Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T21:19:56.712Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Social Insurance Paradox: A Comment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 November 2014

John O. Blackburn*
Affiliation:
Duke University
Get access

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Notes
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 1967

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Aaron, Henry, “The Social Insurance Paradox,” this Journal, XXXII (08 1966), 371–4.Google Scholar A number of points would appear to bear comment, but this note is restricted to one aspect of the matter.

2 Aaron presumably intends his results to apply generally to economies with or without capital. The Samuelson article cited, An Exact Consumption-Loan Model of Interest with or without the Social Contrivance of Money,” Journal of Political Economy, LXVI (12 1958), 467–82Google Scholar, carefully excludes economies with any storable goods.

3 These propositions are demonstrated, inter alia, for Cobb-Douglas models in Solow, R. M., “A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Ecoonmics, LXX (02 1956), 6594 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Brems, H., “Growth, Distribution, Productivities and Thrift in Cobb-Douglas Models,” Southern Economic Journal, XXIX (01 1963), 181–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar; “Comment” by J. O. Blackburn and “Reply” by Brems, Hans, Southern Economic Journal XXX (10 1963), 175–9.Google Scholar

4 Phelps, Edmund, “The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen,” American Economic Review, LI (09 1961), 638–42.Google Scholar

5 Aaron does not distinguish between labour and other incomes since he does not explicitly introduce capital and related profit or interest income. In fact, the status of “interest” as discussed by Aaron is unclear. Since we are dealing with a model in which property income exists, we must take it into account as being consumed or saved. Recipients of property income may also receive labour income; in any event, they must give some thought to their retirement years. The treatment most nearly approaching Aaron's seems to be that of dealing with real output (income) per person or per worker, analogous to his real wage (or real output per worker) in an economy in which only one factor (labour) is explicitly considered.