Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-xbtfd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T07:59:29.121Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Rise of Conservative Capitalism: Ideological Tensions within the Reagan and Thatcher Governments

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2009

Kenneth R. Hoover
Affiliation:
University of Wisconsin—Parkside

Extract

The phrase liberal capitalism has occasionally been used in contemporary political criticism to lump together the ideological approaches of nonsocialist political parties and to suggest that there are few significant differences among those who generally support a market-based political economy. C. B. Macpherson, in an influential essay entitled The Real World of Democracy (1965), argues that “by admitting the mass of the people into the competitive party system, the liberal state did not abandon its fundamental nature; it simply opened the competitive political system to all the individuals who had been created by the competitive market society.” As a first approximation then, liberal capitalism appears to stand for a combination of rational contractualism, utilitarian individualism, and the laissez-faire economics of Adam Smith.

Type
Comparative Politics
Copyright
Copyright © Society for the Comparative Study of Society and History 1987

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

This article is based in part on a paper prepared for the XIII World Congress of the International Political Science Association, Paris, July 1985. I would like to thank Norman Cloutier, Mark Kann. Thomas Moore, and Raymond Plant for their suggestions in writing this article.

1 Macpherson, C. B., The Real World of Democracy (London: Oxford University Press, 1965), 11Google Scholar. More recently, the discussion of “liberal democratic capitalism” has been at the heart of attempts to revise Marx's theory of the state. See Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert, “The Crisis of Liberal Democratic Capitalism: The Case of the United States,"” Politics and Society. 11:1 (1982), 5193CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Bowles and Gintis, “Crisis of Liberal Democratic Capitalism.” The phrase democratic capitalism has been avoided here largely because it is used for quite different purposes by Left and Right. On the Left, the phrase is an entry into the argument that democracy has altered capitalism in fundamental ways and that the current struggle is over the reassertion of capitalist control over democracy. This position is summarized in Alford, Robert, “The Reagan Budgets and the Contradiction between Capitalism and Democracy,” in The Future of American Democracy: Views from the Left, Kann, Mark, ed. (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1983), 2253Google Scholar. On the Right, conservatives such as Michael Novak use the phrase democratic capitalism to convey a quite different message: that democratic political norms legitimize the inequalities produced by the economic results of capitalism. The Spirit of Democratic Capitalism (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1982)Google Scholar.

3 Novak, , Spirit of Democratic Capitalism, 5253, 60Google Scholar.

4 For a survey of these expressions, see Smith, Geoffrey, “European Conservative Trend Growing,” Institute for Socioeconomic Studies Journal, 9 (Summer 1984), 4957Google Scholar.

5 The claim here is not that ideas cause events. Rather, it is similar to that made by Tholfsen, Trygve in Ideology and Revolution in Modern Europe: An Essay on the Role of Ideas in History (New York: Columbia University Press, 1984)Google Scholar: unlike the extrinsic relations that govern physical nature, human society is influenced by intrinsic logical and conceptual relations that are embedded in antecedent traditions and beliefs—among the most powerful of which are political ideologies. See Tholfsen, 2–3. Where causation lies cannot be determined; where influence lies is explored in studies such as that undertaken here.

6 Nash, George, The Conservative Intellectual Movement in America: Since 1945 (New York: Basic Books, 1979), 8182Google Scholar. Cf. the distinction between organic and individualist conservatism in Dolbeare, Kenneth and Dolbeare, Patricia, American Ideologies: The Competing Political Beliefs of the 1970s (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1976), 5671Google Scholar.

7 Robert Behrens locates the fault line in the Conservative Party between the Ditchers, who have bought into the postwar politics of statism, and the Diehards, who insist on the “true faith” of the free market and personal responsibility. The libertarian-traditionalist distinction differs in assessing the historical dimension of this split and its impact on current policy. Traditionalists, in our view, deviate only when they compromise Burke; and the faith of the Diehards, as Behrens allows, is in an adaptation of utilitarianism and laissez faire, not the conservative tradition. Cf.Behrens, , “Diehards and Ditchers in Contemporary Conservative Politics,” The Political Quarterly, 50 (0709 1979), 287–88, 292CrossRefGoogle Scholar; idem. The Conservative Party from Heath to Thatcher (London: Saxon House, 1980), 79, 39Google Scholar. For terminology used in the analysis of developments in Great Britain, see the distinction between the New Right and the Tory Far-right in Dunleavy, Patrick, “Analysing British Politics,” in Developments in British Politics, Drucker, Henry, ed. (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1983), 292–93Google Scholar; the discussion of Drys and Wets in Butt, Ronald, “Thatcherissima: The Politics of Thatcherism,” Policy Review, 26 (Fall 1983), 3035Google Scholar. Cf.Felker, Lon and Thompson, Robert, “The Intellectual Roots of Economic Conservatism in the Reagan and Thatcher Administrations,” Journal of the North Carolina Political Science Association, 3 (1983), 3855.Google Scholar

8 Machan, Tibor, ed., The Libertarian Alternative (Chicago: Nelson-Hall, 1974), 499Google Scholar. For nuances in the argument, cf.Nash, , Conservative Intellectual Movement, 1618, 3233Google Scholar; and O'Sullivan, Noel K., Conservatism (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1976), 27Google Scholar.

9 For a critique of Hayek's argument in this respect, see Plant, Raymond, “Hirsch, Hayek, and Habermas: The Dilemmas of Distribution,” in Dilemmas of Liberal Democracies, Ellis, A. and Kumar, K., eds. (London and New York: Tavistock, 1983), 4564Google Scholar.

10 Cf.Nash, , Conservative Intellectual Movement, 73Google Scholar; Nisbet, Robert, Community and Power (New York: Oxford University Press, 1962Google Scholar).

11 Williamson, Richard, “1980: The Reagan Campaign—Harbinger of a Revised Federalism,” Publius, 11 (Summer 1981) 149–50Google Scholar.

12 Structural reforms were much more popular than the cuts in antipoverty programs. Cf.Robinson, John and Fleishman, John, “Ideological Trends in American Public Opinion,” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 472 (03 1984), 5660CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Public Receptive to New Federalism,” Gallup Report, 185 (02 1981), 29Google Scholar.

13 Cannon, Lou, Reagan (New York: Putnams, 1982), 174–86Google Scholar.

14 Ibid., 184; cf. Levy, Frank, “What Ronald Reagan Can Teach the U.S. about Welfare Reform” (Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute, 1977)Google Scholar.

15 Moynihan, Daniel Patrick, The Politics of a Guaranteed Income: The Nixon Administration and the Family Assistance Plan (New York: Vintage, 1973), 110Google Scholar.

16 Nixon is reported to have specifically endorsed the “Tory men, liberal principles” theory of policy innovation. Ibid., 214–15.

17 Ibid., 374–75; Leman, Christopher, The Collapse of Welfare Reform (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1980), 92Google Scholar.

18 Cannon, , Reagan, 178–79Google Scholar.

19 Ibid., 202–7.

20 See Pear, Robert, “3 Key Aides Reshape Welfare Policy,” New York Times, 26 04 1982, p. 12Google Scholar; on AFDC, Demkovich, Linda, “Medicaid for Welfare: A Controversial Swap,” National Journal, 14 (27 02 1982), 363Google Scholar; on Community Development Block Grants, Lovell, Catherine, “CDBG: The Role of Federal Requirements,” Publius, 13 (Summer 1983), 94Google Scholar; on hunger, Demkovich, Linda, “Hunger in America: Is Its Resurgence Real or Is Evidence Exaggerated?NationaUournal, 15 (8 10 1983), 2051Google Scholar; on Social Security, idem, Team Player Schweiker May Be Paying a High Price for Loyalty to Reagan,” National Journal, 14 (15 05 1982), 849Google Scholar; on Medicaid, , “A Weekly Checklist of Major Issues,” National Journal, 7 (13 02 1982), 303Google Scholar; and on ending federal programs for the cities, Viscount, Francis and Jordan, Fred, “Will Cities' Link to Washington Be Cut?Nation's Cities Weekly, 4:21 (05 25 1981), 12Google Scholar.

21 Carleson, Robert and Hopkins, Kevin R., “Whose Responsibility Is Social Responsibility?: The Reagan Rationale,” Public Welfare. 8 (Fall 1981), 9, 1314Google Scholar. Cf. Associated Press, “Reagan Blasts Welfare Programs,” 16 02 1986Google Scholar.

22 In Barfield, Claude E., Rethinking Federalism (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1981), 70Google Scholar. Economist Oates, Wallace, “The New Federalism—An Economist's View,” Cam Journal, 2:2 (Fall 1982), 479Google Scholar, points out that the federalized share of AFDC has fallen, rather than risen.

23 McGovern, George, “Whose Responsibility Is Social Responsibility?: An Opposing View,” Public Welfare, 8 (Fall 1981), 9Google Scholar.

24 In Barfield, , Rethinking Federalism, p. 81Google Scholar. Regarding Carleson, see A Weekly Checklist of Major Issues,” National Journal, 7 (13 02 1982), 303Google Scholar.

25 Quoted in Reston, James, “Discussing the Bugs in the Machinery,” interview with David A. Stockman, New York Times. 12 04 1984, p. 12Google Scholar. Cf.Barfield, , Rethinking Federalism, 82Google Scholar.

26 Williamson, Richard, “The 1982 New Federalism Negotiations,” Publius, 13:2 (Spring 1983), 2728CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On weak claims, weak clients, and the role of political constituencies, cf.Greider, William' commentary in “The Education of David Stockman,” The Atlantic Monthly (12 1981), 30, 5152Google Scholar; Stockman, David' apology for the deficits, The Triumph of Politics (New York: Harper and Row, 1986), 124–27, 408–10Google Scholar; and his 1975 preview of that apology, The Social Pork Barrel,” Public Interest, no. 39 (Spring 1975), 27Google Scholar.

27 Kessel, John, “The Structures of the Reagan White House,” American Journal of Political Science, 28:2 (05 1984), 235–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar. In his memoir, Stockman variously describes himself as an “intellectual conservative” and a “social idealist” who thought supply-side economics along with a rationalization of means-tested entitlements could genuinely help the poor—he was intent on using libertarian means for traditionalist ends (p. 40). Cf.Moynihan, Daniel Patrick, “Political Aids,” The New Republic (05 26 1986), 18Google Scholar. He finally had to acknowledge that a tax increase was the only way out if equity was to be served, a position that separated him from thoroughgoing libertarians such as Donald Regan, then secretary of the treasury and now White House chief of staff; Stockman, , Triumph of Politics, 347–48, 363–64Google Scholar.

28 Cannon, , Reagan, 194Google Scholar.

29 Nathan, Richard and Doolittle, Fred, “Reagan's Surprising Domestic Achievement,” Wall Street Journal, 18 09 1984, p. 28.Google Scholar

30 Weicher, John (American Enterprise Institute), “Welfare ‘Reforms’ Will Stick,” Chicago Tribune, 16 08 1984, p. 27Google Scholar. The president indicated that total spending on the poor went up during his administration, but that was the effect of the recession on the size of entitlement populations.

31 Bawden, D. Lee and Palmer, John, “Social Policy,” in The Reagan Record, Palmer, John and Sawhill, Isabel, eds. (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Press), 204Google Scholar.

32 Ibid., 185–86.

33 U.S. Congress, House, Committee on Ways and Means, Effects of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1981 (OBRA) Welfare Changes and the Recession on Poverty, Committee Print for the Subcommittee on Oversight and Subcommittee on Public Assistance and Unemployment Compensation, 98th Cong., 2d sess. (Washington, D.C.: GPO, 25 07 1984)Google Scholar, Table A, p. x.

34 Ibid., 12.

35 Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, Washington, D.C., “Taxing the Poor” (04 1984)Google Scholar.

36 Congressional Budget Office projections, February 1983, cited in “The Combined Effectsof Major Changes in Federal Taxes and Spending Programs since 1981,7” staff memorandum, April 1984, prepared by the staff of the Human Resources and Community Development and Tax Analysis Division of the Congressional Budget Office, Table 3, p. 7a.

37 Newsweek, (9 09 1985), 24Google Scholar. This is the lowest percentage recorded for the bottom 40 percent since the Census Bureau began collecting this data in 1947.

38 U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, “Family Income in America,” staff report, 99th Cong., 1st sess. (28 11 1985), Table I, p. 4Google Scholar.

39 Marilyn Moon and Isabel Sawhill, “Family Incomes: Gainers and Losers,” in Palmer, and Sawhill, , The Reagan Record, 329Google Scholar, Table 10.5; 333, Table 10.6.

40 Noble, Kenneth, “Study Finds 60% of 11 Million Who Lost Jobs Got New Ones,” New York Times, 6 02 1986, p. 1Google Scholar. Noble reports that “the study said a large proportion of the displaced workers were middle-aged people in manufacturing ‘with long and stable job histories,’ rather than young people who change jobs often,” and estimated that the program instituted in 1982 to deal with displaced workers reached no more than 5 percent of them.

41 Hershey, Robert, “Savings Take a Dramatic Slide,” New York Times, 3 11 1985, sec. 4, p. ElGoogle Scholar.

42 See U.S. Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, Significant Features of Fiscal Federalism, 1984 Edition (Washington, D.C.: A.C.I.R., 1984)Google Scholar. Cf.Palmer, Kenneth and Pattakos, Alex, “The State of American Federalism: 1984,” Publius, 15 (Summer 1985), 117Google Scholar.

43 “Federalism and the States 1986,” report issued by the National Governors' Association (Washington, D.C.: National Governors' Association, 02 1986), 14Google Scholar.

44 See Beer, Samuel, Britain against Itself: The Political Contradictions of Collectivism (New York: Norton, 1982), 6475Google Scholar.

45 Ibid., 177–78.

46 Behrens, Robert, The Conservative Party in Opposition, 1974–1977: A Critical Analysis (Coventry: Lancaster Polytechnic, 1977), 1315Google Scholar.

47 Quoted in Plant, Raymond, “The Resurgence of Ideology,” in Developments in British Politics, Drucker, , ed., 13Google Scholar.

48 Cf.Behrens, , Conservative Party, 1417, 74Google Scholar.

49 Bosanquet, Nick, –Social Policy,” in Developments in British Politics, Drucker, , ed., 168– 69Google Scholar; re Behrens, see his “Diehards and Ditchers,” 286.

50 Miliband, Ralph, “A State of De-Subordination,” British Journal of Sociology. 29:4 (12 1978), 402CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51 Beer, , Britain against Itself, 194–97Google Scholar. Cf.Harbour, William, The Foundations of Conservative Thought (Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press, 1982), 185Google Scholar.

52 This is a problem that Adam Smith was vaguely aware of, but did not address. See Carnoy, Martin, The State and Political Theory (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984), 29Google Scholar.

53 See Leathers, Charles, “Thatcher-Reagan Conservatism and Schumpeter's Prognosis for Capitalism,” Review of Social Economy, 4:1 (1984), 2829Google Scholar.

54 Beer, , Britain against Itself, 126–31Google Scholar. Cf.Vigurie, Richard' mix of libertarianism and populism in The Establishment vs. the People (Chicago: Regnery Gateway, 1983)Google Scholar.

55 Piven, Frances Fox and Cloward, Richard, The New Class War (New York: Pantheon, 1982), 23Google Scholar. Cf.Alford, , “Reagan Budgets,” in Future of American Democracy, Kann, , ed., 4748Google Scholar, on Daniel Bell' argument of the same kind; and Beer, Samuel's argument about “pluralist stagnation” in Britain, Britain against Itself, 100101Google Scholar.

56 Hoskyns, John, “Conservatism Is Not Enough,” Political Quarterly, 55 (0103 1984), 1011CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The government is also criticized by the libertarians for being “inadequately radical.” See Thomas, Hugh (chairman of the (Conservative) Centre for Social Studies), “The Fruits of Conservatism,” New Society, 67:13 (1984), 435–36.Google Scholar

57 Walker, David, “Thatcher Faces Revolt on Student Aid,” The Chronicle of Higher Education, 3 (3 12 1984), 1Google Scholar.

58 Behrens, , Conservative Party, 1718Google Scholar.

59 For a sampling of these claims, see Greenleaf, W. H., The Rise of Collectivism, Vol. I of The British Political Tradition (London: Methuen, 1983), 161–63Google Scholar; Behrens, , “Diehards and Ditchers,” 286–95Google Scholar.

60 Harbour, William, Foundations of Conservative Thought, 186–87Google Scholar. Cf. Beer's citation of the sentiment of a prominent Tory M.P. of traditionalist background that “political advice, derived from liberal economic theory …leaves governors and its own adherents always frustrated at the distance between their model of the world and reality,” in Britain against Itself, 173–74Google Scholar.

61 Norton, Philip and Aughey, Arthur, Conservatives and Conservatism (London: Temple Smith, 1981), 285Google Scholar.

62 Quoted by Apple, R. W., “Thatcher Barely Escapes Defeat as 48 Conservative M.P.s Rebel,” New York Times, 24 07 1985, p. 4Google Scholar.

63 Tolchin, Susan and Tolchin, Martin, Dismantling America: The Rush to Deregulate (New York: Houghton Mifflin, 1983), 255Google Scholar; cf. “State Regulators Rush in Where Washington No Longer Treads: Will the New Federalism Create a Fifty-Headed Hydra?” Business Week, (19 09 1983), 124Google Scholar.

64 Dunleavy, Patrick and Rhodes, R. A. W., “Beyond Whitehall,” in Developments in British Politics, Drucker, , ed., 126128Google Scholar. Robert Behrens points out that antidevolutionists were generally found on the free market side, though there were exceptions. See Conservative Party in Opposition, 1920Google Scholar.

65 Conlan, Timothy, “Federalism and Competing Values in the Reagan Administration” (Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., 09 1984)Google Scholar, cites ten cases where structural devolution lost out to Reagan's prescriptive policy goals. Cf.Light, Alfred, “Federalism, FERC v. Mississippi, and Product Liability Reform,” Publius, 13 (Spring 1983), 8596CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

66 Shell, Donald, “The House of Lords and the Thatcher Government,” Parliamentary Affairs, 38 (Winter 1985), 1632Google Scholar.

67 Hobbes, Thomas, Leviathan (London: Penguin, 1970), 12Google Scholar.

68 This is a more dynamic conception of traditional conservatism than Samuel Huntington finds in the American version, where the traditionalist is seen more simply as “one who stands by established institutions.” Huntington, Samuel, “Conservatism as an Ideology,” American Political Science Review, 51:2 (06 1957), 470CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

69 Pym, Francis, The Politics of Consent (London: Hamish Hamilton, 1984)Google Scholar. Cf.Keegan, William, Mrs. Thatcher's Economic Experiment (London: Allen Lane, 1984)Google Scholar, on the doctrinal infighting.

70 Lelyveld, Joseph, “Thatcher Government Upset over a Critical Church Report,” New York Times, 2 12 1985, p. 11Google Scholar.

71 Durham, Martin, “Family, Morality, and the New Right,” Parliamentary Affairs: A Journal of Comparative Politics, 38:2 (Spring 1985), 180–91Google Scholar.

72 Behrens, , Conservative Party, 118Google Scholar. Cf. “Thatcher's Answer to Deficits: Tax!” Will, George, Los Angeles Times, 30 09 1983, sec. II, p. 7, col. 1Google Scholar; and Riddell, Peter, The Thatcher Government (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1984)Google Scholar.

73 Bowles, and Gintis, , “Crisis of Liberal Democratic Capitalism,” 6164Google Scholar.

74 See Medcalf, Linda and Dolbeare, Kenneth, Neopolitics (New York: Random House, 1985), 5051Google Scholar. Cf.Dolbeare, Kenneth, Democracy at Risk (Chatham, N.J.: Chatham House, 1984), xiixiiiGoogle Scholar.

75 Gamble, Andrew, Britain in Decline: Economic Policy, Political Strategy, and the British State (Boston: Beacon Press, 1981), 186–87Google Scholar.

76 This is the general argument of Bowles and Gintis, Adam Przeworski, and Immanuel Wallerstein and others. Cf.Slessarev, Helene, “Two Great Society Programs in an Age of Reaganomics” (Paper presented to the Midwest Political Science Convention, Chicago, 04 1984), 35Google Scholar.

77 Cf. British traditionalist Scruton, Roger, The Meaning of Conservatism (Totowa, N.J.: Barnes and Noble Books, 1980), 127–28Google Scholar, and American traditionalist Kirk, Russell, “The Problem of Community,” in his A Program for Conservatives (Chicago: Regnery, 1962), ch. 6, esp. 140–42Google Scholar.

78 This argument is developed by Fine, Ben and Harris, Laurence in The Peculiarities of the British Economy (London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1985)Google Scholar.

79 According to Federal Reserve Board data, the annual net acquisition of United States assets by foreigners has more than tripled in the period 1980–85. Cf. Andrew Gamble's distinction between “liberal political economy” and “national political economy” in Gamble, Britain In Decline, 133 et passim.

80 Cf.Wright, Patrick, On Living in an Old Country (London: Verso New Left Books, 1985)Google Scholar.

81 For a fuller exploration of the relationships between identity and politics, see Hoover, Kenneth, A Politics of Identity (Urbana: University of Illinois Press, 1976), esp. chs. 5, 6Google Scholar.

82 To use Stuart Hall's terms, there is a limit to how far the class-to-party nexus can be dissolved into a government-to-people conception without engendering a reaction for both economic and sociopsychological reasons. See Hall, ' thesis concerning “authoritarian populism”Google Scholar in Moving Right,” Socialist Review, no. 55 (1981), 113–37Google Scholar. Cf. Vigurie, The Establishment vs. the People; Gamble, , Britain in Decline, 145Google Scholar.