Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-15T17:48:48.116Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Accounting for Nonconvergence in Global Wool Marketing before 1939

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2015

Abstract

From the mid-nineteenth century, raw wool became a global commodity as new producing countries in the Southern Hemisphere supplied the world's growing textile industries in the North. The selling practices of these big-five exporters—Australia, New Zealand, South Africa, Argentina, and Uruguay—ranged from auction through a hybrid of auction and private sale to exclusively private sale. We explore why these countries persisted with different marketing arrangements, contradicting two streams of literature on institutions: isomorphism and the new institutional economics. The article makes several important contributions through blending distinct branches of theory and by focusing on the international constraints to convergence in an earlier period of globalization.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The President and Fellows of Harvard College 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 For an account of the growth of the woolen textile industry in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, see Jenkins, David, “The Western Wool Textile Industry in the Nineteenth Century” and “Wool Textiles in the Twentieth Century,” in The Cambridge History of Western Textiles, vol. 2, ed. Jenkins, David (Cambridge, U.K., 2003), 761–89Google Scholar, 993–1022.

2 Stephen C. Brearley, “The International Wool Market, 1840–1913” (PhD diss., University of Leicester, 2004), chap. 3.

3 Plessis, A. Foster Du, The Marketing of Wool (London, 1931), 102Google Scholar.

4 DiMaggio, Paul J. and Powell, Walter W., “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields,” American Sociological Review 48 (1983): 147–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 North, Douglass C., Structure and Change in Economic History (New York, 1981)Google Scholar; North, Douglass C., Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge, U.K., 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. His later work emphasizes the role of institutions in reducing uncertainty, which is a necessary but not “a sufficient condition for efficiency” (Institutions, 84). The existing set of institutions within a country may result in an incomplete refashioning of institutional frameworks spurred by new information or technologies.

6 After cleaning, the wool fiber is broken up by a process of carding or combing into tops, which enables it to be spun. For a contemporary description of the processes involved, see Barker, Aldred F. and Priestley, E., Wool Carding and Combing with Notes on Sheep Breeding and Wool Growing (London, 1912)Google Scholar, chaps. 9 and 10.

7 Maddison, Angus, Contours of the World Economy: Essays in Macro-Economic History (Oxford, 2007), 70Google Scholar, table 2.1.

8 Jenkins, “Western Wool Textile Industry,” 762–65.

9 Fraser, W. Hamish, The Coming of the Mass Market (London, 1981)Google Scholar, chap. 5; Penelope Byrde, “Dress: The Industrial Revolution and After,” in Cambridge History of Western Textiles, ed. Jenkins, 882–909; Lou Taylor and Fiona Anderson, “Fashion for Women and Men in the Twentieth Century,” in Cambridge History of Western Textiles, ed. Jenkins, 1044–74.

10 Jenkins, “Wool Textiles in the Twentieth Century,” 993.

11 Jenkins, “Western Wool Textile Industry,” 788, table 19.6; Clapham, John H., The Woollen and Worsted Industries (London, 1907), 221–70Google Scholar.

12 Blau, Gerda, “Wool in the World Economy,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 109 (1946): 183, 181CrossRefGoogle Scholar, table 2.

13 Carter, Harold B., His Majesty's Spanish Flock (Sydney, 1964)Google Scholar; James F. Guthrie, A World History of Sheep and Wool (privately printed, 1957); Ponting, K. G., The Wool Trade Past and Present (Manchester, 1961)Google Scholar; Massy, Charles, The Australian Merino (Ringwood, Vic., 1990)Google Scholar.

14 Concerning Wool (Melbourne, n.d.), 94.

15 Critchell, James Troubridge and Raymond, Joseph, A History of the Frozen Meat Trade: An Account of the Development and Present Day Methods of Preparation, Transport, and Marketing of Frozen and Chilled Meats (London, 1912, reprinted 1969), chaps. 1–6Google Scholar.

16 See Bell, Adrian R., Brooks, Chris, and Dryburgh, Paul R., The English Wool Market, c. 1230–1327 (Cambridge, U.K., 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar and De Roover, Raymond, The Rise and Decline of the Medici Bank, 1397–1494 (Cambridge, Mass., 1963)Google Scholar. We thank one of the referees for drawing our attention to the continuities in marketing and financing in the international wool trade.

17 Rees, G. L., Britain's Commodity Markets (London, 1972), 320–30Google Scholar; Maughan, Cuthbert, The Markets of London (London, 1931)Google Scholar, chap. 20.

18 Rees, Britain's Commodity Markets, 321–26; Ville, Simon, The Rural Entrepreneurs: A History of the Stock and Station Agent Industry in Australia and New Zealand (New York, 2000)Google Scholar. Wool buyers traveled from Europe, North America, and Japan to the wool-producing countries. Charles Bean describes the migratory flow to Australia before 1914: “Towards the end of winter a number of well-paid foreign gentlemen arrive to buy wool in Sydney. Towards the end of summer they sail home again, and find out roughly what wool their principals will be wanting next summer. Towards the end of winter they will come back again to buy it.” Bean, Charles E. W., On the Wool Track (London, 1910), 270Google Scholar.

19 Skinner, Thomas, Skinner's Wool Trade Directory of the World, 1928 (Bradford, 1928)Google Scholar.

20 Skinner, Thomas, Skinner's Wool Trade Directory of the World, 1948 (Bradford, 1948)Google Scholar, 21, 30, 10.

21 For an excellent overview, see Brearley, “International Wool Market,” chap. 4. This process of relocation has been examined most fully with respect to the establishment of local auction sales in Australia. Barnard, Alan, The Australian Wool Market, 1840–1900 (Melbourne, 1958), chap. 7Google Scholar; Ville, Simon, “Relocation of the International Market for Australian Wool,” Australian Economic History Review 45, no. 1 (2005): 7395CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Barnard, Australian Wool Market, 167–68.

23 Rees, Britain's Commodity Markets, 323–30.

24 Butlin, Noel George, Investment in Australian Economic Development, 1861–1900 (Cambridge, U.K., 1964)Google Scholar; Ville, Rural Entrepreneurs.

25 Merrett, David Tolmie, Morgan, Stephen, and Ville, Simon, “Industry Associations as Facilitators of Social Capital: The Establishment and Early Operations of the Melbourne Woolbrokers’ Association,Business History 50, no. 6(2008): 781–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Merrett, David Tolmie and Ville, Simon, “Institution Building and Variation in the Formation of the Australian Wool Market,” Australian Economic History Review 53, no. 2 (2013): 146–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 For New Zealand's auctions, see Ville, Simon, “Rent Seeking or Market Strengthening? Industry Associations in New Zealand Wool Broking,Business History Review 81 (Summer 2007): 304–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar; for South Africa, see Abbott, Malcolm, “South African Wool Marketing,” South African Journal of Economic History 12/13 (1997/1998): 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Wickens, Peter, “State and Private Enterprise in the Development of the Cape Wool-Growing Industry,” South African Journal of Economic History 1, no. 1 (1986): 47Google Scholar; and Du Plessis, Marketing of Wool, 184–85.

27 The proportion of New Zealand wool auctioned domestically rose from 35 percent in 1900 to 85 percent in 1938 (Australia Bureau of Agricultural Economics, Statistical Handbook of the Sheep and Wool Industry [Canberra, 1949], 76Google Scholar).

28 Clapham, Woollen and Worsted Industries, 98.

29 Goodfellow, David Martin, An Economic History of South Africa (London, 1931), 118–19Google Scholar, 128, 136. On an overseas visit in 1931, Walter Devereux, a representative of the Australian Wool Growers Council, confirmed the continuation of private sales arrangements in both South America and South Africa (Walter Devereux to Australian Wool Growers Council, 30 Mar. 1931, and Walter Devereux to Sir Charles Waddell, 23 Apr. 1930, E246/1–5, Australian Wool Growers Council, Noel Butlin Archives Centre, Australian National University, Canberra).

30 Brearley, “International Wool Market,” 136. After 1900, growers not selling direct from the farm used commission agents to consign their wool, which would be offered to the fifty or sixty firms operating in the main markets, Buenos Aires and Bahia Blanca (Australia, Statistical Handbook of the Sheep and Wool Industry, 77). See also Brown, Jonathon C., “Dynamics and Autonomy of a Traditional Marketing System: Buenos Aires, 1810–1860,” Hispanic American Historical Review 56, no. 4 (1976)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sabato, Hilda, “Wool Trade and Commercial Networks in Buenos Aires, 1840s to 1880s,” Journal of Latin American Studies 15, no. 1 (1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Sabato, Hilda, Agrarian Capitalism and the World Economy: Buenos Aires in the Pastoral Age, 1840–1890 (Albuquerque, 1990), chap. 6Google Scholar.

31 Sabato, Agrarian Capitalism, 234.

32 Garside, Alston Hill, Wool and the Wool Trade (New York, 1939), 69Google Scholar.

33 For a review of the literature, see Scott, W. Richard, Institutions and Organizations: Ideas and Interests, 3rd ed. (Los Angeles, 2008)Google Scholar.

34 DiMaggio and Powell, “Iron Cage Revisited,” 147.

35 Giddens, Anthony, Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure and Contradiction in Social Analysis (Berkeley, 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; DiMaggio and Powell, “Iron Cage Revisited,” 148.

36 DiMaggio and Powell, “Iron Cage Revisited,” 150.

37 Merrett and Ville, “Institution Building and Variation,” 148–50.

38 DiMaggio and Powell, “Iron Cage Revisited,” 148.

39 Ibid., 150–54.

40 North, Institutions, chaps. 5 and 6.

41 Magee, Gary B. and Thompson, Andrew S., Empire and Globalisation: Networks of People, Goods and Capital in the British World, c. 1850–1914 (Cambridge, U.K., 2010), 69CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

42 For a careful discussion of the nature of the connections between Britain and its empire, see Magee and Thompson, Empire and Globalisation. Institution building in Latin America is explored by Coatsworth, John H., “Structure, Endowments, and Institutions in the Economic History of Latin America,” Latin American Research Review 40, no. 3 (2005): 126–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Coatsworth, John H., “Political Economy and Economic Organizations,” in Cambridge Economic History of Latin America, ed. Bulmer-Thomas, Victor, Coatsworth, John, and Cortes-Conde, Roberto (New York, 2006), 235–74Google Scholar.

43 See, for instance, Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A., “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review 91, no. 5 (2001): 13691401CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A., Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (London, 2012)Google Scholar; Diamond, Jared, Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies (New York, 1997)Google Scholar; Engerman, Stanley L. and Sokoloff, Kenneth L., “Five Hundred Years of European Colonization: Inequality and Paths of Development,” in Settler Economies in World History, ed. Lloyd, Christopher, Meltzer, Jacob, and Sutch, Richard (Leiden, Netherlands, 2013)Google Scholar; and Sachs, Jeffrey D., “Notes on a New Sociology of Economic Development,” in Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, ed. Harrison, Lawrence E. and Huntington, Samuel P. (New York, 2000), 2943Google Scholar.

44 Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail, 279–80, 282, 299, 329, 341, 372, 385, 387, 398, 401–2, 445.

45 Clapham, Woollen and Worsted Industries, 98.

46 Textile Mercury, The Wool Year Book and Diary, 1915 (Manchester, 1915)Google Scholar, 40, 50; Statistical Handbook of the Sheep and Wool Industry, 19, table 21.

47 Roberts, Stephen, History of Australian Land Settlement (South Melbourne, 1924, reprinted 1968)Google Scholar, parts 3–5.

48 Coatsworth, “Structure, Endowments,” 131; Coatsworth, “Political Economy,” 259–61; Amaral, Samuel, The Rise of Capitalism on the Pampas: The Estancias of Buenos Aires (Cambridge, U.K., 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail, 258–71. For a comparison of Australian and Argentinian experiences, see McLean, Ian W., Why Australia Prospered: The Shifting Sources of Economic Growth (Princeton, 2013)Google Scholar, chaps. 4 and 5.

49 We owe this point to Malcolm Abbott.

50 Ville, Rural Entrepreneurs; Butlin, Investment, 57–166.

51 The wool trade was both a result of and a contributor to a “network” resulting from the movement of people, goods, and capital within the British world, as described by Magee and Thompson, Empire and Globalisation.

52 Skinner, Skinner's Wool Trade Directory, 1948, lxxv–lxxxiii; Abbott, Malcolm, “Promoting Wool Internationally: The Formation of the International Wool Secretariat,Australian Economic History Review 38, no. 3 (1998): 258–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

53 Tenny, Lloyd S., “Standardization of Farm Products,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 137 (1928): 208Google Scholar, 210.

54 Skinner, Skinner's Wool Trade Directory, 1948, xxviii.

55 Garside, Wool and the Wool Trade, chaps. 8–9; Du Plessis, Marketing of Wool, chap. 11.

56 Beckert, Sven, Empire of Cotton: A New History of Global Capitalism (London, 2014), 320–21Google Scholar.

57 Rees, Britain's Commodity Markets, 332.

58 Du Plessis, Marketing of Wool, 120, 135; Blau, “Wool in the World Economy,” 216–17.

59 Brisbane Wool Selling Brokers’ Association, Cuttings books, OM.A/7/1, John Oxley Library, State Library of Queensland, Brisbane.

60 David Merrett and Ville, Simon, “Industry Associations and Non-Competitive Behaviour in Australian Wool Marketing: Evidence from the Melbourne Woolbrokers’ Association, 1890–1939,Business History 54, no. 4(2012): 510–28Google Scholar.

61 The Australian Mercantile Land and Finance Company estimated that it would need to sell at least 25,000 bales to be profitable in the Brisbane market prior to World War I. We have raised the minimum efficient scale figure to 30,000 as brokers’ costs would have risen. Moreover, the crossbred wool dealt with by New Zealand brokers both reduced selling commissions and increased handling charges (Bailey, John D., A Hundred Years of Pastoral Banking: A History of the Australian Mercantile Land and Finance Company [Oxford, 1966], 196Google Scholar).

62 Australasian Insurance and Banking Record, 19 Oct. 1899, 699.

63 Merrett, Morgan, and Ville, “Industry Associations as Facilitators”; Merrett and Ville, “Industry Associations”; Merrett and Ville, “Institution Building and Variation.”

64 “For two generations those sales [at the Wool Exchange in Coleman Street] have been the centre of the international wool trade,” Clapham, Woollen and Worsted Industries, 91.

65 Blau, “Wool in the World Economy,” 184–85, table 4.

66 Garside, Wool and Wool Trade, 7–8; Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Report of Wool Marketing in England and Wales (London, 1926), 2730Google Scholar.

67 Neller, Shelley, Wool in the Australian Imagination (Glebe, New South Wales, 1994)Google Scholar; Wadham, Samuel M. and Wood, Gordon L., Land Utilization in Australia (Melbourne, 1950), 118Google Scholar.

68 Critchell and Raymond, Frozen Meat Trade.

69 Jenkins, “Wool Textiles in the Twentieth Century,” 1007.

70 Blau, “Wool in the World Economy,” 181.

71 Textile Mercury, Wool Year Book, 1915, 422–23; Textile Mercury, Wool Year Book, 1930 (Manchester, 1930), 82Google Scholar; Barker and Priestley, Wool Carding and Combing, 233–34.

72 Textile Mercury, Wool Year Book, 1915, 465.

73 Ibid., 62–63.

74 “The success of grading depended entirely on the extent to which each bale contained wool of one quality only and each lot contained bales of even quality,” Barnard, The Australian Wool Market, 81.

75 Du Plessis, Marketing of Wool, 58–59; Barker and Priestley, Wool Carding and Combing, 69, 105.

76 Barker and Priestley, Wool Carding and Combing, 97, 129–39, 144–87.

77 Classing prior to auction cost British top makers 15 to 18 pence per 240 pounds (weight) of wool; see Textile Mercury, Wool Year Book, 1915, 93. For classing costs in Australia, see Jeffrey, Geoffrey, The Principles and Practice of Australasian Woolclassing (Adelaide, 1899), 45Google Scholar; and Smith, Henry B., The Sheep and Wool Industry of Australasia (Melbourne, 1917), 89Google Scholar.

78 Blau, “Wool in the World Economy,” 191.

79 Sabato, Agrarian Capitalism, 229.

80 We ignore differences in interest rates and currency fluctuations.

81 Price categories at London auctions were “super,” “average to good,” and “inferior to average.” Textile Mercury, Wool Year Book, 1930, 51.

82 Sabato, Agrarian Capitalism, 229–30.

83 Sabato, “Wool Trade and Commercial Networks,” 60.

84 Du Plessis, Marketing of Wool, 102.

85 Fibers comprised around 16 percent of all primary products exports in 1913 and 1928, and about 10 percent of all merchandise exports in those years. See Yates, P. Lamartine, Forty Years of Foreign Trade (London, 1959), 222–23Google Scholar, table A.16.

86 Collis, Brad, Fields of Discovery: Australia's CSIRO (Crows Nest, New South Wales, 2002), 176–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

87 Cox, A. B., Cotton: Demand, Supply, Merchandising (Austin, 1953), 131–47Google Scholar; Beckert, Empire of Cotton.

88 Donald Coleman, “Man-Made Fibres before 1945,” in Cambridge History of Western Textiles, ed., Jenkins, 994.

89 Scott, Institutions and Organizations.

90 See Merrett and Ville, “Institution Building and Variation,” for an account of interselling center differences within Australia.

91 Acemoglu and Robinson, Why Nations Fail.