Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-25T19:54:06.019Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Adam Smith’s Bourgeois Virtues in Competition

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 January 2015

Thomas Wells
Affiliation:
Erasmus University, Rotterdam
Johan Graafland
Affiliation:
Tilburg University
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract:

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Whether or not capitalism is compatible with ethics is a long standing dispute. We take up an approach to virtue ethics inspired by Adam Smith and consider how market competition influences the virtues most associated with modern commercial society. Up to a point, competition nurtures and supports such virtues as prudence, temperance, civility, industriousness and honesty. But there are also various mechanisms by which competition can have deleterious effects on the institutions and incentives necessary for sustaining even these most commercially friendly of virtues. It is often supposed that if competitive markets are good, more competition must always be better. However, in the long run competition enhancing policies that neglect the nurturing and support of the bourgeois virtues may undermine the continued flourishing of modern commercial society.

Type
Special Issue: Reviving Traditions: Virtue and the Common Good in Business and Management
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Business Ethics 2012

References

REFERENCES

Alpizar, F., Carlsson, F., and Johansson-Stenman, O. 2005. “How Much Do We Care About Absolute Versus Relative Income Consumption?,” Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organisation 56: 405–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Badhwar, N. K. 2008. “Friendship andCommercial Societies,” Politics Philosophy Economics 7(3) (August 1): 301–26. DOI:10.1177/1470594X08092105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bassiry, G. R., and Jones, M. 1993. “Adam Smith and the Ethics of Contemporary Capitalism,” Journal of Business Ethics 12(8): 621–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N., and Jordahl, H. 2006. “Free to Trust: Economic Freedom and Social Capital,” Kyklos 59(2): 141–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, M., 1996. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Boot, A., 2009. De ontwortelde samenleving. Ondernemingen overgeleverd aan financiers? Assen: Van Gorcum.Google Scholar
Bovenberg, A. L., 2002. “Norms, Values, and Technological Change,” De Economist 150(5): 521–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovenberg, A. L., 2007. “Boekbespreking,” Christen Democratische Verkenningen 28(3): 166–70.Google Scholar
Calkins, M. J., and Werhane, P. H. 1998. “Adam Smith, Aristotle, and the Virtues of Commerce,” The Journal of Value Inquiry 32(1): 4360CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, F., Johansson-Stenman, O., and Martinsson, P. 2007. “Do You Enjoy Having More than Others? Survey Evidence of Positional Goods,” Economica 74,no. 296(11): 586–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carmon, Z., Wertenbroch, K., and Zeelenberg, M. 2003. “Option Attachment: When Deliberating Makes Choosing Feel Like Losing,” Journal of Consumer Research 30: 1529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., 1997. “Consumer Preferencefor a No Choice Option,” Journal of Consumer Research 24(2): 215–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fleischacker, S. 2005. On Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations: A Philosophical Companion. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Florida, R. L. 2002. The Rise of the Creative Class. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Franklin, B. 2008 (1748). The Way to Wealth and Poor Richard’s Almanac. Nayika Publishing.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S., Benesch, C., and Stutzer, A. 2007. “Does Watching TV Make Us Happy?,” Journal of Economic Psychology 28(3): 283313.–CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graafland, J. J., and Smid, H. 2004. “Reputation, Corporate Social Responsibility and Market Regulation,” Tijdschrift voor Economie en Management 49(2): 269306.–Google Scholar
Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., and Rajgopal, S. 2005. “The Economic Implications Of Corporate Financial Reporting,” Journal of Accounting and Economics 40(1): 373.–DOI:10.1016/j.jacceco.2005.01.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griswold, C. L. 1999. Adam Smith and the Virtues of Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hanley, R. 2006. “Adam Smith, Aristotleand Virtue Ethics,” in New Voices on Adam Smith, ed. Montes, Leonidas and Schliesser, Eric. London. New York: Routledge 1739.–Google Scholar
Hanley, R. 2008. “Commerce and Corruption: Rousseau‘s Diagnosis and Adam Smith’s Cure,” European Journal of Political Theory 7 2: 137–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanley, R. 2009. Adam Smith and the Character of Virtue. New York: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, J. 2006. “The Benefits of Cooperation,” Philosophy & Public Affairs 34: 313–51. DOI:10.1111/j.1088-4963.2006.00073.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, J. 2007. “An Adversarial Ethicfor Business: Or When Sun-Tzu Met the Stakeholder,” Journal of Business Ethics 72(4): 359–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Ensminger, J., McElreath, R.,Barr, A., Barrett, C., Bolyanatz, A., Cardenas, J. C.,Gurven, M., Gwako, E., Lesorogol, C.,Marlowe, F.,Tracer, D., and Ziker, J. 2010. “Markets, Religion, Community Size, and the Evolution of Fairness And Punishment,” Science 327(March): 1480–84. DOI:10.1126/science.1182238.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hirsch, F. 1977. Social Limits to Growth. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1982. “Rival Interpretations of Market Society: Civilizing, Destructive, or Feeble?,” Journal of Economic Literature 20(4): 1463–84.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. 1997(1977). The Passions and the Interests. Princeton Princeton, N.J.Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hursthouse, R. 2007. “Virtue Ethics,” in the Stanford Encyclopaedia of Philosophy, http://plato.stanford.edu/entries/ethics-virtue/.Google Scholar
Iyengar, S. S., and Lepper, M. R. 2000. “When Choice Is Demotivating: CanOneDesire Too Much of a Good Thing?,” Journal of Personality andSocialPsychology 79: 9951006.–CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Johansson-Stenman, O., Carlsson, F. and Daruvala, D. 2002. “Measuring Future Grandparents’ Preferences for Equality and Relative Standing,” Economic Journal 112: 362–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Slovic, P., and Tversky, A. 1982. Judgment under Uncertainty. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. 1997. “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation,” in the The Quarterly Journalof Economics, 112: 1251–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. H. 1923. “The Ethics of Competition,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 37(4): 579624.–CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. 1997. “The Interaction between Norms and Economic Incentives: Intrinsic Motivation and Extrinsic Incentives,” American Economic Review, 87: 359–64.Google Scholar
Laverty, K. J. 1996Economic ‘Short-termism’: The Debate, the Unresolved Issues, and the Implications for ManagementPractice and Research,” Academy of Management Review 21: 825–60.Google Scholar
Layard, R. 2003. “Happiness: Has SocialScience a Clue?” Lionel Robbins Memorial Lectures 2002/2003, Centre forEconomic Performance, London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Layard, E. P. 2000. “The Power of IncentivesAmerican Economic Review 90(2): 410–14.Google Scholar
Lienhard, M. 2006. “Productivity and Well-Being under Fixed Wages and Piece Rates,” in Psychological Foundation of Wage Incentives: An ExperimentalAnalysis(Doctoral Thesis, University ofZurich, 2006)pp 65104.– http://www.iew.uzh.ch/study/ thesisses/mlienhard/dissertation.pdf.Google Scholar
MacIntyre, A. C. 1981. After Virtue. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
MacIntyre, A. C. 1995. Marxism and Christianity. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, D. A. 2006. An Engine, Not a Camera: How Financial Models Shape Markets. Cambridge,Mass.: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Major, V. S., Klein, K. J., and Ehrhart, M. G. 2002. “Work Time, Work Interference with Family, and PsychologicalDistress,” Journal of Applied Psychology 87: 427–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, K., and Engels, F. 2002(1848). The Communist Manifesto, ed. Jones, Gareth Stedman. Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. 1998. “Bourgeois Virtue and the History of P and S,” The Journal of Economic History 58(2): 427317.–CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. 2006. The Bourgeois Virtues. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. 2008. “Adam Smith, the Last of the Former Virtue Ethicists,” History of Political Economy 40(1): 4371.–CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mick, D. G., Broniarczyk, S. M., and Haidt, J. 2004. “Choose, Choose, Choose, Choose, Choose, Choose: Emergingand Prospective Research on the Deleterious Effects of Living in Consumer Hyper Choice,” Journal of Business Ethics 52: 207–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, J. G. 1984. “Culture and the Development of Everyday Social Explanation,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 46(5): 961–78. DOI:10.1037/0022-3514.46.5.961.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Otteson, J. 2002. Adam Smith's Marketplace of Life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pitts, J. 2005. A Turn to Empire: The Rise of ImperialLiberalism in Britain and France. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raphael, D. D., and Macfie, A. L. 1982. “Introduction,” in Smith, Adam, The Theory Of Moral Sentiments. Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.Google Scholar
Rappaport, A. 2005. “The Economics ofShort-Term Performance Obsession,” Financial Analyst Journal. 61: 6579.–CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasmussen, D. C. 2008. The Problems and Promise of Commercial Society. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
Ross, L. 1977. “The Intuitive Psychologist and His Shortcomings: Distortions in the Attribution Process,” Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 10: 173220.– New York: PAcademic Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schor, J. B. 1993. The Overworked American: The Unexpected Decline of Leisure. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Schor, J. B. 1997. Beyond an Economy of Work and Spend. Tilburg: Tilburg University Press.Google Scholar
Schwartz, B. 2004. The Paradox of Choice. New York: HarperCollins Publishers Inc.Google Scholar
Sennett, R. 1998. The Corrosion of Character.New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Sennett, R. 2007. The Culture of the New Capitalism.New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Shafir, E., Simonson, I., and Tversky, A. 1992. “Reason-Based Choice,” Cognition 49(1): 1136.– CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafir, E., and Tversky, A., 1992. “Thinking through Uncertainty: Nonconsequential Reasoning and Choice,” Cognitive Psychology 24(4): 449–74 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shearer, B. 2004. “Piece Rates, FixedWages and Incentives: Evidence from a Field Experiment,” Reviewof Economic Studies 71(2): 513–34. DOI:10.1111/0034-6527.00294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepard, J. M., Shepard, J., and Wokutch, R. E. 1991. “The Problem of Business Ethics: Oxymoron or Inadequate Vocabulary?,” Journal of Business and Psychology 6(1): 923.– CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skreta, V., and Veldkamp, L. 2009. “Ratings Shopping and Asset Complexity: ATheory of Rating Inflation,” NBER working paper no. 14761.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1981[1776,1789]. An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. Campbell, R. H.Skinner, A. S., and Todd, W. B.Indianapolis: Liberty Classics.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1982a [1762−1763, 1766]. Lectures on Jurisprudence, ed. MeekR. L., R. L.,Raphael, D. D., and Stein, P. G.Indianapolis:Liberty Press.Google Scholar
Smith, A. 1982b [1759, 1790]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, ed. Raphael, D. D.and Macfie, A. L.Indianapolis:Liberty Classics.Google Scholar
Solnick, S. J., and Hemenway, D. 1998. “Is More Always Better? A Survey on Positional Concerns,” Journal of Economic Behavior &Organization 37: 373–83. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 1992a. “Corporate Roles, Personal Virtues: An Aristotelean Approach to Business Ethics,” Business Ethics Quarterly 2(3): 317–39. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 1992b. Ethics and Excellence. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 1998. “The Moral Psychology of Business: Care and Compassion in the Corporation,” Business Ethics Quarterly 8(3): 515–33. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 2002. “Business Ethicsand Virtue,” in A Companion to Business Ethics, e.d. Frederick, Robert. Wiley-Blackwell, 3055.– Google Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 2008. “Free Enterprise, Sympathy, and Virtue,” in Moral Markets, e.d. Zak, Paul J.Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press,1641.– Google Scholar
Solomon, R. C. 2008. “Free Enterprise, Sympathy, and Virtue,” in Moral Markets, e.d. Zak, Paul J.Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press,1641.– Google Scholar
van Staveren, I. 2009. “Virtue Ethics,” in Handbook of Economics and Ethics, e.d. Peil, Jan and Staveren, Irene van. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar,570–77.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. 1987. “Competition,” in The New Palgrave, e.d. Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P.London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., Sunstein, C. R., and Balz, J. P. 2010. “Choice Architecture,” in SSRN eLibrary(April 2). http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1583509CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickers, J. S. 1995. “Concepts of Competition,” Oxford Economic Papers 47:123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. 2003 [1904–1905]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, trans.Parsons, Talcott. Courier Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Wells, T.Forthcoming. “Adam Smith on Morality and Self-Interest,” in Handbook of the Philosophical Foundations of Business Ethics ed. Lütge, Christoph. Springer.Google Scholar
Werhane, P. 1989. “The Role of Self-Interest in Adam Smith‘sWealth of Nations,” in Journal of Philosophy 86(11): 669–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werhane, P. 1991. Adam Smith and His Legacy for Modern Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Werhane, P. 1999. Moral Imagination and Management Decision-Making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Werhane, P. 2000. “Business Ethics and the Origins of Contemporary Capitalism: Economics and Ethics in the Work of Adam Smith and Herbert Spencer,” Journal of Business Ethics 24(3): 185–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, M., Hill, S., McGovern, P., Mills, C., and Smeaton, D. 2003. “‘High-Performance’ Management Practices, Working Hours and Work-Life Balance,”British Journal of Industrial Relations 41 no.2 (6): 175–95. DOI:10.1111/1467-8543.00268.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, P. J., and Knack, S. 2001. “Trust and Growth,”The Economic Journal 111(470) (April): 295321.– CrossRefGoogle Scholar