Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-hc48f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T18:37:05.942Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social Contracting as a Trust-Building Process of Network Governance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 January 2015

Abstract:

Social contracting has a long and important place in the history of political philosophy (Hardin, 1991; Waldron, 1989) and as a theory of justice (Baynes, 1989; Rawls, 1971). More recently, it has been developed into an individual rights-based theory of organizations (Keeley, 1980, 1988), and as a way to integrate ethics and moral legitimacy into corporate strategy and action (Donaldson, 1982; Freeman & Gilbert, 1988). Currently, it is being proposed as an integrative theory of economic ethics (Donaldson & Dunfee, forthcoming). This paper will extend the Donaldson and Dunfee approach by arguing that social contracting can best be understood and applied in organizational settings if it is perceived and treated as a network governance process. This insight can benefit management scholars and practitioners alike, since it calls attention to the processes by which trust is created and sustained in on-going contractual relationships. It also strongly suggests that a new approach to applying managerial discretion, as moral agency, is needed to realize the full competitive and ethical potential of emerging network forms.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Business Ethics 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, P. 1993. “Time-and-Motion Regained.” Harvard Business Review, 71(1): 97108.Google Scholar
Alter, C., & Hage, J. 1993. Organizations Working Together. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications, Inc.Google Scholar
Allison, G. 1971. Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis. Boston: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 1984. The Cooperative Game Theory of the Firm. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 1990a. “The Participatory Generation of Information Rents and the Theory of the Firm.” In Aoki, M., Gustafsson, B. & Williamson, O. (Eds.), The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties: 2652. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 1990b. “Toward an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm.” Journal of Economic Literature, 28(1): 127.Google Scholar
Aram, J. 1989. “The Paradox of Interdependent Relations in the Field of Social Issues in Management.” Academy of Management Journal, 14(2): 266283.Google Scholar
Argyris, C., & Schon, . 1978. Organizational Learning: A Theory of Action Perspective. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1973. “Social Responsibility and Economic Efficiency.” Public Policy, 21: 303317.Google Scholar
Austrom, D., & Lad, L. 1989. “Issues Management Alliances: New Responses, New Values, and New Logics.” In Post, J. (Ed.), Research in Corporate Social Performance and Policy: 233255. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Bartlett, C., & Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing Across Borders: The Transnational Solution. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Baynes, K. 1989. “Kant on Property Rights and the Social Contract.” The Monist, 72(3) 433453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belenky, M., Clinchy, B., Goldberger, N., & Tarule, J. 1986. Women’s Ways of Knowing: The Development of Self, Voice, and Mind. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bradach, J., & Eccles, R. 1989. “Price, Authority, and Trust: From Ideal Types to Plural Forms.” Annual Review of Sociology, 97118.Google Scholar
Brenner, S., & Cochran, P. 1991. “The Stakeholder Theory of the Firm: Implications for Business and Society Research.” In Mahon, J. (Ed.), Proceedings of the Second Annual Meeting of the International Association for Business and Society: 449467.Google Scholar
Burns, T., & Stalker, G. 1961. The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock.Google Scholar
Calton, J. 1993. “What is at Stake in the Stakeholder Model?” In Ludwig, D., (Ed.), Business & Society in a Changing World Order. Lewiston, NY: Edwin Mellen Press, pp. 101127.Google Scholar
Calton, J., & Lad, L. 1993. “Collaborative Governance: The Firm, the Interorganizational Field, and ‘Negotiated Order.’” In Pasquero, J. and Collins, D. (Eds.), Proceedings of the Fourth Annual Meeting of the International Association for Business and Society: 8489.Google Scholar
Clegg, S. 1990. Modern Organizations: Organizational Studies in the Postmodern World. London: Sage Publications, Inc.Google Scholar
Coase, R. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica, 4: 386405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, A., and Townsley, M. 1990. “Perspectives on Collaboration as Replacement for Confrontation,” Public Utilities Fortnightly, March 1, pp. 913.Google Scholar
Contractor, F., & Lorange, P. 1988. Cooperative Strategies in International Business. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath & Co.Google Scholar
Davidow, W., & Malone, M. 1992. The Virtual Corporation: Structuring and Revitalizing the Corporation for the 21st Century. New York: Harper Collins Publishers.Google Scholar
Desjardin, J. 1990. “Virtue and Business Ethics.” In Desjardins, J. & McCall, J. (Eds.), Contemporary Issues in Business Ethics: 5459. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing Co.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. 1992. “Nadel’s Paradox Revisited: Relational and Cultural Aspects of Organizational Structure.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 118142. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Donaldson, T. 1982. Corporations and Morality. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Donaldson, T., & Dunfee, T. Forthcoming. “Integrative Social Contracts Theory: A Communitarian Conception of Economic Ethics.” Economics and Philosophy.Google Scholar
Ellis, W. B. 1989. “The Collaborative Process in Utility Resource Planning,” Public Utilities Fortnightly, June 22, pp. 911.Google Scholar
Evan, W., & Freeman, E. 1993. “A Stakeholder Theory of the Modern Corporation: Kantian Capitalism.” In Beauchamp, T. & Bowie, N. (Eds.), Ethical Theory and Business (4th ed.): 7593. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Fiske, S., & Taylor, S. 1991. Social Cognition (2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Freeman, E. 1984. Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach. Boston: PitmanGoogle Scholar
Freeman, E., & Evan, W. 1990. “Corporate Governance: A Stakeholder Interpretation.” Journal of Behavioral Economics, 19(4): 337359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, E., & Gilbert, D. Jr. 1988. Corporate Strategy and the Search for Ethics. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Gerlach, M., & Lincoln, J. 1992. “The Organization of Business Networks in the United States and Japan.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 491520. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Gilligan, C. 1982. In a Different Voice. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gilligan, C. 1988. “Remapping the Moral Domain: New Images of Self in Relationship.” In Gilligan, C., Ward, J., & Taylor, J., with Bardige, B. (Eds.), Mapping the Moral Domain: A Contribution of Women’s Thinking to Psychological Theory and Education: 319. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Goodpaster, K. 1991. “Business Ethics and Stakeholder Analysis.” Business Ethics Quarterly, 1: 5373Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1992. “Problems of Explanation in Economic Sociology.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 2556. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Gray, B., & Wood, D. 1991. “Collaborative Alliances: Moving from Practice to Theory.” Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 27(1): 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handy, C. 1990. The Age of Unreason. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, G. 1968. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science. 162: 12431248.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hardin, R. 1991. “Hobbesian Political Order — Reading Hobbes in Other Words: Contractarian, Utilitarian, Game Theorist.” Political Theory, 19(2): 156180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heimer, C. 1992. “Doing Your Job and Helping Your Friends: Universalistic Norms about Obligations to Particular Others in Networks.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 143164. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Hill, C., & Jones, T. 1992. “Stakeholder-Agency Theory.” Journal of Management Studies, 29(2):131154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, A. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hood, J., Logsdon, J., and Thompson, J. 1993. “Collaboration for Social Problem-Solving: A Process Model.” Business & Society, 32(1): 117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaikumar, R. 1986. “Post-Industrial Manufacturing.” Harvard Business Review, 64(6), Nov.-Dec.: 6976.Google Scholar
Jantsch, E. 1980. The Self-Organizing Universe. Oxford: Pergamon Press.Google Scholar
Jennings, B. 1991. “Possibilities of Consensus: Toward Democratic Moral Discourse.” Journal of Medicine and Philosophy, 16(4): 447463.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. 1976. “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure.” Journal of Financial Economics, 3: 305360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeley, M. 1980. “Organizational Analogy: A Comparison of Organismic and Social Contract Models.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 337362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeley, M. 1988. A Social-Contract Theory of Organizations. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Klonoski, R. 1991. “Foundational Considerations in the Corporate Social Responsibility Debate.” Business Horizons, 34(4): 918.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B., Shan, W., and Walker, G. 1992. “The Make or Cooperate Decision in the Context of an Industry Network.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 348–365. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Lewin, D., & Mitchell, D. 1992. “Systems of Employee Voice: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives.” California Management Review, 34(3): 95111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyons, N. P. 1988. “Two Perspectives: On Self, Relationships, and Morality.” In Gilligan, C., Ward, J., & Taylor, J., with Bardige, B. (Eds.), Mapping the Moral Domain: A Contribution of Women’s Thinking to Psychological Theory and Education: 2148. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Logsdon, J. 1991. “Interests and Interdependence in the Formation of Social Problem-Solving Collaborations.” Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 27(1): 2337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macneil, I. 1981. “Economic Analysis of Contractual Relations: Its Shortfalls and the Need for a ‘Rich’ Classificatory Apparatus.” Northwestern University Law Review, 75: 10181063.Google Scholar
Michael, E., & Savage, G. 1993. “On the Road to Jerusalem: Exploring the Ethical Ground for Stakeholder Management.” In Pasquero, J. & Colins, D., (Eds.). Proceedings of the Fourth Annual Meeting of the International Association for Business & Society: 418428.Google Scholar
Nathan, M., & Mitroff, I. 1991. “The Use of Negotiated Order Theory as a Tool for the Analysis and Development of an Interorganizational Field.” Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 27(2): 163180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nisbett, R., & Ross, L. 1980. Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcomings of Social Judgment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Nohria, N. 1992. “Is a Network Perspective a Useful Way of Studying Organizations?” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.). Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 122. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Nohria, N., & Eccles, R. 1992. “Face to Face: Making Network Organizations Work.” In Nohria, N. & Eccles, R. (Eds.). Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action: 288308. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Noreen, E. 1988. “The Economics of Ethics: A New Perspective on Agency Theory.” Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13(4): 359369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ouchi, W. 1980. “Markets, Bureaucracies, and Clans.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 25: 129141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, T. 1986. Thriving on Chaos: Handbook for a Management Revolution. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Perrow, C. 1986. “Economic Theories of Organizations.” Theory and Society, 15: 1145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, W. 1990. “Neither Market nor Hierarchy: Network Forms of Organization.” Research in Organizational Behavior, 12: 295336.Google Scholar
Pryne, E. 1993. “A New Horizon for the Tolt Basin; Watershed Analysis Helps Teams See Forest for the Trees,” Seattle Times, December 6: B-1, B2.Google Scholar
Quinn, J. B. 1992. Intelligent Enterprise: A Knowledge and Service Based Paradigm for Industry. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reich, R. 1992. The Work of Nations. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Ring, P. 1992. “The Role of Trust in the Design and Management of Business Organizations.” In Waddock, S. (Ed.). Proceedings of the Third Annual Meeting of the International Association for Business & Society: 284292.Google Scholar
Schonberger, R. 1992. “Total Quality Management cuts a Broad Swath through Manufacturing and Beyond.” Organizational Dynamics, 20(4): 1627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snow, C., Miles, R., & Coleman, H. 1992. “Managing 21st Century Network Organizations.” Organizational Dynamics, 20(3): 519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldron, J. 1989. “John Locke: Social Contract versus Political Anthropology.” Review of Politics, 57(1): 327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wheatley, M. 1992. “Searching for Order in an Orderly World: A Poetic for Post-Machine-Age Managers.” Journal of Management Inquiry, 1(4): 337342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. 1984. “Corporate Governance.” Yale Law Journal, 93: 11971230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, and Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. 1991. “Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives.” Administrative Science Quarterly, 36: 269296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, D. 1991. Corporate Social Performance Revisited. Academy of Management Review, 16: 691718.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wood, D. 1992. Discovering the Structure of Corporate Social Performance. Chairperson’s address to the Social Issues in Management division of the Academy of Management, Las Vegas.Google Scholar
Wood, D., & Gray, B. 1991. “Toward a Comprehensive Theory of Collaboration.” Journal of Applied Behavioral Science, 27(2): 139162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar