to the dictator's power, although they are, in fact, compatible (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018; Timoneda Reference Timoneda2020). As for regime types, scholars have mostly focused on the emergence of military rule and the impact of internal and external conflict (Eibl, Hertog, and Slater Reference Eibl, Hertog and Slater2021; Kim Reference Kim2019).

3 The democratizing impact of coups may be conditional on international reactions (Thyne and Hitch Reference Thyne and Hitch2020; Thyne et al. Reference Thyne2018), aid dependence (Marinov and Goemans Reference Marinov and Goemans2014), economic development or interdependence (Chacha and Powell Reference Chacha and Powell2017; Miller Reference Miller2012; Miller Reference Miller2021), or the rank of coup makers (Albrecht, Koehler, and Schutz Reference Albrecht, Koehler and Schutz2021).

4 A quantitative replication of Thyne and Powell (Reference Thyne and Powell2016) by Chin (Reference Chin2017, Chapter 4) found a positive effect of (some types of) successful coups but not of failed attempts on post-coup democratization.

5 A liberalizing or power-sharing response mainly works by reducing incentives to rebel by co-opting and giving elites and other social groups a say in policy making (Bove and Rivera Reference Bove and Rivera2015; Woo and Conrad Reference Woo and Conrad2019). Yet recurring policy disagreements or failed bargains can lead to renewed opposition against the leader.

6 Indeed, coup-proofing strategies such as the creation of paramilitary units or altering promotion and recruitment policies are often met with preemptive reactions from disgruntled military officers (De Bruin Reference De Bruin2018; Harkness Reference Harkness2018; Roessler Reference Roessler2011).

7 Actively opposing a failed coup is a clear signal of loyalty. Even remaining neutral and not joining a coup constitutes a sign of relative loyalty to the leader. If presented with a credible option to topple the regime some insiders opt not to, they are tacitly accepting the legitimacy of the leader.

8 Woldense (Reference Woldense2022) suggests that some co-conspirators may evade notice and still constitute an invisible enemy. However, it is likely that some can be later identified as captured coup makers are tortured and otherwise coerced into revealing their identities. Even if unidentified, the purge of those who executed the coup and the need to remain in hiding severely limit their ability to reorganize in the short term.

9 Also, reprisals against conspirators may also bolster compliance and deter future plots.

10 Coups against strong leaders are likely to fail. While they may take place from time to time, the fact that they are launched is mostly due to ex-ante uncertainty about the leader's strength (Timoneda Reference Timoneda2020).

11 As Easton and Siverson (Reference Easton and Siverson2018, 599) clearly put it, compared to successful ones, ‘failed coups rarely paint so clear a picture, with coup conspirators failing due to incompetence, poor planning, foreign intervention, a lack of commitment, or simple bad luck. Consequently, failed coups rarely reveal much about the relative strengths of either coup plotters or surviving leaders.’

12 Loyalty is typically increased by installing relatives and/or co-ethnics (Geddes, Wright, and Frantz Reference Geddes, Wright and Frantz2018) or even outsiders (including foreigners) (Woldense Reference Woldense2022) in top positions and in the security forces. Challenges and defections become more unlikely since the fate of handpicked elites is tied more closely to that of the dictator and they lack independent support bases.

13 Having loyal agents gives dictators an informational advantage over other elite members, ensures obedience to orders to use violence against opponents, and informs potential enemies about the costs of rebelling.

14 To maximize consistency with prior coup datasets, the Colpus dataset includes coup attempts not only against GWF regime leaders but also against civilian ‘nominal executives’ under indirect military regimes. These latter coup attempts are excluded from our analyses because they target nominal executives for which we lack personalism data.

15 The GWF personalism data is computed annually on January 1 of each calendar year. We impute all monthly values for a given year with the same value for that one specific year. Although our results would be more precise with monthly personalism data, we have no reason to expect that treating personalism as constant within calendar years systematically biases our results.

16 See the Appendix for the results with the leader spell year as the unit of observation. However, our strict fixed effects specifications have more difficulty converging in the smaller-form dataset, and even more so when only observing leader spells three years before and after a failed coup. Our imputation does not raise theoretical issues of particular concern, as shown by the almost identical results obtained when using yearly data.

17 We lag our main failed coup variables by 1 year (12 months).

18 These leader spells are only observed before the failed coup, not after.

19 Data on military spending are available from the Correlates of War project (National Material Capabilities dataset v5.0). Oil income data is available in Fails' (Reference Fails2019) replication files: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/0KL6JK. We use GDP per capita and economic growth data from the World Bank Databank (NY.GDP.PCAP.CD and NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG).

20 Descriptive statistics for other variables are in the appendix.

21 These models do not include a time trend or year fixed effects for the following theoretical and empirical reasons. First, a time trend controls for the positive or negative evolution of both dependent and independent variables over time. Models in Table 1 only explore the short-term effect of failed coups on personalism, making it unnecessary to de-trend the data, especially the low correlation between time and failed coups. As for year fixed effects, they control for the latent probability that coups happen in a given year. In the immediate sample, coups happen at different times and, therefore, the time panel is severely unbalanced – some years have fewer than seven observations. This is reflected in the Variance Inflation Factor for all variables in the model, which increases to over 50 when year fixed effects are added. Lastly, note that we are explaining around 85 per cent of the variation in personalism in all models. We add year fixed effects to the better-balanced panel in Table 2.

22 Besides the year and regime ID fixed effects, we run an Oster test to ensure that omitted variable bias is not affecting the results. The adjusted coefficient from the Oster test is slightly higher than in Table 1 for all models, further strengthening the results.

23 Marginal effects plots are in the Appendix (Figure 3).

24 The model used is an autoregressive model with lagged personalism as the main explanatory variable, and includes controls for military expenditures and oil income.

25 We keep the sample to those leader spells that experienced one event because otherwise we cannot establish a before-and-after comparison. Leaders who were successfully deposed by a successful coup exit the sample and those that never experienced a failed coup do not display their behaviour after the event. The synthetic control approach in the next section aims to provide a counterfactual to the more explicitly approximate potential causal effect of a failed coup on personalization.

26 As noted in Chin, Wright, and Carter (forthcoming, Reference Chin, Wright and Carter2022, 612), ‘The failed 1973 coup attempt led to the passage of a constitutional amendment giving the president more power. With Shihab having been killed, al-Bakr took over as minister of defence. The coup attempt also led to the creation in 1973 of the notorious Department of General Intelligence (DGI), which was initially headed by a Tikriti, Saadun Shakir (an RCC member). His deputy at DGI was Barzan Hussein, Saddam Hussein's younger half-brother.’

27 This is especially important since the underlying personalism data is available only at the yearly level, so our monthly predictions have a certain amount of white noise as they result from cross-regime averages. A three-year period before and after a failed coup (six years in total) allows us to maximize sample size and provide reliable results considering the underlying characteristics of the data.

28 As opposed to synchronous interventions, failed coups happen at different times. We centre all our data at the time of the failed coup and keep monthly observations up to three years before and after it. We thus maximize the available number of comparison groups as well as the variation in the underlying personalism data.

29 In the absence of a failed coup, we prepared the sample in such a way that the treatment group is centred around its mean duration in months.

30 Fitted using the multiple.synth () function from R package SCtools.

31 We also explore whether there could be a conditional relationship between pre-failed coup and post-failed coup personalism levels (Chacha and Powell Reference Chacha and Powell2017). We find that personalism increases after a failed coup in regimes with both low and high levels of pre-coup personalism (the results are available from the authors).

32 “The so-called DAF (déserteurs de l'armée française) group, for example, including the tank battalion commander, Slimane Hoffman, and the director of Boumediene's private office (chef de cabinet), Abdelkader Chabou, were men whose professional military expertise, combined with their lack of pre-war militant credentials (which mirrored his own), and consequent lack of other connections in the wartime FLN, made them especially useful – and close – to Boumediene” (McDougall Reference McDougall2017, 252). The rise of the DAF group was said to have incensed the ex-ALN veterans who led the December 1967 coup (McDougall Reference McDougall2017, 255).

33 Nevertheless, coming from the small Somba ethnic group that made up no more than 5–7 per cent of the population, Kérékou relied on a policy of ethnic quotas to ensure a measure of ethnic balance in the military rather than pursue an all-out policy of ethnic stacking (Harkness Reference Harkness2018, 190).

References

Abadie, A (2021) Using synthetic controls: Feasibility, data requirements, and methodological aspects. Journal of Economic Literature 59(2), 391425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abadie, A, Diamond, A and Hainmueller, J (2015) Comparative politics and the synthetic control method. American Journal of Political Science 59(2), 495510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abadie, A and Gardeazabal, J (2003) The economic costs of conflict: A case study of the Basque country. American Economic Review 93(1), 113–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akindes, S (2015) Civil-military relations in Benin: Out of the barracks and back–now what? In Rupiya, MR, Moyo, G and Laugesen, H (eds), The New African Civil-Military Relations, South Africa: The African Public Policy & Research Institute, 3864.Google Scholar
Albrecht, H, Koehler, K and Schutz, A (2021) Coup agency and prospects for democracy. International Studies Quarterly 65(4), 1052–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, C (1992) Restructuring an authoritarian state: ‘Democratic renewal’ in Benin. Review of African Political Economy 19(54), 4258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Associated Press (1967) Regime in Algeria says that 6 aides will get new jobs. New York Times, December 11, 14.Google Scholar
Associated Press (1971) Sierra Leone army puts down a coup. New York Times, March 24, 2.Google Scholar
Baxley, R (2011) Shifting loyalties: Libya's dynamic tribalism. Harvard International Review 33(2), 6.Google Scholar
Berry, L (1989) Libya: Historical setting. Chap. 1 in Libya: A country study, In Metz, HC (ed.), Area Handbook, 4th edn. Washington, DC: Library of Congress, 160.Google Scholar
Boix, C and Svolik, MW (2013) The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics 75(2), 300–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bokobza, L et al. (2022) The morning after: Cabinet instability and the purging of ministers after failed coup attempts in autocracies. Journal of Politics 84(3), 1437–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boutton, A (2019) Coup-proofing in the shadow of intervention: Alliances, moral hazard, and violence in authoritarian regimes. International Studies Quarterly 63(1), 4357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bove, V and Rivera, M (2015) Elite co-optation, repression, and coups in autocracies. International Interactions 41(3), 453–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno De Mesquita, B et al. (2003) The Logic of Political Survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capoccia, G and Kelemen, RD (2007) The study of critical junctures: Theory, narrative, and counterfactuals in historical institutionalism. World politics 59(3), 341–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casey, AE (2020) The durability of client regimes: Foreign sponsorship and military loyalty, 1946–2010. World Politics 72(3), 411447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chacha, M and Powell, J (2017) Economic interdependence and post-coup democratization. Democratization 24(5), 819–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chehabi, HE and Linz, JJ (eds) (1998) Sultanistic Regimes. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chin, JJ (2017) Military power and democratization (PhD diss.). Princeton University.Google Scholar
Chin, JJ, Carter, DB and Wright, JG (2021) The varieties of coups d’état: Introducing the Colpus dataset. International Studies Quarterly 65(4), 1040–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chin, JJ, Wright, JG and Carter, DB (forthcoming, 2022) Historical dictionary of modern coups d’état. Historical Dictionaries of War, Revolution, and Civil Unrest. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Clapham, C (1972) Sierra Leone: Civilian rule and the new republic. The World Today 28(2), 8291.Google Scholar
Colgan, JD and Weeks, JL (2015) Revolution, personalist dictatorships, and international conflict. International Organization 69(1), 163–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooley, JK (1982) Libyan Sandstorm: The Complete Account of Qaddafi's Revolution. New York: Holt, Rinehart/Winston.Google Scholar
Curtice, TB and Arnon, D (2020) Deterring threats and settling scores: How coups influence respect for physical integrity rights. Conflict Management and Peace Science 37(6), 655–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Bruin, E (2018) Preventing coups d’ètat: How counterbalancing works. Journal of Conflict Resolution 62(7), 1433–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Decalo, S (1973) Regionalism, politics, and the military in Dahomey. The Journal of Developing Areas 7(3), 449–78.Google Scholar
Decalo, S (1981) People's republic of Benin. Chap. 5. In Szajkowski, B (ed.), Marxist Governments. London, UK: Springer, 87115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Decalo, S (1989) Modalities of civil-military stability in Africa. Journal of Modern African Studies 27(4), 547–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Derpanopoulos, G et al. (2016) Are coups good for democracy? Research & Politics 3(1), 17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Derpanopoulos, G et al. (2017) Are coups good for democracy? A response to Miller (2016). Research & Politics 4(2), 14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easton, MR and Siverson, RM (2018) Leader survival and purges after a failed coup d'etat. Journal of Peace Research 55(5), 596608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eibl, F, Hertog, S and Slater, D (2021) War makes the regime: Regional rebellions and political militarization worldwide. British Journal of Political Science 52(3), 1002–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Escribà-Folch, A (2013) . Accountable for what? Regime types, performance, and the fate of outgoing dictators, 1946–2004. Democratization 20(1), 160–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, M and Phillips, J (2007) Algeria: Anger of the Dispossessed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Fails, MD (2019) Oil income and the personalization of autocratic politics. Political Science Research and Methods 8(4), 18.Google Scholar
Feliu, L and Aarab, R (2019) The transformation of the power structure and security in Libya: From a unified to a fragmented security sector. Contemporary Arab Affairs 12(1), 7590.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frantz, E et al. (2019) Personalization of power and repression in dictatorships. Journal of Politics 82(1), 372–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fyle, MC (1994) The military and civil society in Sierra Leone: The 1992 military coup d'etat. Africa Development/Afrique et Développement 19(2), 127–46.Google Scholar
Fyle, MC (2006) Historical Dictionary of Sierra Leone, 2nd edn. Historical Dictionaries of Africa99. Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press.Google Scholar
Gandhi, J (2008) Political Institutions Under Dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaub, F (2013) The Libyan armed forces between coup-proofing and repression. Journal of Strategic Studies 36(2), 221–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, B (1999) What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science 2(1), 115–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, B, Wright, J and Frantz, E (2014) Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: A new data set. Perspectives on Politics 12(2), 313331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geddes, B, Wright, J and Frantz, E (2018) How Dictatorships Work: Power, Personalization, and Collapse. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemans, H, Gleditsch, KS and Chiozza, G (2009) Introducing Archigos: A dataset of political leaders. Journal of Peace Research 46(2), 269–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goemans, HE (2008) Which way out? The manner and consequences of losing office. Journal of Conflict Resolution 53(6), 771–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harkness, KA (2018) When Soldiers Rebel: Ethnic Armies and Political Instability in Africa. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, DJ (2014) Sierra Leone: A Political History. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Horowitz, DL (1985) Ethnic Groups in Conflict. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Houngnikpo, MC and Decalo, S (2013) Historical Dictionary of Benin, 4th edn. Historical dictionaries of Africa. Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press.Google Scholar
Hughes, A (1971) Sierra Leone. Chap. 5, In Macadam, I, Grindrod, M and Boas, A (eds). The Annual Register, vol 213. World Events in 1971. London, UK: Longman, 246–47.Google Scholar
Kaplan, I (1976) Area Handbook for Sierra Leone. Vol 550. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kebschull, HG (1994) Operation “just missed”: Lessons from failed coup attempts. Armed Forces & Society 20(4), 565–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kendall-Taylor, A, Frantz, E and Wright, J (2017) The global rise of personalized politics: It's not just dictators anymore. The Washington Quarterly 40(1), 719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, NK (2019) External territorial threats and military regimes. Political Research Quarterly 72(4), 863–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kline, B (1992) Sierra Leone: Civilian-military republic. Chap. 11 in from military to civilian rule, In Danopoulos, CP (ed.), New York: Routledge, 214–29.Google Scholar
Krogstad, EG (2012) Security, development, and force: Revisiting police reform in Sierra Leone. African Affairs 111(443), 261–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lachapelle, J (2020) No easy way out: The effect of military coups on state repression. Journal of Politics 82(4), 1354–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lenze, PE Jr (2016) Civil-military Relations in the Islamic World. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Little, AT (2017) Coordination, learning, and coups. Journal of Conflict Resolution 61(1), 204–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luke, DF (1988) Continuity in Sierra Leone: From Stevens to Momoh. Third World Quarterly 10(1), 6778.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lutterbeck, D (2013) Arab uprisings, armed forces, and civil-military relations. Comparative Politics 39(1), 2852.Google Scholar
Magaloni, B (2008) Credible power-sharing and the longevity of authoritarian rule. Comparative Political Studies 41(4–5), 715–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marinov, N and Goemans, H (2014) Coups and democracy. British Journal of Political Science 44(4), 799825.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, ML (1985) The rise and ‘thermidorianization'of racial praetorianism in Benin. Journal of Communist Studies 1(3–4), 5881.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDougall, J (2017) A History of Algeria. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meng, A (2020) Constraining Dictatorship: From Personalized Rule to Institutionalized Regimes. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, MK (2012) Economic development, violent leader removal, and democratization. American Journal of Political Science 56(4), 1002–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, MK (2016) Reanalysis: Are coups good for democracy? Research & Politics 3(4), 15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, MK (2021) Shock to the System. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Morency-Laflamme, J (2018) A question of trust: Military defection during regime crises in Benin and Togo. Democratization 25(3), 464480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naylor, PC (2015) Historical Dictionary of Algeria, 4th edn. Historical Dictionaries of Africa102. Lanham, MD: Scarecrow Press.Google Scholar
New York Times (1967) Algeria reports crushing revolt by army faction. New York Times, December 16, 1.Google Scholar
Ottaway, D and Ottaway, M (1970) Algeria: The Politics of A Socialist Revolution. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oztig, LI and Donduran, M (2020) Failed coups, political survival, and civil liberties restrictions in nondemocratic regimes. The Social Science Journal 57, 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollack, KM (2002) Arabs at war: Military Effectiveness, 1948–1991. Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Powell, J, Chacha, M and Smith, GE (2018) Failed coups, democratization, and authoritarian entrenchment: Opening up or digging in? African Affairs 118(471), 238–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, JM and Thyne, CL (2011) Global instances of coups from 1950 to 2010: a new dataset. Journal of Peace Research 48(2), 249–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quandt, WB (1972) Algerian military development: The professionalization of a guerrilla army. Technical report. Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
Reno, W (2003) Sierra Leone: Warfare in a post-state society. In Rotberg, RI (ed.), State Failure and State Weakness in A Time of Terror. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 71100.Google Scholar
Roberts, H (1984) The politics of Algerian socialism. North Africa: Contemporary Politics and Economic Development. London: Croom Helm, pp. 549.Google Scholar
Roessler, P (2011) The enemy within: Personal rule, coups, and civil war in Africa. World Politics 63(2), 300–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, N (2014) Seizing Power: The Strategic Logic of Military Coups. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
St. John, RB (2014) Historical Dictionary of Libya, 5th edn. Historical Dictionaries of Africa. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.Google Scholar
St. John, RB (2015) Libya: Continuity and Change, 2nd edn. New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sudduth, JK (2017) Strategic logic of elite purges in dictatorships. Comparative Political Studies 50(13), 17681801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sudduth, JK and Bell, C (2018) The rise predicts the fall: How the method of leader entry affects the method of leader removal in dictatorships. International Studies Quarterly 62(1), 145159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, M (2009) Power sharing and leadership dynamics in authoritarian regimes. American Journal of Political Science 53(2), 477494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svolik, M (2012) The Politics of Authoritarian Rule. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tartter, JR (1994) National security. Chap. 5 in Algeria: A country study, In Metz, HC (ed.), Area Handbook, 5th edn. Washington, DC: Library of Congress, 238–84.Google Scholar
Thyne, C and Hitch, K (2020) Democratic versus authoritarian coups: The influence of external actors on states’ postcoup political trajectories. Journal of Conflict Resolution 64(10), 1857–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thyne, C et al. (2018) Even generals need friends: How domestic and international reactions to coups influence regime survival. Journal of Conflict Resolution 62(7), 1406–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thyne, CL and Powell, JM (2016) Coup d’état or coup d'autocracy? How coups impact democratization, 1950–2008. Foreign Policy Analysis 12(2), 192213.Google Scholar
Timoneda, JC (2020) Institutions as signals: How dictators consolidate power in times of crisis. Comparative Politics 53(1), 4968.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Timoneda, JC, Escribà-Folch, A and Chin, J (2023) “Replication Data for: The Rush To Personalize: Power Concentration After Failed Coups in Dictatorships”. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/NJFAQV, Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:kzAs2B8qu39f2OAD1VaMIw== [fileUNF]Google Scholar
United Press International (1975) Dahomey sentences 7 to die. New York Times, March 19, 30.Google Scholar
Vandewalle, D (1998) Libya Since Independence: Oil and State-Building. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varol, OO (2017) The democratic coup d’état. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vidler, E (1998) Regime survival in the Gambia and Sierra Leone: A comparative study of the people's progressive party (1965–1994) and the all people's congress (1968–1992) (PhD diss.). University of Newcastle upon Tyne.Google Scholar
Way, C and Weeks, JLP (2014) Making it personal: Regime type and nuclear proliferation. American Journal of Political Science 58(3), 705–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weeks, JLP (2012) Strongmen and straw men: Authoritarian regimes and the initiation of international conflict. American Political Science Review 106(2), 326–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilton-Marshall, O and Shaw, G (1975) Chapter 3: French-speaking West and Central Africa. In Hodson, HV, Hoffman, V and Bose, B (eds), The Annual Register, vol 217. World Events in 1975. London: Longman, 223–29.Google Scholar
Woldense, J (2022) What happens when coups fail? The problem of identifying and weakening the enemy within. Comparative Political Studies 55(7), 1236–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woo, AS and Conrad, CR (2019) The differential effects of “democratic” institutions on dissent in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics 81(2), 456–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, J (2021) The latent characteristics that structure autocratic rule. Political Science Research and Methods 9(1), 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zartman, IW (1970) The Algerian army in politics. Chap. 5. In Welch, CE Jr (eds), Soldier and State in Africa. Evanston, IL: Northwestern University Press, 224–49.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Immediate effect of failed coups on latent personalization (DV) using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

Figure 1

Table 2. Long-term effect of failed coups on latent personalization (DV) using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

Figure 2

Table 3. Immediate effect of a failed coup on the different dimensions of personalism (Hypothesis 2), using COLPUS (left) and P&T (right), the two measures of failed coups available in the literature

Figure 3

Figure 1. Predicted personalism before and after a failed coup (x = 0) based on model (b) from Table 1. Personalism variable scaled between 0 and 1. 95% confidence intervals shown.

Figure 4

Figure 2. Predicted personalism before and after a failed coup attempt, based on the synthetic control model. The personalism variable is scaled between 0 and 1. 95% confidence intervals shown.

Figure 5

Figure 3. Synthetic control results for Algeria, Sierra Leone, Bangladesh, Benin, Iraq, and Azerbaijan, based on synthetic control models for each individual case. The personalism variable is scaled between 0 and 1.

Supplementary material: PDF

Timoneda et al. supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Timoneda et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 225.8 KB
Supplementary material: Link

Timoneda et al. Dataset

Link