Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-13T03:48:34.225Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Cycle of Medieval Cathedrals – Explaining the Construction of Iberian Cathedrals through Economic Development

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2023

Paulo Reis Mourao*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics & NIPE, University of Minho, 4700 Braga, Portugal.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Iberian cathedrals are some of the most impressive religious buildings in Europe. Mostly erected between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries, they are also the outcome of regional phases of growth and development. This article discusses this period favourable to the building of religious structures in the Iberian Peninsula, considering local dynamism, the religiosity of adherents and stimuli from the economic development of the surrounding areas. Using models of spatial autocorrelation, we observed different results for the Portuguese dioceses and for the Spanish ones. Spanish dioceses, in particular, exerted competitive effects on surrounding dioceses, making the erection of new cathedrals close to a diocese with an old or a valued cathedral less probable. It was also observed that the dynamism of cathedral construction in a given diocese tended to be replicated in the closest dioceses between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries.

Type
Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Academia Europaea Ltd

Introduction

The construction of temples, especially involving considerable monumentality, is only possible when there is a combination of several factors. The next sections of this article will detail the main reasons behind the construction of medieval cathedrals in the Iberian Peninsula. However, these sections will also advance to two dimensions that have not been properly studied in this field. On the one hand, there is the importance of the local dynamics where we will test the hypothesis that places with an accumulation of religious buildings tend to preserve these buildings even in their expansion, depending on the interaction of cycles of local development and religious fervour. On the other hand, the dynamics of the neighbouring dioceses also have an observable influence. Basically, we intend to analyse whether the construction or expansion of cathedrals in a given diocese of the Iberian Peninsula motivated neighbouring dioceses to also build or expand their own cathedrals.

Historically, a cycle of cathedral construction existed in Galicia in approximately the twelfth and thirteenth centuries. The concentration of the main buildings on the northern coast of Portugal around the same period and the observation that most cathedrals in Catalonia had their starts separated by less than a century seem to suggest the importance of local dynamics in stimulating the emergence of large-scale religious centres.

This study is thus clearly innovative by bringing the advantages of spatial autocorrelation analysis to fields as diverse as economic history, the history of religion, the economics of public works and the economics of religion itself.

The first intention is therefore to test an innovative hypothesis: the construction of large religious buildings in the Iberian Peninsula between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries was the result of contagion effects from neighbouring regions in addition to local economic dynamics. In essence, we can consider that the combined presence of the three classic vectors – peaks in regional economic growth, a more intensely lived religiosity, and availability of materials and labour in nearby spaces – stimulated these communities to raise engineering works of this scope. However, as a result of these dynamics on the whole territory under observation, the presence of efforts to build these larger cathedrals in neighbouring communities/dioceses has not been tested with the detail here until now.

Several studies, such as those by Klotz (Reference Klotz1999) or Mourao (Reference Mourao2019), have found statistical significance in the ‘neighbourhood effect’ in real-world examples that range from the budgeting of public expenditures to the development of cultural and sports infrastructures. Obviously, such studies have concentrated on recent historical periods. Thus, the novelty of this article is twofold – both in terms of the historical period analysed and in the methodological resources used.

As a detailed examination of a period with relatively few approaches (the so-called ‘Late Middle Ages’ in the Iberian Peninsula), this investigation aims to contribute to the development of knowledge in three main areas:

  • To recognize how economic development in the Iberian Peninsula allowed the construction of religious centres with recognized monumentality.

  • To show how the presence of the three combined vectors (financial resources, religious fervour, and construction resources) throughout the various regions of the Iberian Peninsula motivated the construction of cathedrals.

  • To test how the ‘neighbourhood effect’, that is, the planning and construction of sees/cathedrals in a given diocese, was also a reflex of the spread of episcopal headquarters in the surrounding space.

The remaining work is structured as follows. The next section reviews the literature on the issue raised here. We revisit not only the cycles of development in the Iberian Peninsula but also cycles of accumulation of essential resources for building cathedrals. We also discuss the role of three effects subsequently tested: the relevance of the local dynamics, the religiosity of the residents and the influence coming from neighbouring dioceses. The third section empirically tests these hypotheses and the fourth section draws conclusions.

The Building of Cathedrals in the Iberian Peninsula – an Analysis from Spatial Autocorrelation to Contagion Effect

Defining the Focus of this Work – the Construction of a Cathedral in Iberian Territories

To study the spatial autocorrelation of cathedral construction, it is important to define from the start the concept of cathedrals to understand the reason for this focus. Thus, the notion of a cathedral, or cathedral church, is associated with a church where the main figure of the diocese – the Bishop – is entitled to a chair (cathedra). Although the modern concept appeared only in the fourteenth century, in approximately 1340 (Usher Reference Usher2012), our study collected observations for each diocese of the Iberian Peninsula that included the year of the construction or expansion of the most relevant church. Thus, for generalization purposes, this study will primarily observe the religious buildings – as well as the ensuing improvements – of structures considered diocesan headquarters in the Iberian Peninsula since the twelfth century.

Studies that accurately detail the differences between the expressions of Catholic religious architecture, namely, the differences between chapels, churches, basilicas, Sés or cathedrals, are those by authors such as Icher (Reference Icher1998).

Money, Religiosity and Endogenous Resources – Economic Development in the Iberian Peninsula between the Twelfth and Fifteenth Centuries as a Catalyst for the Construction of Cathedrals

The analysis of the economic and social history of the middle ages in the Iberian Peninsula has been developing at a slow pace. The works of Virginia Rau, Damião Peres, Magalhães Godinho and Oliveira Marques created a significant impulse throughout the twentieth century. Subsequently, figures such as Balard et al. (Reference Balard, Genet and Rouche1994), Fourquin (Reference Fourquin1969) and Álvarez Palenzuela (Reference Álvarez Palenzuela2003) generated an equivalent development in a more recent period.

In invoking such works here, we do so with a sense of construction. In reality, we cannot disconnect the development of any cycle of religious construction from the cycle of surrounding economic development. Financing a religious temple has always been a complex task; this is even more so if the temple is categorized as a ‘cathedral’. Regardless of the religious sect in question, in the wake of the findings by Icher (Reference Icher1998), Fourquin (Reference Fourquin1969) and Fonseca (Reference Fonseca1984), the construction of religious temples combines the following levels of effort/cost.

  • Efforts toward capital accumulation. Works for public use tend to be financially expensive, regardless of time and place. We restate here the thesis of Briscoe (Reference Briscoe1988) and Hutcheson (Reference Hutcheson1993), according to whom the most ‘grandiose’ works of any time (sometimes identified as ‘works of the regime’) occur in periods of capital accumulation in the surrounding communities that, in general, coincide with peak cycles in local and regional expansion. Thus, churches and cathedrals could only be raised when communities of believers perceived that there was an accumulation of capital. Although individual currencies have had their own cycles within each kingdom of the Iberian Peninsula, we follow the thesis of Valdés (Reference Valdés2014) that moments of greater economic development associated with the accumulation of resources were also periods with a greater dynamism in the circulation of registered money.

  • Local or regional availability of materials and labour. If today the professionalization of the civil engineering sector makes it possible for teams to travel around the globe, in the times associated with the data analysed here, the scope of religious temples implied the use of available labour among locals from the region (Icher Reference Icher1998). Such essential availability did not prevent the use of architects from other spaces or even from other countries or the use of imported architectural materials/details. However, the close (regional) availability of labour and construction materials would make any construction project of this magnitude more viable by reducing associated costs.

  • Religious efforts. These efforts of religious intentionality, according to Alashi (Reference Alashi2017), can be divided into three main directions: honour, worship and legacy. Thus, communities and leaders with the intention of building this type of religious space ‘feel’ the need to honour the divine (Lang et al. Reference Lang, Chan and Ragvald2005), to manifest the robustness of their faith and to leave this space for their heirs and for other believers (Alashi Reference Alashi2017).

We will now detail these main aspects of the economic history of the Iberian Peninsula between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries, explaining the construction of cathedrals.

Cycles of Currency Circulation in the Iberian Peninsula throughout the Late Middle Age

The relationship between monetary flows and religious purposes is not limited to the relationship between the dynamic circulation of currencies and the construction of religious temples. Other relationships are discussed in Valdés (Reference Valdés2014). In fact, Valdés states very explicitly that coins were used not only for alms (in response to feelings of mercy and charity) but also for donations and offerings to organizations. Thus, because ecclesiastical figures possessed both temporal rights (namely, the ability to collect taxes) and the ability to issue currency under real authorization (Olmos Reference Olmos2012), authors such as Duby (Reference Duby1990) list the possibility that the development of monetary flows – in the rest of Europe or in the Iberian Peninsula – promoted the building/reconstruction of religious temples.

In another work, Olmos (Reference Olmos2002) shows how the references to monetary values in the documents preserved from this period allow an association with economic and social dynamism in the surrounding area. Long periods were observed (especially in the eighth and ninth centuries) of great political and military instability in the Peninsula, where the consulted documents do not present references to monetary values; thus, economic and commercial relations were being carried out with much less significance or were only supported by direct exchange mechanisms. Olmos (Reference Olmos2002) shows how, during the tenth century, documents referring to ‘monetary units’ associated with cereal or livestock, such as wheat weights or sheep units, began to appear. The following centuries witnessed an intensification of the documentation of growing money flows – the coins minted in the Arab caliphs in the southern part of the Peninsula (the ‘parias’) entered circulation as valued coins in the Christian northern kingdoms that provided soldiers for wars between the caliphs, but there were also significant efforts to issue monetary ‘billons’ by Afonso VI and Afonso VII (already in the eleventh and twelfth centuries). The various moments of subsequent currency issuance (between the thirteenth and sixteenth centuries) can thus be assumed, in line with Puntoni (Reference Puntoni2019), as moments of monetary reform, which generally aimed to respond to the needs of most kingdoms, controlling inflationary tensions and the problems of seigniorage. Simultaneously, monetary issuances were moments used for propaganda (spreading the image of the king).

As Olmos (Reference Olmos2012) and Valdés (Reference Valdés2014) mention, the monetary flows in the Iberian Peninsula were conditioned by political instability, either between the several Christian and Arab states of the Peninsula or between the monarchs and the most powerful feudal lords, who had several tense episodes. The bourgeoisie’s own development, especially from the thirteenth century onward, has given special dynamism to monetary flows, inflationary tensions or even issues of monetary depreciation (Olmos Reference Olmos2012; Valdés Reference Valdés2014). Although quantitative studies on monetary flows in the various kingdoms of the Iberian Peninsula are scarce, several episodes can be interpreted as critical moments in monetary history. These monetary issues had become severe enough to induce public discussion among the various social classes and both secular and ecclesiastical authorities (Olmos Reference Olmos2012). Some of these moments are listed by Olmos (Reference Olmos2012): Catalonia (1118), Cortes de Benavente (1202), Aragon (1204), Alfonso X, Leiria (1254), the war between Afonso X and the Infante Sancho (1282, with inflation rates of approximately 500%), Brabant (1356) and Aragon (1372). In general, these moments of monetary crisis – revealing complex dynamics in the commercial markets of the Peninsula – were used to debate the authority to issue money, the ability to devalue the currency in progress, and the ban or admission of foreign currency circulation.

We do not intend to exhaust all possible discussion detailing the monetary struggles during this period in the different kingdoms and caliphs of the Peninsula. For this purpose, we suggest, in addition to previous studies, the works of Puntoni (Reference Puntoni2019) and Pastor (Reference Pastor2013).

Demographic Cycles in the Iberian Peninsula throughout the Late Middle Age

Demographics was a dimension correlated with monetary flows. Documents, whether concessionary in nature (such as ‘forais’/municipal documents of autonomy) or of monastic origin, show how the population grew in periods of relative political and military stability but also suffered significant falls not only in periods of political and administrative instability but also during epidemic crises, which were frequent.

The demographic rhythms of the Iberian Peninsula between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries are discussed in several works (García and Expósito Reference García and Expósito1983; Cruselles-Gómez Reference Cruselles-Gómez1999). In general, it is difficult to speak of a demographic expansion cycle characteristic of the entire peninsula. Cruselles-Gómez (Reference Cruselles-Gómez1999) also observes how demographic cycles were clearly more dynamic in urban areas than in rural areas. The reason is related to the proliferation of epidemics, most likely in urban areas, due to the quality of local accommodations and sanitation and high densities of human concentration (Fonseca Reference Fonseca1984). It should be noted that the construction of cathedrals – the current focus – was also concentrated in urban areas, as Icher (Reference Icher1998) noted, since the presence of the cathedral itself was a cause of significant urban dynamism. Authors such as Cruselles-Gómez (Reference Cruselles-Gómez1999) are convinced that visible demographic growth reinforced the economic and social dynamics of cities (and villages) on the Peninsula, generating labour circulation and the development of markets for various professions. However, the absence of a clear peninsular cycle of demographic expansion does not prevent the presence of cycles of demographic growth in certain periods in certain areas of the peninsula. We specifically refer to relatively extensive areas within each kingdom between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries. As population circulation was limited, periods of political and military stability in these large areas were most likely associated with demographic growth.

Cycles of Religiosity in the Iberian Peninsula throughout the Late Middle Age

The third factor in the erection of cathedrals – the religiosity of the classes of believers – also had particular dynamics in the Iberian Peninsula. Christians of the medieval Iberian Peninsula did not have the idiosyncratic crises that those in France, Central Europe or Italy had (with well-organized sectarian or heretical currents, as discussed by Peters Reference Peters1980, or Russell Reference Russell1963). However, religiosity crises, as well as some critical political episodes, occurred in the Iberian Peninsula, as detailed in works by Araújo (Reference Araújo2011) and Jesus (Reference Jesus2016). Such religious movements, managed by figures of the clergy and of secular authorities, drove the construction of places of worship. These places had the size and grandeur proportional to their centrality, to the dimension of the veneration flows of the invoked oragos (Icher Reference Icher1998) and to the commitment and prestige of local promoters (sometimes kings and landlords, and often clerics, namely, bishops).

The construction (or reconstruction) of cathedrals presented a multidimensional purpose – from the manifestation of wealth and ostentation for the purpose of expressing ideological and political supremacy to the consolidation of the surrounding space as a central location in economic, political, scientific and religious terms. Finally, supporting the building of the temple was seen from the perspective of citizens of the Middle Ages as an ‘investment’, not only in a greater cause (the spread of Christianity) but also in ensuring a personal return, both from a perspective of spiritual returns, such as indulgences and ‘perpetual masses’, and from the perspective of strategic valorization in the local and regional social community, in line with the arguments of Kolm and Ythier (Reference Kolm and Ythier2006).

From Spatial Autocorrelation to Contagion Analysis – Contagion, Mimicry or Cycles of Economic Expansion

From the above literature, we find three validated dimensions of local dynamics essential for the promotion of religious construction:

However, as Riccetti (Reference Riccetti2002) or Orme (Reference Orme2017) claim, in the cycle of expensive buildings, the following three factors become relevant:

  • the presence of an architectural culture;

  • the existence of a cycle of economic development extended to the entire surrounding space (in our case, the neighbouring dioceses);

  • the influence of competition or complementarity in the aforementioned space (that is, of the surrounding dioceses).

We will now explore these dimensions.

From Architectural Culture to the Regional Development Cycle and the Neighbourhood Effect

The construction of buildings is associated with the gathering of factors related to leadership and collective needs. As Riccetti (Reference Riccetti2002) notes, buildings that are constructed and upgraded are a source of additional future work, namely, reconstruction and expansion.

Economic development has also been discussed as one of the most powerful forces changing the social and economic structures of most agents in a region (Lopes Reference Lopes1988). With the increase in income generated and distributed in the same region, this economic cycle includes the possibility of accumulating the resources necessary to finance the construction of more expensive structures. Recent work validates this assumption, relating the economic growth of a region to a significant investment in civil construction projects (Lopes et al. Reference Lopes, Ruddock and Ribeiro2002). Therefore, we can expect that a cycle of construction or expansion (either of buildings for collective use or of buildings for private use) must reflect that previous cycle of economic growth.

However, even though the region is characterized by economic growth and the accumulation of resources, this does not mean that income and resources have been distributed equally among the subregions. The evidence shows regional inequalities exist for various reasons. Distribution processes tend to be more advantageous for some than for others, which will lead to the concentration of construction projects in one place at the expense of others. In addition, the ‘neighbourhood effect’ in construction investment can reflect a dimension of complementarity, when more is built in a region because there is also more new construction around, or a relation of substitutability, when due to internal competition, determined locals capture resources from neighbouring regions, increasing the volume of their own construction and decreasing the volume of construction in the neighbouring regions. Works that address these dual dimensions in the ‘neighbourhood effect’ include those by Martín Martín (Reference Martín Martín2013), who authored a relevant study showing how bishops tended to interfere closely in neighbourhood political issues in the Iberian Peninsula during the Late Middle Age. The next section will describe our empirical effort to test this dimension of spatial autocorrelation in the construction of Iberian cathedrals through the Middle Ages.

Empirical Section

Empirical Model

Based upon the theoretical discussion, our empirical model will explain the construction of cathedrals in the Iberian Peninsula between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries considering the following three assumptions.

  • The principle of maintaining building upkeep, by which existing buildings tend to ask for renovations and improvements (although with decreasing marginal value, following Olmos Reference Olmos2012 or Riccetti Reference Riccetti2002);

  • The principle of centre–periphery competition in regional economics, by which existing structures of capital located at a centre tend to attract investments from neighbouring areas (Orme Reference Orme2017);

  • The mimetism effect, by which the abundance of inputs in a given diocese and in their neighbouring areas will motivate the construction of religious infrastructure (Araújo Reference Araújo2011).

Therefore, the likelihood of a given diocese constructing/expanding a cathedral is identified as y*. It is modelled as a function of neighbouring diocese activity (Neighbour) and of the existing structure of religious buildings (x). We follow the modelling established by Arima (Reference Arima2016).

Therefore, we will define y* i = αNeighbour i + x i β + e i . Assuming agents are value-maximizers (i.e., they will construct a cathedral if the construction is worth the effort), the probability of observing cathedral construction (y = 1) can be written as:

(1) $$\matrix{ {P\left( {y = 1{\rm{|}}x,Neighbour} \right) = P\left( {y* > 0{\rm{|}}x,Neighbour} \right)} \hfill \cr {\quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad = P\left( {e > - \alpha Neighbour - {\bf{x\beta }}{\rm{|}}x,Neighbour} \right)} \hfill \cr {\quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad = {\bf{\Phi }}\left( {{\bf{\alpha }}Neighbour + {\bf{x\beta }}} \right)} \hfill \cr } $$
(2) $${y_i} = \left\{ {\matrix{ {0, {\text {if}} \; y * < 0} \hfill \cr {1, {\text {if}} \; y * > 0} \hfill \cr } } \right.$$

where α is the vector of coefficients associated with Neighbour and β the vector of coefficients associated with the controls x. Following Arima (Reference Arima2016), we assume that the unobservable term e is normally distributed; then, the probability of a cathedral’s construction or expansion is given as P(y = 1|x, Neighbour) = P(y* > 0|x, Neighbour) = P(e > −αNeighbour|x, Neighbour) = Φ(αNeighbour + ). Φ(.) is the cumulative normal density function, which primarily leads to a nonspatial probit model.

We use the probit model with spatial dependency designed by Smith and LeSage (Reference Smith, LeSage, LeSage and Kelley2004). Following Arima (Reference Arima2016), this model is more appropriate for our observations in dioceses/religious areas because ‘[…] spatial dependencies are ascribed to occur between regions, not between individual observations. In their model implementation, SLS used county-level observations grouped by states (i.e., regions) and spatial dependencies were assigned between states instead of between individual counties.’

Therefore, following Smith and LeSage (Reference Smith, LeSage, LeSage and Kelley2004) and Arima (Reference Arima2016), we write our empirical model predicting the construction of a cathedral in a given century between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries as follows:

(3) $$y{^*_i} = \alpha Neighbo{r_{ij}} + {{\bf{x}}_{ij}}{\bf{\beta }} + \theta j + {e_{ij}}$$

with

$${\theta _j} = \rho \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^m {w_{jk}}{\theta _k} + {\mu _j}$$

In equation (3), θ j : j = 1, …, m is the effect of the neighbouring dioceses and may be defined as a spatial autoregressive process, where w jk is the weight reflecting the degree of spatial proximity between dioceses j and k. ρ is the parameter that reflects the overall degree of spatial dependency between dioceses – we will give a particular focus to this parameter in further estimations. The idiosyncratic error (e ij ) is assumed to be normally distributed, conditional on θ. μ j is also assumed to be normally distributed.

Following Mourao and Vilela (Reference Mourao and Vilela2020), we can think of the previous models as binary-dependent variable models based on the usual spatial Durbin model:

(4) $${y_{it}} = \alpha + \rho {W_i}{y_{it}} + {X_{it}}\beta + {W_i}{X_{it}}\gamma + {e_{it}}$$

We also identify αNeighbour ij in equation (3) as ${W_i}{X_{it}}\gamma $ in equation (4), and therefore, y* also depends upon the cumulative value of religious cathedrals in the neighbouring areas. Therefore, y* can be modelled as

$$y{^*_i} = {\mu _j} + {W_i}{X_{it}}\gamma \; + {{\bf{X}}_{ij}}{\bf{\beta }} + \;\rho \mathop \sum \limits_{k = 1}^m {w_{jk}}{\theta _k} + {e_{ij}}$$

Data and Sources

To move forward in this effort, we construct two major variables:

  • A variable that signals information about the existence of construction or significant changes in the main cathedral in each diocese (Olmos Reference Olmos2012; Valdés Reference Valdés2014). This binary variable has been represented by y* i ;

  • A variable with the accumulated value of religious heritage associated with each diocese (Araújo Reference Araújo2011; Riccetti Reference Riccetti2002). We will consider this variable as a proxy for X i.

Thus, we established each set of 50 years between 1100 and 1500 as a temporal unit, and we observed the historical dioceses of the Iberian Peninsula as a spatial unit. This means that dioceses created after a given date do not appear before that date, as necessary for methodological rigour. For example, the diocese of Majorca was only considered after 1237, the year of its emergence from the diocese of Barcelona. In terms of time units, the use of (long) periods of 50 years is explained by the following motivations. First, the ‘construction cycle’ is a long cycle even if we consider recent investments or cycles for public works (Lopes et al. Reference Lopes, Ruddock and Ribeiro2002). As authors such as Icher (Reference Icher1998) or Araújo (Reference Araújo2016) point out, the construction of cathedrals occurred over long periods, sometimes involving more than a century between the beginning and the conclusion of the initial project. Second, the existence of accumulated dynamics both in the inputs that we analysed in the second section (dynamics of local and regional markets, demographics and religiosity) and in the evidenced output (the construction of the cathedral) is supported by long cycles, in line with the studies by Riccetti (Reference Riccetti2002).

The work of identifying these dioceses was thus long. It was based on several sources, from local archives to historical, religious and architectural literature (Barreira Reference Barreira1937; Ferreira Reference Ferreira1957; Gaspar Reference Gaspar1979; Guerreiro Reference Guerreiro1982; Costa Reference Costa1998; Azevedo Reference Azevedo1985; Navascues Reference Navascues2010; Sobrino Reference Sobrino2019). The existence of construction or significant modifications in the main cathedral of each diocese was identified by a binary variable. We mark this as 1, thus, the half-century when each cathedral began its construction or when the sources identified a significant expansion effort. As a significant expansion effort, we considered structural changes, the introduction or extension of any of the five structural elements in cathedrals of this period (Guerreiro Reference Guerreiro1982; Navascues Reference Navascues2010): vaults, chapels, naves, transepts and towers. We identify this variable as (Y it ), which should not be confused with the variable Y*. In terms of descriptive statistics, Y it has the following values: 1152 observations, with a mean of 0.487, a standard deviation of 0.722, a maximum of 1000, and a minimum of 0.000.

The accumulated value of the religious heritage of each cathedral in each diocese results from the accumulated value of Y it . Therefore, for each period t, we identify this accumulated value as X it . In terms of descriptive statistics, X it has the following values: 1152 observations, with a mean of 3.114, a standard deviation of 3.690, a maximum of 17.000, and a minimum of 0.000.

The effort we put into building these variables, while honest, is not without its limitations. Ideally, to test our hypotheses, we should have, for each year and for each diocese, a monetized value of the construction or expansion effort of each cathedral. Such information would allow us to generate much more in-depth measures, including the surrounding economic dynamics as well as a much more detailed indication of the valuation of other ‘inputs’: demographic dynamics and religiosity. However, given the available sources and data, such estimates are not yet possible for all our observed cathedrals and dioceses.

Results and Discussion

Table 1 shows our results for the set of dioceses observed in the Iberian Peninsula.

Table 1. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Iberian Peninsula, 1100–1500).

We preferred to divide the estimates in equation (3) by centuries to detail how the reaction of each diocese was different from century to century. In the first row, we have the estimated coefficients for the spatial autocorrelation parameter ρ. Thus, it is possible to observe that the dynamic capacity of neighbouring regions influenced the dynamics of religious construction in the dioceses of the Iberian Peninsula and had its period of greatest significance between the years 1200–1300 and 1300–1400. Between 1100 and 1200, we noticed that the dynamics of religious cathedral construction were mainly influenced by the existence of accumulated value in religious buildings (parameter β). The statistical significance found for all the estimated coefficients of parameter β (positive parameters) over the period reveals that the local dynamics of each diocese is the main factor affecting the construction or expansion of the cathedral. This perspective is convergent with the perspective of Icher (Reference Icher1998). On the other hand, we cannot fail to mention that the estimated value for ϒ reveals, for periods from 1200 onward, a sense of ‘spatial competition’ between neighbouring regions; the negative sign indicates that the greater the accumulated value of religious heritage in the surrounding dioceses, the expected likelihood of building or expanding a cathedral in a given diocese is less, for most spaces in the Iberian Peninsula. The values of log-likelihood as well as R 2 suggest that the model estimated for the period between 1400 and 1500 has a higher quality than the models estimated for the remaining periods.

After discussing Table 1, we divide Iberian dioceses by considering them as Portuguese (if belonging to the kingdom of Portugal) or Spanish (if belonging to the kingdoms of Castile-Léon, Navarre or Aragon). We opted for this division to avoid generalist insights that would happen if we had not done this methodological step. In line with the arguments of diverse authors (Fonseca Reference Fonseca1984; Navascues Reference Navascues2010), given the autonomy of individual spaces – even in ecclesiastical terms – additional reasons arise for justifying this division.

Table 2 shows the estimated coefficients for equation (3) but only considers the data for the Portuguese dioceses. Some differences can already be found in light of the results shown in Table 1. First, the Portuguese dioceses only felt the effect of spatial correlation from 1300 onward. In particular, from 1400 onward, the dynamics of religious construction in the surrounding spaces stimulated religious construction in each diocese, with the curious aspect being that here, unlike the estimated parameter for dioceses across the Iberian Peninsula (Table 1), the estimated parameter for the Portuguese period between 1400 and 1500 is positive and significant. This evidence (ϒ positive and significant) indicates a complementary relationship between the religious capital accumulated in the neighbouring dioceses and the construction or expansion of the cathedral in each Portuguese diocese (Fonseca Reference Fonseca1984). It should be noted that this period in the Portuguese space is one of clear economic and demographic growth in most years as a result of the centrality that the country gained from the dynamics of sea voyages and Iberian discoveries. Once again, the estimated β values were significant and positive, indicating that dioceses with accumulated capital in religious constructions tended to carry out more modifications/expansions than spaces with less accumulation of religious capital.

Table 2. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Portugal, 1100–1499).

Table 3 shows the estimation of equation (3) only for Spanish dioceses in the period under analysis. The differences with the results achieved for the Portuguese dioceses are notable, especially in the values estimated for ϒ. These values were estimated to be significant and negative, which shows that, in Spanish dioceses, a spatial competition effect persisted between neighbouring dioceses. The more expanded a particular cathedral was, the lower the expected probability of the construction of religious buildings in neighbouring dioceses in the observed periods. The remaining parameters under observation – ρ and β – were in line with the results of the previous tables. Therefore, there were particularly positive and significant ρ values after 1200, showing that works in neighbouring dioceses led to significant development in each diocese in question. This result converged with our central hypothesis; that is, the influx of expressive inputs/resources in the various regions tended to produce more frequent ‘outputs’ in the set of analysed regions. These results also follow Olmos (Reference Olmos2012) and Valdés (Reference Valdés2014). Once again, dioceses with more highly valued accumulated capital tended to be more likely to have more religious construction works.

Table 3. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Spain, 1100–1499).

Conclusion

The building of collective-use structures traditionally involves high costs, be it the construction of buildings representing state or local powers, sports stadiums or pavilions, living quarters or religious infrastructure. Thus, this work focused on the economics of religious constructions. The focus of such an analysis was the Christian kingdoms of the Iberian Peninsula between the twelfth and fifteenth centuries.

Thus, we intended, in concrete terms, to determine whether the construction of buildings such as cathedrals in each observed diocese was driven by the traditional hypothesis about the dynamics of religious capital accumulation in the region. However, in addition to this hypothesis, we also intended to assess the pressure of developments in the surrounding region in the construction of cathedrals or in their expansion; in a simple way, we intended to assess whether the construction of neighbouring cathedrals influenced (positively or negatively) the probability of a diocese building its own cathedral or expanding the existing one.

For this purpose, after the construction of a detailed database with specific sources, we evaluated not only the effects of spatial autocorrelation present in our data but also the dynamics of local religious construction. Thus, the results were separated within the Iberian Peninsula into the Portuguese dioceses and the Spanish dioceses, to explore in greater detail.

Through spatial autocorrelation analysis, we observed different outcomes for Spanish dioceses than for Portuguese dioceses. For Spanish dioceses, we observed a negative ‘neighbourhood effect’ if neighbouring dioceses had more valuable buildings. Thus, the presence of an older cathedral or one with more significant accumulated changes tended to decrease the likelihood of new cathedral construction in a nearby diocese. In contrast, for the Portuguese dioceses observed in the late Middle Ages, the referred effect (associated with parameter ϒ) had statistically significant positive estimated coefficients, validating the presence of positive spillovers from the accumulated value of temples in neighbouring dioceses. Across the diversity of the peninsular dioceses, the contagion effect of dynamism (associated with the traditional parameter ρ) was positive and statistically significant, indicating that the dynamism in a diocese was replicated in neighbouring dioceses, which leads us to identify religious elements as special factors affecting construction, in addition to the cycles of economic development of the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries in the Iberian Peninsula.

These results are pioneering in the literature on the economic history of the Middle Ages in the Iberian Peninsula. They are innovative not only in the use of spatial autocorrelation analysis, which has not been tested for this approach thus far, but also in revealing the religious history of the Iberian Peninsula, showing the correlation between local economic development and the building of its medieval cathedrals.

We intend to expand this analysis to more medieval European dioceses and to detail the effects for each Iberian kingdom. We also intend to expand this effort to analyse the construction of primary mosques in the administrative divisions within the (Arab) caliphates of the Iberian Peninsula. We additionally intend to explore the possibility of monetizing religious buildings; therefore, we intend to identify the value of the (monetary) costs associated with the effort of constructing each cathedral. Finally, the state of the regional economy is broadly relevant to the potential for cathedral-building projects, and this aspect is considered a promising further avenue, namely, by adding the number of recorded fairs or demographic estimations as soon as appropriate values can be identified for the observed dioceses.

Acknowledgements

This paper is financed by National Funds of the FCT – Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology within the project ‘UIDB/03182/2020’.

The author acknowledges the suggestions provided by two anonymous reviewers on a previous version of this research. Any remaining limitations are exclusively those of the author.

About the Author

Paulo Reis Mourao was born in Vila Real (Portugal). He is the author of several scientific articles indexed by ISI Thompson and of some books. His works are focused on Economics, Public Finance, Social Economics and Sports Economics. He often appears in national and international media, commenting on social and economic issues. Paulo Mourao has been awarded several times for his scientific works.

References

Alashi, A (2017) Gothic vs Romanesque style research. Researchgate document. 10.13140/RG.2.2.18423.11682.Google Scholar
Álvarez Palenzuela, V (coord.) (2003) Historia de la Europa. [History of Europe.] Barcelona: Ariel.Google Scholar
Araújo, A (2016) Vida e Ação dos Franciscanos em Lamego. [Life and Action of the Franciscans in Lamego.] Minerva, Lamego.Google Scholar
Araújo, M (2011) Heresia, poder político e lógicas corporativas na Península Ibérica (séc. XIII–XV). [Heresy, political power and corporate logic in the Iberian Peninsula (13th–15th century).] Thesis. University of Brasilia.Google Scholar
Arima, Y (2016) A spatial probit econometric model of land change: the case of infrastructure development in western Amazonia, Peru. PLoS One 11(3), e0152058.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Azevedo, C (1985) Igrejas de Portugal. Difel. [Churches of Portugal.] Bertrand: Lisboa Google Scholar
Balard, M, Genet, J-P and Rouche, M (1994) A Idade Média no Ocidente: dos Bárbaros ao Renascimento. [Middle Age in West: From Barbarians to Renaissance.] Lisboa: D. Quixote.Google Scholar
Barreira, J (1937) Estudos de arte. História de uma catedral (Desenhos de Manuel Barreira). [Art Studies – History of a Cathedral (Paintings of Manuel Barreira).] Seara Nova, Lisboa.Google Scholar
Briscoe, G (1988) The Economics of the Construction Industry. London: Batsford.Google Scholar
Costa, L (1998) A Sé de Braga. Algumas breves notícias sobre a catedral de Santa Maria. [Braga’s Cathedral – some short news about Saint Mary’s Cathedral.]. APPACDM (Braga)Google Scholar
Cruselles-Gómez, E (1999) La Población de la Ciudad de Valencia en los Siglos XIV y XV. [The population of Valencia in the centuries XIV and XV.] Revista Historia Medieval X, 4584.Google Scholar
Duby, G (1990) Guerreiros e Camponeses. [Warriors and peasants.] Editorial Estampa, Lisboa.Google Scholar
Ferreira, JA (Mgr.) (1957) A arte em Portugal. 1 - Porto. (…). Catedral, Cedofeita, S. Francisco e Santa Clara. [The Art in Portugal 1 – Porto. Cathedral, Cedofeita, S Francisco and St Clara.] Marques Abreu Editor.Google Scholar
Fonseca, LA d (1984) La Cristandad Medieval, Historia Universal EUNSA, tomo 5. [The Medieval Christianity. Historia Universal EUNSA, 5.] Pamplona. EUNSA.Google Scholar
Fourquin, G (1969) Histoire Économique de l’Occident Médiéval. Paris: Armand Colin.Google Scholar
García, A and Expósito, A (1983 ) Demografía medieval: modelos de poblamiento en la Extremadura castellana a mediados del siglo XIII. [Medieval demography – models of settlement in Castella’s Extremadura during the 13th century.] Studia Historica, Historia Medieval I, 113148.Google Scholar
Gaspar, JG (1979) Catedral de Aveiro. História e arte. [Aveiro’s Cathedral – history and art.] Paróq. De Na. Sra. Da Glória, Aveiro.Google Scholar
Guerreiro, DA (1982) A catedral de Évora. Arte e história. [Evora’s cathedral. Art and history.] Guia para o visitante (resumo em língua francesa). Edições Sé de Évora, Évora.Google Scholar
Hutcheson, JM (1993) The life cycle economics of buildings. Property Management 11(4), 308313. https://doi.org/10.1108/02637479310048105 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Icher, F (1998) Building the Great Cathedrals. New York: Harry N. Abrams.Google Scholar
Jesus, TS (2016) Heresias Medievais Na Península Ibérica (Séc. Xi-xvi): um Debate Historiográfico Preliminar. [Medieval heresies in the Iberian Peninsle (centuries XI-XVI) – a preliminary debate.] VIII Encontro Estadual de História. Feira de Santana, Baia.Google Scholar
Klotz, S (1999) Ökonometrische Modelle mit raumstruktureller Autokorrelation – Eine kurze Einführung/Econometric Models with Spatial Autocorrelation – An Introductory Survey. Journal of Economics and Statistics (Jahrbuecher fuer Nationaloekonomie und Statistik) 218(1-2), 168196.Google Scholar
Kolm, S and Ythier, J (2006) Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Vol. 1. New York: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Lang, G, Chan, S and Ragvald, L (2005) Folk temples and the Chinese religious economy. Interdisciplinary Journal of Research on Religion 1(4).Google Scholar
Lopes, AS (1988) Dimensão e funções dos centros urbanos: um apontamento de economia urbana. [Dimension and functions of urban centres: an indication of urban economy.] Estudos de Economia VIII(2), 173180.Google Scholar
Lopes, J, Ruddock, L and Ribeiro, FL (2002) Investment in construction and economic growth in developing countries. Building Research & Information 30(3), 152159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martín Martín, J (2013) Problemas de límites en las diócesis vecinas de Castilla y Portugal en la Edad Media. Das begrenzte Papsttum. Berlin, Boston: De Gruyter. doi:https://doi.org/10.1515/9783110308020.169 Google Scholar
Mourao, P (2019) ‘Keeping up with the (Portuguese) Joneses’—a study on the spatial dependence of municipal expenditure. Applied Economics 51(34), 36893709. doi: 10.1080/00036846.2019.1581914 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mourao, P and Vilela, C (2020) No country for old men? The multiplier effects of pensions in Portuguese municipalities. Journal of Pensions Economics and Finance 19(2), 247261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Navascues, P (2010) Catedrales De España (Atlas Ilustrado). Tikal Susaeta, Madrid.Google Scholar
Olmos, J (2002) El nacimiento de la moneda en Castilla. De la moneda prestada a la moneda propia. I Jornadas Científica sobre Documentación jurídicoadministrativa, económico-financiera y judicial del reino castellano-leonés, siglos X-XIII, Madrid, Universidad Compluytense, 2002, pp. 303–346.Google Scholar
Olmos, J (2012). La Moneda Medieval: Fuentes Documentales Para Su Estudio. Conference Proceedings ‘La Moneda: Investigación numismática y fuentes archivísticas’. MadridGoogle Scholar
Orme, N (2017) The History of England’s Cathedrals. Toronto: Pontifical Institute of Mediaeval Studies Google Scholar
Pastor, B (2013) A Casa da Moeda do Porto na Alfândega Velha – Bases para uma proposta de interpretação patrimonial de um recurso turístico a desenvolver. [The Mint of Porto at Alfândega Velha - Bases for a proposal of heritage interpretation of a tourist resource to be developed.] Thesis. Instituto Ciencias Sociais, University of Minho, Braga.Google Scholar
Peters, E (ed). (1980) Heresy and Authority in Medieval Europe. University of Pennsylvania Press. Retrieved 3 September 2020, from http://www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt3fh8qt CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Puntoni, P (2019) Da Libra ao Real: Sobre A Formação do Sistema Monetário Português (1185-1580). Revista de História (São Paulo) (178), a08917. Epub 25 March 2019. https://doi.org/10.11606/issn.2316-9141.rh.2019.141351id> Google Scholar
Riccetti, L (2002) Le mani sull’Opera. Vescovo, Capitolo e Comune, tra devozione civica, finanziamento e gestione del patrimonio dell’Opera del Duomo di Orvieto fino al 1421. Nuova Rivista storica 86(1), 49110.Google Scholar
Russell, J (1963) Interpretations of the origins of medieval heresy. Mediaeval Studies 25, 2653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, TE and LeSage, JP (2004) A Bayesian probit model with spatial dependencies. In LeSage, JP and Kelley, P (eds), Advances in Econometrics: Spatial and Spatiotemporal Econometrics. Oxford: Elsevier, pp. 127160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobrino, M (2019) Catedrales: Las biografías desconocidas de los grandes templos de España (Historia). La Esfera de los Libros, S.L. MadridGoogle Scholar
Usher, R (2012) Churches and cathedrals. In Protestant Dublin, 1660–1760. Early Modern History: Society and Culture. London: Palgrave Macmillan. https://doi.org/10.1057/9780230362161_3 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valdés, A (2014) Uso y reutilización de la moneda en la Edad Media en el Noroeste Peninsular (II). Numisma 143172.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Iberian Peninsula, 1100–1500).

Figure 1

Table 2. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Portugal, 1100–1499).

Figure 2

Table 3. Estimations of the spatial autocorrelation model (Spain, 1100–1499).