Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T05:50:30.905Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Informational lobbying, information asymmetry, and the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy in the U.S. States

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 February 2024

Yuni Wen*
Affiliation:
Saïd Business School, University of Oxford, Oxford, UK
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Existing research on lobbying has predominantly focused on its material returns, such as equity returns, stock prices, and government contracts while overlooking its informational impact. This paper addresses this gap by investigating to what extent and under what conditions policymakers assimilate information delivered through corporate lobbying. Drawing on an informational perspective, it proposes that the informational effect of lobbying is moderated by the information asymmetry between policymakers and firms. Focusing on the U.S. ride-hailing industry, this study utilizes a unique dataset on U.S. state legislatures’ adoption of the model policy lobbied by ride-hailing companies. The results reveal that the informational impact of corporate lobbying is highly contingent upon the presence of information asymmetry between policymakers and firms, which can be attributed to policymakers’ resources for independent information gathering, information deliberation through public hearings or media discussions, and countervailing lobbying efforts.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Vinod K. Aggarwal

Introduction

Lobbying is a longstanding corporate political activity that firms deploy to shape policymaking through the transfer of information.Footnote 1 To capture the effectiveness of lobbying in helping firms advance their interests, existing research has examined how firms’ monetary expenditures in persuading government officials are associated with firm-level outcomes, such as equity returns, stock prices, and government contracts,Footnote 2 as well as the enactment of policies.Footnote 3 However, this prevalent emphasis on the material returns to lobbying, primarily driven by data availability, can obscure the informational nature of lobbying. An alternative informational view of lobbying contends that the financial resources firms allocate to lobbying activities do not automatically generate pressure on policymakers. Instead, the transmission of information plays the key role, as policymakers seek information to determine their position on a given issue and choose the best policy option.Footnote 4 For this reason, despite many studies on the effectiveness of lobbying, we still know little about to what extent and under what circumstances lobbying can effectively deliver information to policymakers.

The investigation of the effectiveness of lobbying in delivering information has been constrained by data. This is because lobbying often takes place in a private and covert manner, and measuring and quantifying the information transmitted through lobbying is challenging.Footnote 5 To overcome this challenge, this paper focuses on the U.S. ride-hailing industry and utilizes a unique dataset on the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by U.S. state governments. Model policies are draft policies promoted by firms on a particular issue to wider groups of legislators as the template for policymaking.Footnote 6 Since 2015, ride-hailing firms have employed an army of lobbyists to promote a model policy to the fifty state governments.Footnote 7 The content of the ride-hailing model policy was made available by the Centre for Media and Democracy,Footnote 8 and as of now, 49 U.S. state governments have passed 86 policies governing ride-hailing services. By analyzing the extent to which the passed policies incorporate the model policy across different states, I aim to capture variation in policymakers’ adoption of information delivered through firm lobbying. Additionally, I will explore the conditions that contribute to these varying levels of information intake.

Building upon the informational perspective of lobbying, this paper proposes that policymakers’ intake of information provided by firms is co-determined by two key factors: the lobbying efforts made by firms to transmit information and the information asymmetry between policymakers and firms. This paper further argues that such information asymmetry is the result of (1) policymakers’ resources to gather their own information on a given issue, (2) information deliberation through public hearings or media discussions, and (3) countervailing lobbying efforts. The empirical findings in the U.S. ride-hailing industry provide compelling support for this argument, indicating that the informational impact of lobbying activities of ride-hailing firms is heavily reliant on the presence of significant information asymmetry between state legislators and ride-hailing firms.

This study is expected to make several contributions to the literature on corporate political activities (CPAs). First, it shifts the focus from the traditional emphasis on the material returns of corporate lobbying to the informational view of lobbying. It speaks to the growing body of work on informational lobbying by analyzing the delivery of information not merely as the substance but also as the outcome of lobbying activities.Footnote 9 Second, this research addresses the long-standing data restriction and measurement challenges in lobbying studies regarding the informational impact of lobbying.Footnote 10 It overcomes this limitation by leveraging a unique dataset on the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by fifty U.S. state governments. Third, this study contributes to the emerging stream of CPA literature that focuses on the supplier side of the political market.Footnote 11 It sheds light on information asymmetry as a crucial characteristic of policy suppliers. It provides a nuanced picture of how information asymmetry moderates the impact of firm lobbying, while not affecting petitions and campaign contributions.

Theory and hypotheses

An informational view of lobbying

Firms engage in various CPAs to influence public policies in their favor.Footnote 12 These activities include providing information, building constituencies, and making financial contributions.Footnote 13 Among them, lobbying, which refers to the transfer of information between firms and politicians in private settings,Footnote 14 is the most commonly used corporate political strategy.Footnote 15 This is because compared to campaign contributions, which provide financial support to political candidates during elections, lobbying is low-profile and subject to less public scrutinyFootnote 16 ; unlike grassroots mobilization, which relies on third-party stakeholders to pressure politicians, lobbying allows firms to directly convey their demands without distortion.Footnote 17

Existing CPA literature has predominantly treated lobbying as a material transaction between firms and politicians.Footnote 18 Early studies placed significant emphasis on the amount of expenditure firms spend on lobbying government officials,Footnote 19 but more recently, research has started to focus on the specific government entities targeted by firm lobbying and the breadth of their lobbying expenditure.Footnote 20 Moreover, the current measurements of returns to lobbying have mostly focused on firm-level material benefits, such as accounting-based firm performance,Footnote 21 government contracts awarded to a focal firm,Footnote 22 tax breaks,Footnote 23 and stock market prices.Footnote 24 For instance, Chen, Parsley, and Yang’s comprehensive analysis of firms in Compustat showed that firms’ lobbying expenditures are positively associated with their performance, measured by assets, sales, and stock prices.Footnote 25 To a lesser extent, a few studies have underscored the enactment of policies as the consequence of lobbying.Footnote 26 For example, Kang indicated that the energy industry’s lobbying efforts had a significant, albeit modest, impact on the probability of energy law enactments by the U.S. Congress.Footnote 27 This emphasis on the material returns to lobbying is primarily driven by the availability of data, as the data on firm-level benefits, and policy enactments are accessible and observable.Footnote 28

However, this prevalent focus on material returns to lobbying overshadows the fact that lobbying inherently involves transmission of information and that firms can directly benefit from transmitting their private information into public policies.Footnote 29 A group of political scientists has advocated for an informational view of lobbying, which posits that the interaction between firms and politicians primarily involves the exchange of information and messages, rather than material goods or services.Footnote 30 Although firms allocate financial resources to lobbying activities, this money is not explicitly transferred to politicians, as is the case with campaign contributions.Footnote 31 Instead, the value of lobbying lies in “the storage of good information and the ability to convey it in a useful way” (quoted in Levine, Reference Levine2009). On the one hand, policymakers always feel “information starved” (quoted in Levine, Reference Levine2009)—They need information to choose the best alternative among all policy options and decide their positions on a policy issue to enhance their own chances of re-election.Footnote 32 On the other hand, firms acquire relevant information, and they gain influence by strategically revealing that information through lobbyists to sway policymakers toward their preferred policy.Footnote 33 The National Institute for Lobbying and Ethics made this statement, “Information must be provided in order to produce informed decisions. Public officials cannot make fair and informed decisions without considering information from a broad range of interested parties”. Footnote 34

The importance of informational lobbying has also been highlighted by some empirical and model studies. For example, Drutman and Hopkins, through an analysis of emails sent by Enron employees, demonstrated that Enron’s lobbying efforts relied on their “monopoly on policy-relevant information” to persuade policymakers.Footnote 35 Austen-Smith introduced a policymaking model accounting for incomplete information, where he posits that lobbyists, though without legislative power, can exert great influence on policies with the specialist information they offer, and their influence differs at different policy stages.Footnote 36 Similarly, several case studies emphasized the idea of “access”, which refers to the exchange of policy-relevant information with public actors.Footnote 37 Furthermore, Bruycker identified two modes of information supply of lobbying: one is the transmission of technical, economic, and legal expertise, and the other is political information, which is to indicate the level of public support and opposition to a specific decision.Footnote 38 These are echoed in the work of Albareda and colleagues, whose survey of EU public officials suggests that the capacity of interest groups to affect policy is linked to their supply of both technical expertise and insights into public sentiment. Footnote 39

Despite the growing body of work on informational lobbying, it has failed to capture the effectiveness of lobbying in delivering information. In the political market where both firms and politicians derive private gains from their exchange, Footnote 40 such gains for corporate lobbying accrue not only from corporates’ material outcomes but also from the extent to which policymakers assimilate the information transmitted through corporate lobbying. Lobbying activities have traditionally taken place covertly within private settings, making it challenging to discern the specifics of the information being communicated.Footnote 41 Additionally, quantifying and measuring information itself poses a significant challenge. Obtaining data on the informational need of government agents and measuring their intake of the information provided is difficult, further complicating the research process.Footnote 42 This paper aims to fill this gap by investigating the extent to which and under what conditions policymakers adopt information delivered through corporate lobbying. Specifically, it employs a unique dataset of the model policy lobbied by U.S. ride-hailing firms. By measuring the extent to which the model policy is manifested in the enacted policies, it captures the informational impacts of lobbying.

As indicated by the informational view of lobbying, it is expected that with more corporate lobbying efforts to deliver information, policymakers would incorporate a greater amount of corporate-derived information into their policymaking. Here the lobbying efforts are operationalized as the number of lobbyists because firms can achieve the spread of information through multiple lobbyists. Network theory suggests that a greater number of lobbyists can tap into diverse networks and channels within the political sphere, therefore facilitating information spread.Footnote 43 Communication theory also indicates that more lobbyists mean information redundancy, which increases the likelihood that key messages reach their intended targets.Footnote 44 It therefore generates the baseline hypothesis as follows.

Baseline Hypothesis: The volume of information policymakers adopt from firms is positively associated with firms’ lobbying efforts.

Additionally, the effectiveness of lobbying is contingent upon contextual factors, especially the characteristics of policy suppliers.Footnote 45 A growing body of CPA research has recognized the heterogeneous and dynamic nature of politicians’ receptivity to corporate political strategy, shifting focus from the demand side to the supply side of the political market.Footnote 46 As highlighted by two recent reviews of CPA scholarship, firms engage with various government actors within specific institutional contexts.Footnote 47 Notably, Choi et al. utilized cross-country firm-level data and found that the influence of firms’ lobbying activities on public policies depends on the levels of political competition and electoral accountability faced by policymakers in different countries.Footnote 48 This paper delves into one particular feature of policy suppliers—information asymmetry, and its impact on the effectiveness of lobbying, measured by policymakers’ assimilation of information from firms.

Information asymmetry between policymakers and firms

The informational view of lobbying is based on the premise that policymakers are less informed than firms on a relevant policy issue.Footnote 49 Policymakers face significant challenges when it comes to accessing and evaluating the economic and technical consequences of policies and gauging public opinion on them. Meanwhile, much of the information necessary for assessing the economic consequences of policies is readily available to businesses.Footnote 50 This information asymmetry arises not only from the capacity limitations and broader range of responsibilities faced by policymakers,Footnote 51 but also from firms’ incentives to research issues of concern for their own survival. Moreover, firms have the advantage of gathering information about relevant policy matters through their daily operations, granting them access to private information that holds significant importance for political decision-making.Footnote 52 For example, a case study by Mello, Abiola, and Colgrove highlighted that Merck’s provision of policy-relevant information resulted in the introduction of cervical cancer vaccinations in 41 states and proposed mandates in 24 states for teenage girls.Footnote 53 Policymakers openly acknowledged their reliance on Merck’s lobbying efforts for making policy changes. Gao and McDonald’s recent case study on the personal genomic industry discovered that the industry organized a series of private workshops and meetings with the Food and Drug Administration, which was in information deficiency of the new technology; as a result, the industry was able to develop a set of recommendations for personal genomics, including data privacy and accuracy of test results, which were eventually adopted by the regulators.Footnote 54 This paper argues that information asymmetry between policymakers and firms is the result of three factors: firstly, policymakers have limited resources to independently gather information regarding policy issues; secondly, there is an absence of public deliberation concerning the matter; and thirdly, there is a deficiency in countervailing lobbying activities.

Information gathering

Policymakers tend to gather information with regard to a given issue on their own in order to choose the best alternative among all policy options.Footnote 55 They are aware that firms can selectively present or withhold information in a manner that aligns with their own interests.Footnote 56 However, policymakers require resources to gather information.Footnote 57 The concept of legislative professionalism was created to refer to the amount of resource policymakers can devote to policymaking.Footnote 58 On one end, professional legislatures receive relatively high pay, have large staffs, and tend to hold no other jobs outside of their political position. On the other end, the so-called citizen or amateur legislatures have small staffs, receive relatively low compensation, and usually have another income source.Footnote 59 Professional legislators are able to conduct research on a given issue and tailor policies to their own needs.Footnote 60 Part-time policymakers, especially those who are not well compensated, have no time or motivation to adequately gather information on larger and more complex issues.Footnote 61 Policymakers’ capacity to collect information can also be compromised in the absence of experienced supporting staff, such as scientists to help forecast its benefits and risks, economists and accountants to calculate expenditure, and committee staff to conduct research and provide internal sources of information.Footnote 62

The significance of resource constraints faced by policymakers has been extensively documented. Adopting a resource exchange perspective, various research suggests that public officials often seek the expertise, specialized knowledge, or political acumen of interest groups, which in turn bolsters the legitimacy and effectiveness of forthcoming legislations. Footnote 63 In particular, scholars have highlighted the heavy reliance of constrained policymakers on information from firms,Footnote 64 and how this reliance transforms firms into de facto “service bureaus”.Footnote 65 The growing dependence of policymakers on firms for information can be attributed to the escalating complexity of policy issues and the declining policymaking capacity in the United States.Footnote 66 As an example, at the Federal level, there is a decline in congressional staff while the workload remains steady in terms of bill introductions and passage; meanwhile, an increase in the number of votes and pages in the Federal Register indicates a growing level of policy complexity.Footnote 67 By this view, policymakers, who are operating with limited resources to gather information, are more likely to rely on information provided by firms. Therefore, the hypothesis is summarized as follows.

Hypothesis 1: The positive relationship between corporate lobbying and policymakers’ adoption of information from corporations is weakened as policymakers’ capacity for independent information gathering increases.

Information deliberation

Policy deliberation is a process in which policymakers, stakeholders, and members of the public discuss information, ideas, and perspectives related to a particular policy issue.Footnote 68 In this process, individuals can cultivate and articulate their viewpoints, acquire knowledge about the positions of others, and ultimately gain insight and make informed judgments about matters of public significance.Footnote 69 It provides a platform for policymakers to directly listen to different perspectives and information on a policy issue from different stakeholders.Footnote 70 Policymakers may therefore be exposed to new information that they had not previously known or considered, which can lead to a greater understanding of the issue at hand.Footnote 71 For instance, it has been shown that individuals who engaged in a sequence of deliberative discussion regarding the influence of money in politics exhibited enhanced understanding of the subject matter.Footnote 72 In a similar vein, policy deliberation can lead to more inclusive policy outcomes that take into account the demands and concerns of different groups rather than heavily leaning towards one party.Footnote 73 An experiment by Fishkin et al. demonstrated that deliberative polling—which involves balanced information intake, in-depth discussion with a diverse group, and moderator intervention to balance participation—yields more considered opinions than traditional polling methods.Footnote 74

Public hearings play a significant role in facilitating deliberation for policy formation, as they provide a structured platform for evaluating critical social, technological, and economic matters through formalized procedures.Footnote 75 In a public hearing, a legislative body invites representatives from government agencies, industries, academic researchers, advocacy groups, and members of the public to provide testimonies or comments on the proposed policy or decision.Footnote 76 Public hearings channel demands that are difficult for government to address because of limited resources, and provide an opportunity to challenge the prevailing discourse.Footnote 77 Mass media is another primary channel for political deliberation.Footnote 78 Page, while recognizing the “face-to-face ideal” for conventional deliberation, suggests that in contemporary democracies, deliberation is predominantly conducted through mass media, “who not only help policy experts communicate with each other, but also assemble, explain, debate, and disseminate the best available information and ideas about public policy, in ways that are accessible to large audiences of ordinary citizens.”Footnote 79 Habermas also refers to the mass media as the dominant public sphere of Western democracies where citizens can express their viewpoints and engage in critical debates.Footnote 80 Media coverage of an issue enhances policymakers’ and the public’s access to information regarding an issue, and consequently, they tend to form their views based on the information readily accessible to them through mass media sources.Footnote 81 It is therefore expected that information deliberation, represented by public hearings and media discussion, can weaken the informational impact of corporate lobbying on policymakers. The hypotheses are as follows.

Hypothesis 2a: The positive relationship between corporate lobbying and policymakers’ adoption of information from corporations is weakened with the occurrence of public hearings.Footnote 82

Hypothesis 2b: The positive relationship between corporate lobbying and policymakers’ adoption of information from corporations is weakened with more local media discussion.

Countervailing forces

Countervailing force theorists posit that in the regulatory landscape, the power of large businesses to influence policy decisions is moderated by the presence of opposing groups. These groups exert their own form of power to negotiate and advocate for interests that may counteract those of dominant firms, thus restoring public welfare and fair market practices.Footnote 83 Specifically, Austen-Smith and Wright pointed out that competing groups lobby strategically and counteractively to offset information from a group, so the result is a policy outcome that reflects the relative influence of the competing lobbying efforts.Footnote 84 In addition, the trustworthiness of each lobbyist’s information plays a critical role in whose input is valued more in the policymaking process.Footnote 85 It follows that when opposing lobbyists present conflicting information or perspectives, policymakers must discern which sources are more reliable and are less likely to fully trust any single party. It is therefore expected that the informational impact of corporate lobbying is diminished by the presence of countervailing lobbying efforts.

Hypothesis 3: The positive relationship between corporate lobbying and policymakers’ adoption of information from corporations is weakened with more countervailing lobbying efforts.

Data and method

Empirical context: the ride-hailing model policy

Ride-hailing firms, also known as transportation network firms (TNCs), utilize digital platforms to connect riders with private drivers. The ride-hailing sector is markedly monopolized, with Uber commanding the majority of the market at around 70 percent, followed by Lyft with about 20 percent. This study thus only focuses on these two companies. This industry was created in a regulatory gray area, with these firms asserting that they should be categorized as technology firms and exempt from traditional taxi regulations.Footnote 86 It sparked protests from taxi drivers nationwide and resulted in over 100 municipal governments implementing bans or moratoriums on ride-hailing firms.Footnote 87 The industry was faced with a series of regulatory controversies. For example, one main issue is how to define ride-hailing, especially how to differentiate it from taxi and for-hire services.Footnote 88 Insurance is another area of concern, as most traditional auto insurance policies do not cover commercial driving activities. It is unclear how to design insurance policies for ride-hailing drivers who mainly work part-time.Footnote 89 Safety is also a significant concern, with the question of whether and how vehicle inspections and driver background checks should be implemented to ensure passenger safety, or whether online ratings of drivers alone can ensure safety.Footnote 90

Starting in late 2014, ride-hailing firms began lobbying state governments in the hope of establishing new state-wide regulatory frameworks to clarify these regulatory issues.Footnote 91 To achieve this goal, Uber and Lyft joined the American Legislative Exchange Council (ALEC) and drafted a model policy in December 2014.Footnote 92 The model policy contained seven key regulatory issues, including the definition of transportation network firms (TNCs), regulatory authority, liability insurance, operating requirements such as driver background checks and vehicle inspections, information disclosure, conversion from taxi firms to TNCs, TNC funds, and obtaining permission.Footnote 93 Ride-hailing lobbyists have been advocating for and circulating the model policy among legislators across states.Footnote 94 One sponsor of the model policy praised it as “an effort by the concerned parties to help bring clarity and consistency to TNC laws across the country”.Footnote 95 By 2019, most U.S. states have enacted at least one policy to govern ride-hailing. It provides a unique setting to examine under what conditions policymakers assimilate information from firms, as measured by their adoption of ride-hailing model policies.

Sample and dependent variables

The sample for this study included all fifty U.S. states between 2015 and 2019. The sample began in 2015, as the model policy was made in December 2014, and ended in 2019, when most U.S. states had already issued state-wide policies to govern ride-hailing and the wave of ride-hailing policy enactments came to an end.

The dependent variable is the extent to which policymakers adopt information from firms into policymaking. This is measured using a proxy variable: the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by state legislatures. To assess this, I analyzed the text similarity between the model policy proposed by ride-hailing firms and the actual ride-hailing policies passed by state governments within a given year. The original text of the ride-hailing model policy was exposed by the Centre for Media and Democracy (CMD), a nationally recognized watchdog group for corruption and democracy. To triangulate the text, I also retrieved the text of the ride-hailing model policy from the Internet Archive, a nonprofit library that collects and preserves digital online content. Figure 1 is an excerpt of the model policy. To obtain the texts of all the ride-hailing policies passed by state governments, I searched the keyword “transportation network company (TNC)” in LegiScan, a website tracking all the state-level bills and laws. It shows a total of 86 ride-hailing policies enacted by 49 state governments, except Oregon.Footnote 96

Figure 1. An excerpt of the ride-hailing model policy.

I adopted two approaches to capture text similarity. The first approach is the cosine similarity score. It is a mathematical technique that calculates the cosine of the angle between two vectors, where the vectors represent the frequency of occurrence of each word in the texts.Footnote 97 The second approach is semantic matching, which measures the closeness of meaning between two texts, instead of a simple overlap of word sets.Footnote 98 I adopted Cortical, a recent AI tool that leverages natural language processing to understand the meaning of text data. It creates a semantic map where related snippets are grouped together and then compares the semantic fingerprints generated from input texts by activating relevant map positions. Both the cosine and semantic similarity scores range from 0 to 1, with 1 indicating perfect similarity between the two texts, and the two scores are highly correlated (r = 0.99). Figure 2 (1) illustrates the range of semantic text similarity scores among different states, highlighting an average score of 0.68. It means that the passed ride-hailing policies have incorporated a substantial proportion of the text of the model policy. Figure 2(2) presents variation in average semantic similarity scores across years.

Figure 2. Semantic text similarity score variation by state and by year.

Independent variables

The major independent variable is ride-hailing lobbying efforts, operationalized as the number of lobbyists hired by ride-hailing firms to influence a state government in a year. I obtained data on lobbying by ride-hailing firms from the National Institute of Money in State Politics, which discloses all the registered lobbyists working on state governments and their firm clients. I triangulated the lobbying data with the lobbying database provided by each state government. Lobbyist number is a more appropriate measurement of corporate lobbying efforts on the U.S. state level than lobbying expenditures.Footnote 99 This is due to the relatively incomplete lobbying expenditure records on the state level, as approximately 33 states do not mandate lobbyists to report expenditure data.Footnote 100 My own dataset also suggests that in over half of the instances where ride-hailing firms engaged in lobbying activities, as evidenced by reported lobbyists, they neglected to disclose their lobbying expenditures. Moreover, as discussed earlier, corporate lobbying efforts are quantified as the number of lobbyists, because a higher count leads to the effective spread of information across various political networks and channels, as well as information redundancy, enhancing the reception of critical messages.

Moderating variables

The first moderator of this study is legislative professionalism. Professional legislators have more resources to devote to gathering information for policymaking. I used the Squire’s Index, the most commonly adopted measurement for legislative professionalism.Footnote 101 The index consists of three dimensions: length of the legislative session, staff resources, and member pay. The states are scored between zero to one, with one indicating that a state legislature resembles Congress and zero indicating no resemblance whatsoever. For example, California, the highest ranked state in Squire’s Index, pays its legislators nearly as much as members of Congress with annual salaries of $116,000.27, and California’s legislature meets annually with no limit on session length and has an average of 8.9 staff per member. By contrast, New Hampshire pays its members $100 annually and only meets forty-five days a year.

The second moderator is ride-hailing public hearing. During those public hearings, state legislatures received testimonies and information input from various participants, not just ride-hailing firms, but also taxi firms, transportation officials, passengers, drivers, and academics. I measured it with a binary variable indicating whether a public hearing on ride-hailing issues was held in a particular state government in a given year. To obtain data on public hearings, I searched for the keywords “transportation network company” and “ride-hailing” in the archives of public hearings on the official websites of state legislative bodies in the United States. I only included legislative hearings and committee hearings that directly involved the legislative body, excluding the administrative and judicial hearings.

The third moderator is media discussion of ride-hailing. Local newspapers are key providers of political information.Footnote 102 I measured media deliberation by counting the number of local media reports discussing ride-hailing regulatory issues. I confined the search on both firms—Uber and Lyft—to the media database Factiva, and obtained news reports that contained the following key words: “regulation”, “political,” “public,” “policy,” “legislation,” and “legal.” Factiva allows media search by geographical locations of newspapers, so I was able to filter the local media articles published in a certain state. I then obtained the accumulated number of media reports on ride-hailing in that state in a year.

The fourth moderating variable is countervailing taxi lobbyists. It was measured as the number of lobbyists hired by taxi companies to influence a state government in a year. I collected the data from the National Institute of Money in State Politics, where I searched all the keywords related to taxi companies, including “taxi,” “limo,” and “cab.”

Control variables

I included a number of control variables. First, I controlled for other political strategies adopted by ride-hailing firms. I measured ride-hailing petitions (vote-based political strategy) with a dummy variable: whether ride-hailing firms called for their users to sign online petitions in a state in a year. I obtained the year in which they initiated petitions from ride-hailing firms’ petition websites and the signed support shared by ride-hailing users on social media. I measured ride-hailing campaign contributions (money-based political strategy) as the amount of money ride-hailing firms donated to a state election in a year. The campaign contribution data were also obtained from the National Institute of Money in State Politics.

Second, I accounted for other political actions of the taxi industry and other stakeholders. To identify taxi protests, I searched “protest” in combination with all the taxi-related keywords in Factiva. I created a count variable to indicate the number of taxi protests in a state in a year. The control variable of taxi campaign contributions was measured as the amount of money taxi firms donated to a state election in a year. The data source was the National Institute of Money in State Politics. Similarly, I included the lobbying influence of insurance companies, which are important allies of ride-hailing companies in promoting the model policy. The following insurance companies were involved in the making and promoting of the ride-hailing model policy: Allstate, Farmers Insurance, State Farm, United Services Automobile Association, the American Insurance Association, the National Association of Mutual Insurance Companies, and the Property Casualty Insurers Association of America.Footnote 103 I obtained their lobbying data from the National Institute of Money in State Politics.

Third, I considered the market demand for ride-hailing because ride-hailing firms may have more influence in states where they have larger markets. One proxy for market demand is the urban population in a state in a year, considering that ride-hailing is mainly operating in population-dense areas. The data were provided by the U.S. Census. Another proxy is the number of cities with ride-hailing services. I measured it with the number of cities in which ride-hailing firms have been operating in a state in a year. I obtained the list of cities in which Uber and Lyft operate from their official websites. I then searched the entry announcement for each city on both firms’ websites to identify their time of entry into these cities and calculated the number of cities in which ride-hailing firms were operating in that state in a year.

Fourth, it included political alliances of ride-hailing in state legislatures. Republicans are known to be more supportive of the ride-hailing industry.Footnote 104 I used a binary metric to represent states where the Republican Party control over the governorship and held majorities in both the state senate and state house in the year. The data were provided by the Annual Book of the States from the Council of State Governments. I also controlled the percentage of ALEC legislators in a state legislature in a year. I acquired the roster of state lawmakers engaged with ALEC initiatives from the Centre for Media and Democracy (CMD). By examining the official webpages of state legislatures and using the Ballotpedia database for state legislators, I determined the tenure of each ALEC-affiliated legislator. Through this process, I was able to ascertain the count of ALEC legislators in a state for a specific year and computed the proportion of ALEC legislators by comparing their number to the overall quantity of state legislators.

Additionally, I considered the economic and sociodemographic features of a state, including its annual population and per capita income. I drew this data from the U.S. Census and the Bureau of Economic Analysis. Finally, I took into account the influence of policy diffusion between states, as a state government may pass ride-hailing legislations that mimic peer states. To assess this, I counted the total number of states (diffusion), as well as those bordering the state in question (neighboring diffusion), that had passed ride-hailing-related legislation by a year. Figure 3 presents the accumulated number of passed state legislations on ride-hailing.

Figure 3. Cumulative enactments of ride-hailing-related laws by U.S. states.

Estimation method

Considering that both the semantic and cosine similarity scores are between 0 and 1, I used fractional regression models.Footnote 105 However, there is the problem of endogeneity in that unobserved variables may have simultaneously influenced ride-hailing firms’ lobbying efforts and the text of ride-hailing policies. To deal with the problem, I used a two-stage Heckman regression model.Footnote 106 This approach is based on the nonrandom assignment of observations to the control and experimental groups. When applied to panel data, such as in this study, the model effectively addresses concerns related to time-invariant, unit-specific omitted-variable bias. I used a Probit model for the first stage, where the coefficients are used to calculate the inverse Mills ratio, which is an estimated selection hazard for the probability that ride-hailing firms are selected to engage in lobbying. Although this method does not strictly require an instrumental variable, the inclusion of an instrumental variable that affects selection but not outcomes greatly increases the robustness of the estimates.Footnote 107 I used lobbying by Airbnb as the instrument to estimate the probability of ride-hailing firms engaging in lobbying, considering that the homesharing and ride-hailing industries have highly overlapped markets, mainly in urban and populous areas, and both encountered regulatory challenges in 2014; meanwhile, Airbnb’s lobbying has no impact on the regulatory outcome of the ride-hailing industry. In addition, the other co-variables in the first-stage models include urban population, the number of cities with ride-hailing, the Republican-controlled state legislature, the percentage of ALEC legislators, state population, and income. It shows that Airbnb lobbying is a significant predictor of ride-hailing lobbying in the first-stage model, indicating that the exclusion restrictions of the Heckman model were met.Footnote 108 Next, I inserted the inverse Mills ratio calculated from the first-stage model into the second-stage outcome model to estimate text similarity between passed ride-hailing policies and the model policy.

Another concern is that the text similarity score is dependent upon the enactment of a ride-hailing policy. I followed a similar procedure for Heckman selection to address this concern. First, a selection equation was used to estimate the likelihood of ride-hailing policy enactment by a state government. To establish the first stage, a variable pertaining to the power structure between local and state governments was used as an instrument: Dillon’s Rule or Home Rule. In the states with Home Rule, local governments can independently issue certain policies, whereas in the states with Dillon’s Rule, local governments need the state government’s approval to issue policies. This variable was selected because prior research and media reports have demonstrated competition between local and state governments in regulating the ride-hailing industry.Footnote 109 When local governments have less regulatory power, the state government is prompted to nullify the local-level regulations by issuing state-wide policies. However, the power structure between local and state governments has no impact on the text of the passed state policies. This variable used as an exclusion restriction was also significant in the selection model. Similarly, I calculated the inverse Mills’ ratio from this first-stage model for state policy enactment and inserted it into the second-stage outcome models.

Results

Main results

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics and bivariate correlations. Table 2 shows the Heckman selection fractional models predicting semantic text similarity between the passed ride-hailing policies and the model policy in a state in a year. Model 1 only includes the control variables. It indicates that taxi protests can discourage the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by state legislatures, while the lobbyists hired by insurance companies, the allies of ride-hailing companies, can encourage it. Model 2 adds the independent variable of ride-hailing lobbyists. In the baseline hypothesis, I proposed a direct positive impact of firm lobbying on policymakers’ adoption of information provided by firms in policymaking. In Model 2, the coefficient of the number of lobbyists hired by ride-hailing firms is significant (β = 0.015, p = 0.034), meaning that corporate lobbying efforts are positively associated with policymakers’ information intake. The baseline hypothesis is thus supported.

Table 1: Descriptive statistics

N = 250.

Table 2: Heckman selection (fractional) models for semantic text similarity between the passed ride-hailing state policies and the ride-hailing model policy

N = 250. Standard errors of state and year are clustered; s.e in parentheses; Significance level: +<0.10, *<0.05, **<0.01, ***<0.001.

Model 3 and Model 4 in Table 2 examine the interaction effect with legislative professionalism. The negative and significant coefficient for the interaction term (β = −0.125, p = 0.042) suggests that the positive relationship between corporate lobbying and the adoption of the model policy diminished with higher legislative professionalism. It thus lends support to Hypothesis 1. Further analysis shows that when legislative professionalism is high (mean + 2SD), two standard deviations increase in the number of ride-hailing lobbyists from the mean would increase the semantic text similarity between the passed ride-hailing policies and the model policy by 29 percent, in contrast to 152 percent for low legislative professionalism (mean). The interaction plot is presented in Figure 4(1).

Figure 4. Interaction plots.

Note: “low” in the graphs presents that the moderator is at the mean level; “high” in the graphs means that the moderator is at two standard deviations above the mean.

Model 5 and Model 6 test the moderating effect of information deliberation with other stakeholders in public hearings. The results indicate that the ride-hailing lobbying strategy can only greatly increase semantic text similarity between the passed ride-hailing policies and the model policy without the presence of public hearings at state legislatures (β = −0.005, p = 0.000). It thus provides evidence for Hypothesis 2a. Specifically, an increase in the number of ride-hailing lobbyists from the mean to two standard deviations above the mean results in a 294 percent increase in the semantic text similarity without the presence of public hearings, whereas it only leads to 9 percent increase with public hearings. Figure 4 (2) presents its interaction plot.

Model 7 and Model 8 examine the interaction impact of information deliberation in the media, using the proxy of the number of media articles discussing regulatory issues of ride-hailing in a state by a year. The results are consistent with Hypothesis 2b, showing that the positive relationship between corporate lobbying and the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by state legislatures is attenuated by media discussion on the issue (β = −0.056, p = 0.018). It means that an increase in the ride-hailing lobbyist number from the mean to two standard deviation deviations above the mean increases semantic text similarity by 38 percent for the high volume of media discussion of the ride-hailing issue(mean + 2SD), compared to 172 percent for the low media coverage volume (mean). Figure 4(3) displays the moderating impact.

Similarly, Model 9 and Model 10 summarize the moderating impact of the countervailing force, which was measured with the number of lobbyists hired by incumbent taxi companies. The result confirms Hypothesis 3 that the countervailing taxi lobbyists weakened the positive relationship between ride-hailing lobbyists and the adoption of the ride-hailing mode policy (β = −0.001, p = 0.020). However, as shown by Figure 4(4), its moderating impact is relatively weak compared to the other three moderators. When the number of taxi lobbyists is high (mean + 2SD), two standard deviations increase in the number of ride-hailing lobbyists from the mean would increase the semantic text similarity by 195 percent, compared to 227 percent for low taxi lobbyist number (mean).

Table 3 presents the Heckman fractional models for cosine text similarity between the passed ride-hailing policies and the model policy. The results are consistent with those obtained from semantic scores.

Table 3: Heckman selection (fractional) models for cosine text similarity between the passed ride-hailing state policies and the ride-hailing model policy

N = 250. Standard errors of state and year are clustered; s.e in parentheses; Significance level: +<0.10, *<0.05, **<0.01, ***<0.001.

Hence, although corporate lobbying efforts can facilitate policymakers adopting information they provide, its impact is highly contingent upon information asymmetry between policymakers and corporations. Specifically, such information asymmetry can be attributed to the extent to which policymakers are constrained by resources to gather their own information, the level of information deliberation, and the strength of countervailing forces.

Additional analyses and robustness checks

I also conducted additional analyses and checked the robustness of the findings. First, Models 1–8 tested whether the four variables regarding information asymmetry moderated the impact of corporate petitions and campaign contributions, which are another two major CPAs of ride-hailing firms. The insignificant coefficients for the interaction terms indicate that information asymmetry only moderates the impact of information-based strategies but not money-based strategies and vote-based strategies. Second, I employed an alternative instrument to mitigate the endogeneity concerns. Here I used the reverse of the strictness of lobbying rules as the alternative instrument, as companies are expected to refrain from lobbying efforts if the lobbying rules of a state are strict; meanwhile, strictness of lobbying rules has no direct influence on the text of ride-hailing laws. The data were obtained from OpenSecrets, a nonprofit research group that tracks the effects of money and lobbying on public policy in the United States. It scored each state by (1) whether lobbyist compensation is disclosed, (2) the quality of disclosure of lobbyist and client identities, (3) the timeliness of disclosure, and (4) how easily the public can access disclosed information. Models 9–12 suggest that all the results remained with the alternative instrument. Third, I delved deeper into the content of the model policy by examining whether corporate lobbying is associated with policymakers’ adoption of the ride-hailing insurance model—a key element of the ride-hailing model policy. The insurance model clarified the insurance amounts in different periods of the ride-hailing service: During Period 1 (driver logged in), primary insurance with limits of $50/$100/$25 is required, maintained by the TNC, driver, or both. For Periods 2 and 3 (en route and carrying passengers), a $1,000,000 liability coverage, akin to limo standards, is mandated, and upheld by the TNC, driver, or a combination thereof. I adopted a dummy variable to capture the adoption of the insurance model proposed by ride-hailing. Models 13–16 indicate that all the hypotheses on corporate lobbying are still supported (Table 4).

Table 4: Additional analyses and robustness checks

N = 250. Standard errors of state and year are clustered; s.e in parentheses; Significance level: +<0.10, *<0.05, **<0.01, ***<0.001.

Conclusion and discussion

This paper examined the effectiveness of lobbying in delivering information, represented as the extent to which and the conditions under which policymakers incorporate information delivered via firm lobbying into policy outcomes. This paper argues that the informational influence of lobbying is moderated by the information asymmetry between policymakers and firms. I find general support for this argument in an empirical study of the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by U.S. state legislatures. To capture whether state legislatures adopt the model policy, I conducted cosine and semantic text similarity analyses between all ride-hailing policies passed by U.S. state legislatures and the model policy lobbied by ride-hailing firms. The results show that the effectiveness of corporate lobbying in conveying information hinges on the degree of information asymmetry between firms and policymakers, which is the result of (1) policymakers’ resources to gather information, (2) information deliberation through public hearings or the media, and (3) the countervailing lobbying efforts. Normatively, the study illuminates the necessity for policymakers to possess sufficient resources for independent information acquisition and champions a balanced approach to lobbying. It suggests that a pluralistic system that incorporates diverse perspectives can foster more equitable and representative policy results.

This study contributes to the CPA literature in a few ways. First, the existing body of research on lobbying has concentrated on its material facets, with particular focus on corporate expenditure on lobbying activities and the material benefits that ensue, such as increases in equity returns, stock market valuations, tax advantages, and government contracts.Footnote 110 Despite this focus, a subset of literature has emerged advocating an informational perspective of lobbying, underscoring the strategic transmission of information as a pivotal element of the interactions between corporate lobbyists and politicians,Footnote 111 as well as the nature of the information exchanged.Footnote 112 However, this perspective has not sufficiently explored how effectively information from firm lobbying is integrated into resulting policy decisions. This study is the first attempt to examine the extent to which and under what conditions lobbying can effectively deliver information to politicians.

Relatedly, while the theoretical basis of this informational perspective on lobbying is well-established, its empirical progress has long been hindered by a scarcity of data.Footnote 113 This challenge stems not only from the fact that firm lobbying takes place through private meetings and in a covert manner but also from the inherent difficulty in quantifying and measuring information.Footnote 114 This study lifts the restrictions by leveraging unique data on the adoption of the ride-hailing model policy by U.S. state legislatures. On the one hand, the content of the ride-hailing model policy, which is also the information delivered by ride-hailing firms to policymakers, is disclosed. On the other hand, most U.S. state legislatures have enacted policies on ride-hailing. It follows that an analysis of the overlap between the enacted policy and the model policy enables us to quantify the information adopted by policymakers.

Third, it joins the emerging stream of CPA literature that focuses on the supply side of the political market and the heterogeneity of politicians’ receptivity to CPAs.Footnote 115 Prior research has either emphasized the influence of the hard characteristics of policy suppliers, including political competition and electoral competition,Footnote 116 or their soft characteristics, such as political ideology.Footnote 117 This study contributes to this emerging CPA research stream by highlighting the influence of information asymmetry between policy suppliers and demanders and showing a nuanced picture that it only moderates the effectiveness of lobbying but not the constituency-building and campaign contribution strategies.

There are limitations to its findings. Firstly, this study is based on the special data on model policies being lobbied by firms. Yet, information input from firms can take various forms, such as statistics, facts, arguments, forecasts, threats, and signals.Footnote 118 Further research can explore and compare the effectiveness of different types of information input in influencing policy outcomes. Second, this paper only includes registered lobbyists. However, as pointed out by Thomas and LaPira, there are also “shadow lobbyists”—these are paid professionals in a gray market for lobbying services. Footnote 119 Should data permit, future research could shed light on the influence and dynamics of these informal lobbying activities. Third, this paper focuses on a specific issue and industry, and future research can extend generalizability by testing the results across multiple issues and industries, such as innovative industries versus conventional industriesFootnote 120 and salient issues versus non-salient issues.Footnote 121 It is possible that policymakers’ information dependency on firms is greater for innovative industries and non-salient issues, which are less known and understood by outsiders, than for conventional industries and salient issues.

Competing interests

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Footnotes

1 Hillman and Hitt (Reference Hillman and Hitt1999); de Figueiredo and Richter (Reference De Figueiredo and Richter2014); de Figueiredo (Reference De Figueiredo2002).

2 e.g., Kim (Reference Kim2008); Borghesi and Chang (Reference Borghesi and Chang2015); Ridge, Ingram, and Hill (Reference Ridge, Ingram and Hill2017).

4 Potters and van Winden (Reference Potters and Van Winden1990); Austen-Smith and Wright (Reference Austen-Smith and Wright1996); Bennedsen and Feldmann, (Reference Bennedsen and Feldmann2002).

5 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

6 Hertel-Fernandez (Reference Hertel-Fernandez2014).

8 CMD (2017).

9 Albareda, Brraun and Fraussen (Reference Albareda, Braun and Fraussen2023); Austen-Smith (Reference Austen-Smith1993).

10 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

11 Choi, Jia, and Lu (Reference Choi, Jia and Lu2015); Wang, Du, and Marquis (Reference Wang, Du and Marquis2019).

12 Hillman, Keim, and Schuler (Reference Hillman, Keim and Schuler2004).

13 Hillman and Hitt (Reference Hillman and Hitt1999); Bonardi, Holburn, and Vanden Bergh (Reference Bonardi, Holburn and Vanden Bergh2006).

14 de Figueiredo and Richter (Reference De Figueiredo and Richter2014).

17 Wen and Yue (Reference Wen and Yue2021).

18 Grossman and Helpman (1994); Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

19 Brasher and Lowery (Reference Brasher and Lowery2006); Drope and Hansen (Reference Drope and Hansen2006); Kim (Reference Kim2008).

21 Unsal, Hassan, and Zirek (Reference Unsal, Hassan and Zirek2016); Lambert (Reference Lambert2019).

23 Richter, Samphantharak and Timmons (Reference Richter, Samphantharak and Timmons2009).

25 Chen, Parsley and Yang (Reference Chen, Parsley and Yang2015).

27 Kang (Reference Kang2016).

28 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

29 Grossman and Helpman (Reference Grossman and Helpman2011).

30 Potters and van Winden (Reference Potters and Van Winden1990); Austen-Smith and Wright (Reference Austen-Smith and Wright1996); Bennedsen and Feldmann, (Reference Bennedsen and Feldmann2002); U.S. Constitution. amend. I.

31 de Figueiredo (Reference De Figueiredo2002).

33 Schnakenberg (Reference Schnakenberg2017)

34 National Institute for Lobbying and Ethics, (n.d.).

35 Drutman and Hopkins (Reference Drutman and Hopkins2013).

36 Austen-Smith (Reference Austen-Smith1993).

38 De. Bruycker (Reference De Bruycker2016).

39 Albared, Braun, and Fraussen (Reference Albareda, Braun and Fraussen2023).

40 Bonardi, Hillman and Keim (Reference Bonardi, Holburn and Vanden Bergh2006), Hillman and Hitt (Reference Hillman and Hitt1999).

41 Nothhaft (Reference Nothhaft2017).

42 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

43 Burt (Reference Burt2000).

44 Cutlip (Reference Cutlip1962).

46 McDonnell and Werner (Reference McDonnell and Werner2016); Wang, Du and Marquis (Reference Wang, Du and Marquis2019); Hadani, Bonardi and Dahan, (Reference Hadani, Bonardi and Dahan2017).

49 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

50 Van Winde (Reference Van Winden1999).

51 Bernhagen and Bräuninger (Reference Bernhagen and Bräuninger2005).

52 Polk (Reference Polk2002).

53 Mello, Abiola, and Colgrove (Reference Mello, Abiola and Colgrove2012).

54 Gao and McDonald (Reference Gao and McDonald2022).

55 Ellis and Groll (Reference Ellis and Groll2020).

56 Schlozman and Tierney (Reference Schlozman and Tierney1983).

58 Woods and Baranowski (Reference Woods and Baranowski2006).

59 Grumm (Reference Grumm1971).

60 Hertel-Fernandez (Reference Hertel-Fernandez2014).

61 Jansa, Hansen and Gray (Reference Jansa, Hansen and Gray2019).

62 Bowen and Greene (Reference Bowen and Greene2014).

63 Bouwen (Reference Bouwen2002), James and Christopoulos (Reference James and Christopoulos2018).

64 Lessig (Reference Lessig2011).

65 Hall and Deardorff (Reference Hall and Deardorff2006).

66 Drutnam (Reference Drutnam2015).

67 Ellis and Groll (Reference Ellis and Groll2020).

68 Lindeman (Reference Lindeman2002).

70 Jacquet and van der Does (Reference Jacquet and van der Does2021).

71 Barabas (Reference Barabas2004).

72 Carpini, Cook and Jacobs (Reference Carpini, Cook and Jacobs2004).

73 Neshkova and Guo (Reference Neshkova and Guo2012).

75 Gephart (Reference Gephart2007).

77 Gephart and Pitter (Reference Gephart and Pitter1993).

78 Strömbäck and Shehata (Reference Strömbäck and Shehata2010).

79 Page (Reference Page1996): 5.

81 Scheufele and Tewksbury (Reference Scheufele and Tewksbury2007).

82 Here, “public hearings” pertain to those where policymakers are directly involved, such as in committee and legislative hearings.

83 Galbraith (Reference Galbraith1954).

84 Austen-Smith and Wright (Reference Austen-Smith and Wright1994).

85 Levine (Reference Levine2009).

86 Baron (Reference Baron2018).

87 Paik, Kang, and Seamans (Reference Paik, Kang and Seamans2019).

88 Cetin and Deakin (Reference Cetin and Deakin2019).

89 Posen (Reference Posen2015).

90 Crespo (Reference Crespo2016).

91 Wen and Yue (Reference Wen and Yue2021).

93 CMD (2017).

95 O’Donnel (Reference O’Donnel2015).

96 Oregon is the only state that had not enacted any legislations on ride-hailing.

97 Arts, Cassiman, and Gomez (Reference Arts, Cassiman and Carlos Gomez2018).

98 Roberts (Reference Roberts2020).

99 Clemens (Reference Clemens2014).

100 NCSL (2018).

101 Squire (Reference Squire2017); Dorrell and Jansa (Reference Dorrell and Jansa2022).

102 Snyder and Stromberg (Reference Snyder and Strömberg2010).

103 O’Donnell (Reference O’Donnel2015).

104 Buss (Reference Buss2014).

105 Ramalho, Ramalho, and Murteira (Reference Ramalho, Ramalho and Murteira2011).

106 Heckman (Reference Heckman1979).

107 Sartori (Reference Sartori2003).

108 Bascle (Reference Bascle2008).

109 Wen and Yue (Reference Wen and Yue2021); Collier, Dubal and Carter (Reference Collier, Dubal and Carter2018).

112 e.g. De Bruycker (Reference De Bruycker2016).

113 Bombardini and Trebbi (Reference Bombardini and Trebbi2020).

114 Kluver (Reference Klüver2012); Nothhaft (Reference Nothhaft2017).

115 McDonnell and Werner (Reference McDonnell and Werner2016); Uzuca, Rightering, and Ozcan (Reference Uzunca, Rigtering and Ozcan2018).

116 Choi et al. (Reference Choi, Jia and Lu2015).

118 de Figueiredo (Reference De Figueiredo2002).

119 Thomas and LaPira (Reference Thomas and LaPira2017).

120 Bolter and Holmquist (1996).

121 Bornardi and Keim (Reference Bonardi and Keim2005).

References

Albareda, Adrià, Saz-Carranza, Angel, Van Acoleyen, Michiel, and Coen, David 2023. “Lobbying the Executive Branch: Unpacking Access to Political Heads, Political Advisers, and Civil Servants.” Business and Politics 25 (1): 116.10.1017/bap.2022.22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albareda, Adrià, Braun, Caelesta, and Fraussen, Bert. 2023. “Explaining Why Public Officials Perceive Interest Groups as Influential: On the Role of Policy Capacities and Policy Insiderness.” Policy Sciences 56: 119.10.1007/s11077-023-09491-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arts, Sam, Cassiman, Bruno, and Carlos Gomez, Juan. 2018. “Text Matching to Measure Patent Similarity.” Strategic Management Journal 39 (1): 6284.10.1002/smj.2699CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, David. 1993. “Information and Influence: Lobbying for Agendas and Votes.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (3): 799833.10.2307/2111575CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, David, and Wright, John R.. 1994. “Counteractive Lobbying.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (1): 2544.10.2307/2111334CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, David, and Wright, John R.. 1996. “Theory and Evidence for Counteractive Lobbying.” American Journal of Political Science 40 (2): 543564.10.2307/2111637CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barabas, Jason. 2004. “How Deliberation Affects Policy Opinions.” American Political Science Review 98 (4): 687701.10.1017/S0003055404041425CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P. 2018. “Disruptive Entrepreneurship and Dual Purpose Strategies: The Case of Uber.” Strategy Science 3 (2): 439462.10.1287/stsc.2018.0059CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bascle, Guilhem. 2008. “Controlling for Endogeneity with Instrumental Variables in Strategic Management Research.” Strategic organization 6 (3): 285327.10.1177/1476127008094339CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Berry, Jeffrey M., Hojnacki, Marie, Leech, Beth L., and Kimball, David C.. 2009. Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226039466.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, Seyla. 1992. Situating the Self: Gender, Community and Postmodernism in Contemporary Ethics. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bennedsen, Morten, and Feldmann, Sven E.. 2002. “Lobbying Legislatures.” Journal of Political Economy 110 (4): 919946.10.1086/340775CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhagen, Patrick, and Bräuninger, Thomas. 2005. “Structural Power and Public Policy: A Signaling Model of Business Lobbying in Democratic Capitalism.” Political Studies 53 (1): 4364.10.1111/j.1467-9248.2005.00516.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beyers, Jan. 2002. “Gaining and Seeking Access: The European Adaptation of Domestic Interest Associations.” European Journal of Political Research 41 (5): 585612.10.1111/1475-6765.00023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bombardini, Matilde, and Trebbi, Francesco. 2020Empirical Models of Lobbying.” Annual Review of Economics 12: 391413.10.1146/annurev-economics-082019-024350CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonardi, Jean-Philippe, Holburn, Guy L. F., and Vanden Bergh, Richard G.. 2006. “Nonmarket Strategy Performance: Evidence from US Electric Utilities.” Academy of Management Journal 49 (6): 12091228.10.5465/amj.2006.23478676CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonardi, Jean-Philippe, and Keim, Gerald D.. 2005. “Corporate Political Strategies for Widely Salient Issues.” Academy of Management Review 30 (3): 555576.10.5465/amr.2005.17293705CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borghesi, Richard, and Chang, Kiyoung. 2015. “The Determinants of Effective Corporate Lobbying.” Journal of Economics and Finance 39: 606624.10.1007/s12197-014-9287-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borkholder, Joy, Montgomery, Mariah, Chen, Miya Saika, and Smith, Rebecca. 2018. “Uber State Interference: How Transportation Network Companies Buy, Bully, and Bamboozle Their Way to Deregulation.” National Employment Law Project and the Partnership for Working Families.Google Scholar
Bouwen, Pieter. 2002. “Corporate Lobbying in the European Union: The Logic of Access.” Journal of European Public Policy 9 (3): 365390.10.1080/13501760210138796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouwen, Pieter. 2004. “Exchanging Access Goods for Access: A Comparative Study of Business Lobbying in the European Union Institutions.” European Journal of Political Research 43 (3): 337369.10.1111/j.1475-6765.2004.00157.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowen, Daniel C., and Greene, Zachary. 2014. “Should We Measure Professionalism with an Index? A Note on Theory and Practice in State Legislative Professionalism Research.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 14 (3): 277296.10.1177/1532440014536407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brasher, Holly, and Lowery, David. 2006. “The Corporate Context of Lobbying Activity.” Business and Politics 8 (1): 123.10.2202/1469-3569.1124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burt, R. S. 2000. “The Network Structure of Social Capital.” Research in Organizational Behavior 22: 345423.10.1016/S0191-3085(00)22009-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buss, Dale. 2014. “Uber Republicans: Can GOP Tap into Millennials’ Frustrations?” Forbes. Accessed December 04, 2022. https://www.forbes.com/sites/dalebuss/2014/08/08/uber-republicans-thats-only-beginning-of-millennial-frustrations/?ss=game-changers#486f9e5c4b64.Google Scholar
Carpini, Michael X. Cook, Delli, Fay Lomax, and Jacobs, Lawrence R.. 2004. “Public Deliberation, Discursive Participation, and Citizen Engagement: A Review of the Empirical Literature.” Annual Review of Political Science 7: 315344.10.1146/annurev.polisci.7.121003.091630CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cetin, Tamer, and Deakin, Elizabeth. 2019. “Regulation of Taxis and the Rise of Ride-Hailing.” Transport Policy 76: 149158.10.1016/j.tranpol.2017.09.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, Hui, Parsley, David, and Yang, Ya-Wen. 2015. “Corporate Lobbying and Firm Performance.” Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 42 (3–4): 444481.10.1111/jbfa.12109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Seong-Jin, Jia, Nan, and Lu, Jiangyong. 2015. “The Structure of Political Institutions and Effectiveness of Corporate Political Lobbying.” Organization Science 26 (1): 158179.10.1287/orsc.2014.0936CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clemens, Austin C. 2014. “All Politics Is Local, But Lobbying Is Federal and Local: The Validity of LDA Data”. Business and Politics 16 (2): 267289.10.1515/bap-2013-0017CrossRefGoogle Scholar
CMD. 2017. Transportation Network Company Act Exposed. Accessed Dec 04, 2022. https://www.alecexposed.org/wiki/Transportation_Network_Company_Act_Exposed.Google Scholar
Collier, Ruth Berins, Dubal, Veena B., and Carter, Christopher L.. 2018. “Disrupting Regulation, Regulating Disruption: The Politics of Uber in the United States.” Perspectives on Politics 16 (4): 919937.10.1017/S1537592718001093CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crespo, Yanelys. 2016. “Uber v. Regulation:” Ride-Sharing” Creates a Legal Gray Area.” University of Miami Business Law Review 25: 79.Google Scholar
Cutlip, Scott M. 1962. Effective Public Relations. London: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
De Bruycker, Iskander. 2016. “Pressure and Expertise: Explaining the Information Supply of Interest Groups in EU Legislative Lobbying.” JCMS: Journal of Common Market Studies 54 (3): 599616.Google Scholar
De Figueiredo, John M. 2002. “Lobbying and Information in Politics.” Business and Politics 4 (2): 125129.10.2202/1469-3569.1033CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Figueiredo, John M., and Richter, Brian Kelleher. 2014. “Advancing the Empirical Research on Lobbying.” Annual Review of Political Science 17: 163185.10.1146/annurev-polisci-100711-135308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, La Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2010. “Disclosure by Politicians.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 2 (2): 179209.10.1257/app.2.2.179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorrell, Robert M. Jr, and Jansa, Joshua M.. 2022. “Copy, Paste, Legislate, Succeed? The Effect of Policy Plagiarism on Policy Success.” Policy & Politics 50 (4): 605623.10.1332/030557321X16445954252430CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drope, Jeffrey M., and Hansen, Wendy L.. 2006. “Does Firm Size Matter? Analyzing Business Lobbying in the United States.” Business and Politics 8 (2): 117.10.2202/1469-3569.1160CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drutnam, Lee. 2015. The Business of America Is Lobbying: How Corporations Became Politicized and Politics Became More Corporate. New York: Oxford University Press Google Scholar
Drutman, Lee, and Hopkins, Daniel J.. 2013. “The Inside View: Using the Enron E-mail Archive to Understand Corporate Political Attention.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 38 (1): 530.10.1111/lsq.12001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellis, Christopher J., and Groll, Thomas. 2020. “Strategic Legislative Subsidies: Informational Lobbying and the Cost of Policy.” American Political Science Review 114 (1): 179205.10.1017/S0003055419000595CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishkin, James, Kousser, Thad, Luskin, Robert C., and Siu, Alice. 2015. “Deliberative Agenda Setting: Piloting Reform of Direct Democracy in California.” Perspectives on Politics 13 (4): 10301042.10.1017/S1537592715002297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth. 1954. “Countervailing Power.” The American Economic Review 44 (2): 16.Google Scholar
Gao, Cheng, and McDonald, Rory. 2022. “Shaping Nascent Industries: Innovation Strategy and Regulatory Uncertainty in Personal Genomics.” Administrative Science Quarterly 67 (4): 915967.10.1177/00018392221112641CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gephart, Robert P. Jr 2007. “Crisis Sensemaking.” International Handbook of Organizational Crisis Management 123: 123–160.10.4135/9781412982757.n5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gephart, Robert P. Jr, and Pitter, Robert. 1993. “The Organizational Basis of Industrial Accidents in Canada.” Journal of Management Inquiry 2 (3): 238252.10.1177/105649269323004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grasse, Nathan, and Heidbreder, Brianne.2011. “The Influence of Lobbying Activity in State Legislatures: Evidence from Wisconsin.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36 (4): 567589.10.1111/j.1939-9162.2011.00027.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2011. Special Interest Politics. London: MIT press.Google Scholar
Grumm, John G. 1971. “The Effects of Legislative Structure on Legislative Performance.” In State and Urban Politics, eds. Richard I. Hofferbert and Ira Sharkansky, 298322.Google Scholar
Habermas, Jurgen. 1989. The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere, trans. Burger, Thomas. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hadani, Michael, Bonardi, Jean-Philippe, and Dahan, Nicolas M.. 2017. “Corporate Political Activity, Public Policy Uncertainty, and Firm Outcomes: A Meta-Analysis”. Strategic Organization 15 (3): 338366.10.1177/1476127016651001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Richard L., and Deardorff, Alan V.. 2006. “Lobbying as Legislative Subsidy.” American Political Science Review 100 (1): 6984.10.1017/S0003055406062010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 47 (1):153161.10.2307/1912352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertel-Fernandez, Alexander. 2014. “Who Passes Business’s “Model Bills”? Policy Capacity and Corporate Influence in US State Politics.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (3): 582602.10.1017/S1537592714001601CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, Matthew D., Kelly, G. Wayne, Lockhart, G. Brandon, and Van Ness, Robert A.. 2013. “Determinants and Effects of Corporate Lobbying.” Financial Management 42 (4): 931957.10.1111/fima.12032CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, Amy J., and Hitt, Michael A.. 1999. “Corporate Political Strategy Formulation: A Model of Approach, Participation, and Strategy Decisions.” Academy of Management Review 24 (4): 825842.10.2307/259357CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hillman, Amy J., Keim, Gerald D., and Schuler, Douglas. 2004. “Corporate Political Activity: A Review and Research Agenda.” Journal of Management 30 (6): 837857.10.1016/j.jm.2004.06.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacquet, Vincent, and van der Does, Ramon. 2021. “The Consequences of Deliberative Minipublics: Systematic Overview, Conceptual Gaps, and New Directions.” Representation 57 (1): 131141.10.1080/00344893.2020.1778513CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, Scott, and Christopoulos, Dimitris. 2018. “Reputational Leadership and Preference Similarity: Explaining Organisational Collaboration in Bank Policy Networks.” European Journal of Political Research 57 (2): 518538.10.1111/1475-6765.12237CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jansa, Joshua M., Hansen, Eric R., and Gray, Virginia H.. 2019. “Copy and Paste Lawmaking: Legislative Professionalism and Policy Reinvention in the States.” American Politics Research 47 (4): 739767.10.1177/1532673X18776628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kang, Karam. “Policy Influence and Private Returns from Lobbying in the Energy Sector.” The Review of Economic Studies 83 (1): 269305.10.1093/restud/rdv029CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katic, Ivana V., and Hillman, Amy. 2023. “Corporate Political Activity, Reimagined: Revisiting the Political Marketplace”. Journal of Management 49 (6): 19111938.10.1177/01492063221137069CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Jin-Hyuk. 2008. “Corporate Lobbying Revisited.” Business and Politics 10 (2): 123.10.2202/1469-3569.1193CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Jin Hyung. 2019. “Is Your Playing Field Unleveled? US Defense Contracts and Foreign Firm Lobbying.” Strategic Management Journal 40 (12): 19111937.10.1002/smj.3061CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klüver, Heike. 2012. “Informational Lobbying in the European Union: The Effect of Organisational Characteristics.” West European Politics 35 (3): 491510.10.1080/01402382.2012.665737CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambert, Thomas. 2019. “Lobbying on Regulatory Enforcement Actions: Evidence from US Commercial and Savings Banks.” Management Science 65 (6): 25452572.10.1287/mnsc.2017.2895CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lenway, Stefanie, Schuler, Douglas, Marens, Richard, Werner, Timothy, and Green, Colby. 2022. “The Evolving Political Marketplace: Revisiting 60 Years of Theoretical Dominance Through a Review of Corporate Political Activity Scholarship in Business & Society and Major Management Journals.” Business & Society 61 (5): 14161470.10.1177/00076503221084660CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence. 2011. Republic, Lost: How Money Corrupts Congress and a Plan to Stop It. New York: Hachette Book Group.Google Scholar
Levine, Bertram J. 2009. The Art of Lobbying. Washington, DC: SAGE.Google Scholar
Lindeman, Mark. 2002. “Opinion Quality and Policy Preferences in Deliberative Research.” Research in Micropolitics: Political Decisionmaking, Deliberation and Participation 6: 199.Google Scholar
McDonnell, Mary-Hunter, and Werner, Timothy. 2016. “Blacklisted Businesses: Social Activists’ Challenges and the Disruption of Corporate Political Activity.” Administrative Science Quarterly 61 (4): 584620.10.1177/0001839216648953CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mello, Michelle M., Abiola, Sara, and Colgrove, James. 2012. “Pharmaceutical Companies’ Role in State Vaccination Policymaking: The Case of Human Papillomavirus Vaccination.” American Journal of Public Health 102 (5): 893898.10.2105/AJPH.2011.300576CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Milyo, Jeffrey, Primo, David, and Groseclsoe, Timothy 2000. “Corporate PAC Campaign Contributions in Perspective.” Business and Politics 2 (1): 5.10.2202/1469-3569.1004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
NCSL. 2018. “50 State Chart: Lobbyist Activity Report Requirements.” Accessed at January 13 2023. https://www.ncsl.org/research/ethics/50-state-chart-lobbyist-report-requirements.aspx.Google Scholar
Neshkova, Milena I., and Guo, Hai. 2012. “Public Participation and Organizational Performance: Evidence from State Agencies.” Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 22 (2): 267288.10.1093/jopart/mur038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nothhaft, Camilla. 2017 Moments of Lobbying: An Ethnographic Study of Meetings Between Lobbyists and Politicians. Doctoral dissertation, Örebro University.Google Scholar
O’Donnel, Anthony.R. 2015. “Insurer-TNC Compromise Paves Way for Rideshare Insurance Regulation.” Accessed January 10, 2023. https://iireporter.com/insurer-tnc-compromise-paves-way-for-rideshare-insurance-regulation/.Google Scholar
Page, Benjamine. I. 1996. “The Mass Media as Political Actors.” PS: Political Science & Politics 29 (1): 2024.Google Scholar
Paik, Yongwook, Kang, Sukhun, and Seamans, Robert. 2019. “Entrepreneurship, Innovation, and Political Competition: How the Public Sector Helps the Sharing Economy Create Value.” Strategic Management Journal 40 (4): 503532.10.1002/smj.2937CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polk, Andreas. 2002. “How Special Interests Shape Policy-A Survey.” University of Zurich, Socioeconomic Institute Working Paper 0206.Google Scholar
Posen, Hannah A. 2015. “Ride-Hailing in the Sharing Economy: Should Regulators Impose Uber Regulations on Uber.” Iowa Law Review 101: 405.Google Scholar
Potters, Jan, and Van Winden, Frans.1990. “Modelling Political Pressure as Transmission of Information.” European Journal of Political Economy 6 (1): 6188.10.1016/0176-2680(90)90036-ICrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Lynda W. 2012. The Influence of Campaign Contributions in State Legislatures: The Effects of Institutions and Politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.10.3998/mpub.2454352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramalho, Esmeralda A., Ramalho, Joaquim J. S., and Murteira, José M. R.. 2011. “Alternative Estimating and Testing Empirical Strategies for Fractional Regression Models.” Journal of Economic Surveys 25 (1): 1968.10.1111/j.1467-6419.2009.00602.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Richter, Brian Kelleher, Samphantharak, Krislert, and Timmons, Jeffrey F.. 2009. “Lobbying and Taxes.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (4): 893909.10.1111/j.1540-5907.2009.00407.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ridge, Jason W., Ingram, Amy, Abdurakhmonov, Mirzokhidjon, and Hasija, Dinesh. 2019. “Market Reactions to Non-Market Strategy: Congressional Testimony as an Indicator of Firm Political Influence.” Strategic Management Journal 40 (10): 16441667.10.1002/smj.3038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ridge, Jason W., Ingram, Amy, and Hill, Aaron D.. 2017. “Beyond Lobbying Expenditures: How Lobbying Breadth and Political Connectedness Affect Firm Outcomes.” Academy of Management Journal 60 (3): 11381163.10.5465/amj.2015.0584CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Carl W., ed. 2020. Text Analysis for the Social Sciences: Methods for Drawing Statistical Inferences from Texts and Transcripts. New Jersey: Routledge.10.4324/9781003064060CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Anne E. 2003. “An Estimator for Some Binary-Outcome Selection Models Without Exclusion Restrictions.” Political Analysis 11 (2): 111138.10.1093/pan/mpg001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheufele, Dietram A., and Tewksbury, David. 2007. “Framing, Agenda Setting, and Priming: The Evolution of Three Media Effects Models.” Journal of Communication 57 (1): 920.Google Scholar
Schlozman, Kay Lehman, and Tierney, John T.. 1983. “More of the Same: Washington Pressure Group Activity in a Decade of Change.” The Journal of Politics 45 (2): 351377.10.2307/2130130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schnakenberg, Keith E. 2017. “Informational Lobbying and Legislative Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 61 (1): 129145.10.1111/ajps.12249CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schuler, Douglas A. 1996. “Corporate Political Strategy and Foreign Competition: The Case of the Steel Industry.” Academy of Management Journal 39 (3): 720737.10.2307/256661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, James M. Jr, and Strömberg, David. 2010. “Press Coverage and Political Accountability.” Journal of Political Economy 118 (2): 355408.10.1086/652903CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Squire, Peverill. 2017. “A Squire Index Update.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 17 (4): 361371.10.1177/1532440017713314CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strömbäck, Jesper, and Shehata, Adam. 2010. “Media Malaise or a Virtuous Circle? Exploring the Causal Relationships Between News Media Exposure, Political News Attention and Political Interest.” European Journal of Political Research 49 (5): 575597.10.1111/j.1475-6765.2009.01913.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, Herschel F., and LaPira, Timothy M.. 2017. “How Many Lobbyists Are in Washington? Shadow Lobbying and the Gray Market for Policy Advocacy.” Interest Groups & Advocacy 6: 199214.10.1057/s41309-017-0024-yCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Topal, Cagri. 2009. “The Construction of General Public Interest: Risk, Legitimacy, and Power in a Public Hearing.” Organization Studies 30 (2–3): 277300.10.1177/0170840608101481CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Unsal, Omer, Hassan, M. Kabir, and Zirek, Duygu. 2016. “Corporate Lobbying, CEO Political Ideology and Firm Performance.” Journal of Corporate Finance 38: 126149.10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2016.04.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uzunca, Bilgehan, Rigtering, JP Coen, and Ozcan, Pinar. 2018. “Sharing and Shaping: A Cross-Country Comparison of How Sharing Economy Firms Shape Their Institutional Environment to Gain Legitimacy.” Academy of Management Discoveries 4 (3): 248272.10.5465/amd.2016.0153CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Winden, Frans. 1999. Experimental Studies of Signaling Games. Boston: Springer.10.1007/978-1-4615-5083-9_7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, Danqing, Du, Fei, and Marquis, Christopher. 2019. “Defending Mao’s Dream: How Politicians’ Ideological Imprinting Affects Firms’ Political Appointment in China.” Academy of Management Journal 62 (4): 11111136.10.5465/amj.2016.1198CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wen, Yuni, and Yue, Qingyue L.. 2021. “By the People and for the People: Ride-Hailing Companies’ Political Strategies in the US.” Academy of Management Proceedings 1: 11206.10.5465/AMBPP.2021.11206abstractCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woods, Neal D., and Baranowski, Michael. 2006. “Legislative Professionalism and Influence on State Agencies: The Effects of Resources and Careerism.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 31 (4): 585609.10.3162/036298006X201940CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. An excerpt of the ride-hailing model policy.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Semantic text similarity score variation by state and by year.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Cumulative enactments of ride-hailing-related laws by U.S. states.

Figure 3

Table 1: Descriptive statistics

Figure 4

Table 2: Heckman selection (fractional) models for semantic text similarity between the passed ride-hailing state policies and the ride-hailing model policy

Figure 5

Figure 4. Interaction plots.Note: “low” in the graphs presents that the moderator is at the mean level; “high” in the graphs means that the moderator is at two standard deviations above the mean.

Figure 6

Table 3: Heckman selection (fractional) models for cosine text similarity between the passed ride-hailing state policies and the ride-hailing model policy

Figure 7

Table 4: Additional analyses and robustness checks