Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T08:18:45.854Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Banking on cooperation: an evolutionary analysis of microfinance loan repayment behaviour

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 December 2020

Stefan Gehrig*
Affiliation:
Human Behaviour and Cultural Evolution Group, Centre for Ecology and Conservation, College of Life and Environmental Sciences, University of Exeter, Penryn Campus, Cornwall TR10 9FE, UK
Alex Mesoudi
Affiliation:
Human Behaviour and Cultural Evolution Group, Centre for Ecology and Conservation, College of Life and Environmental Sciences, University of Exeter, Penryn Campus, Cornwall TR10 9FE, UK
Shakti Lamba*
Affiliation:
Human Behaviour and Cultural Evolution Group, Centre for Ecology and Conservation, College of Life and Environmental Sciences, University of Exeter, Penryn Campus, Cornwall TR10 9FE, UK
*
*Corresponding authors. Stefan Gehrig, e-mail: stefan-gehrig@t-online.de; Shakti Lamba, e-mail: s.lamba@exeter.ac.uk
*Corresponding authors. Stefan Gehrig, e-mail: stefan-gehrig@t-online.de; Shakti Lamba, e-mail: s.lamba@exeter.ac.uk

Abstract

Microfinance is an economic development tool that provides loans to low-income borrowers to stimulate economic growth and reduce financial hardship. Lenders typically require joint liability, where multiple borrowers share the responsibility of repaying a group loan. We propose that this lending practice creates a cooperation dilemma similar to that faced by humans and other organisms in nature across many domains. This could offer a real-world test case for evolutionary theories of cooperation from the biological sciences. In turn, such theories could provide new insights into loan repayment behaviour. We first hypothesise how group loan repayment efficacy should be affected by mechanisms of assortment from the evolutionary literature on cooperation, i.e. common ancestry (kin selection), prior interaction (reciprocity), partner choice, similarity of tags, social learning, and ecology and demography. We then assess selected hypotheses by reviewing 41 studies from 32 countries on micro-borrowers’ loan repayment, evaluating which characteristics of borrowers are associated with credit repayment behaviour. Surprisingly, we find that kinship is mostly negatively associated with repayment efficacy, but prior interaction and partner choice are both more positively associated. Our work highlights the scope of evolutionary theory to provide systematic insight into how humans respond to novel economic institutions and interventions.

Type
Review
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020 Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Evolutionary Human Sciences

Media summary: The paper embeds an empirical review of group loan repayment in microfinance into an evolution-of-cooperation framework.

1. Introduction

Microfinance is a globally widespread economic development tool that aims to provide financial services to people from low-income backgrounds. One of its cornerstones is the provision of small, short-term loans which enable borrowers to invest in new income-generating activities (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Brau & Woller, Reference Brau and Woller2004; Cull & Morduch, Reference Cull and Morduch2018). Conventional lending by banks requires loan-takers to provide material collateral, such as a house or land, that the bank holds as a guarantee and will confiscate if the borrower fails to repay the initial loan. In contrast, microfinance institutions (MFIs) offer loans to individuals who cannot obtain loans from mainstream banking services because they cannot provide the required securities and have no formal credit rating.

A common feature of MFIs is to provide loans to a group of borrowers who are jointly liable to repay it. This has been called joint liability lending (JLL): borrowers are mutually responsible for each other's repayment and must collectively make up any shortfall in repayment if other group members are unable or unwilling to repay. Typically, if the group does not achieve repayment, all group members are barred access to future loans from the micro-lending programme. The typical economic rationale is that JLL can exploit local social networks and ‘peer pressure’ to boost repayment (Besley & Coate, Reference Besley and Coate1995; Ghatak & Guinnane, Reference Ghatak and Guinnane1999).

This interdependence of group members in JLL creates a cooperative dilemma, because the responsibility of collective loan repayment to the lender, as well as the potential benefit of loan renewal in case of success, is shared by all group members. Here we build on Lamba (Reference Lamba, Gibson and Lawson2014) and propose that group-based lending provides a model system to test the extent to which evolutionary theories on cooperation from the biological sciences apply to contemporary human societies. Since JLL participants span the globe, this model system allows us to test evolutionary theories of cooperation in a diverse range of human populations within the same natural context. Conversely, evolutionary theories of cooperation from the biological sciences can potentially explain patterns of repayment observed in the microfinance sector.

In this paper, we (a) describe the cooperative dilemma presented by JLL (Section 2), (b) outline evolutionary mechanisms of cooperation and generate specific hypotheses about how these mechanisms may operate in the context of JLL (Section 3), (c) review empirical studies on microloan repayment to empirically assess whether their findings are qualitatively consistent with the evolutionary hypotheses that we derive for JLL (Section 4) and (d) discuss the results of the review and their implications for evolutionary biology and economics (Section 5). By connecting literatures from development economics and the evolutionary sciences that have to date developed separately, we identify a new model system, i.e. JLL, that can be used to test evolutionary theory on cooperation across a wide cross-section of humanity. Our study generates a range of questions, hypotheses and study designs that warrant further investigation by evolutionary biologists and economists.

2. Microfinance and the cooperative dilemma in joint liability lending

Microfinance describes a bundle of financial services of which the most common is microcredit, the aim of which is to provide loans to small-scale entrepreneurs to reduce financial poverty and spur economic growth. In recent decades, microfinance has grown and spread across the globe (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Brau & Woller, Reference Brau and Woller2004; Cull & Morduch, Reference Cull and Morduch2018). There are estimated to be over 200 million recipients of microfinance worldwide, three-quarters of whom are women, served by more than 3,000 MFIs, which include nongovernmental organisations, commercial banks and other financial institutions (Microcredit Summit Campaign, 2015). More than half of microfinance clients are living in ‘extreme poverty’ as defined by international poverty lines or the relative income position in their home country. Despite years of enthusiasm and success stories among practitioners and observers, rigorous evaluations of the impact of microcredit provision have at best shown modest causal effects on business and income growth (A. Banerjee et al., Reference Banerjee, Karlan and Zinman2015; Duvendack et al., Reference Duvendack, Palmer-Jones, Copestake, Hooper, Loke and Rao2011; Meager, Reference Meager2019) and debates about the evidence continue (Dahal & Fiala, Reference Dahal and Fiala2020). Nevertheless, many scholars suggest that microfinance helps in ‘managing the ups and downs of lives in poverty and near-poverty, even when poverty persists’ (Cull & Morduch, Reference Cull and Morduch2018, p. 551) by improving household finances and smoothing consumption. This contributes to the well-being of borrowers, albeit not triggering transformative economic growth (although others point towards the potential harmful social consequences of microcredit, e.g. S. B. Banerjee & Jackson, Reference Banerjee and Jackson2017; Hulme, Reference Hulme2000).

The microfinance movement in its current form as an entrepreneur-targeted development intervention was initiated in the 1970s by the Grameen Bank in Bangladesh. One of the major innovations was the introduction of JLL in small groups, which is still central to many MFIs and often seen as key to their success (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Hermes & Lensink, Reference Hermes and Lensink2007). In the JLL model, individuals receive loans in groups and are liable for repayment as a collective: only when the group loan is fully repaid will the individual group members have access to future loans and avoid other penalties. This allows lending to customers who have little material collateral and lack formal records of creditworthiness. By allocating repayment responsibilities to a group rather than an individual, the JLL contract creates an incentive for group members to look after each other's financial investments and activities in order to maintain their own access to future loans. Consequently, information and enforcement duties of mainstream lenders are transferred to the borrowers themselves (Besley & Coate, Reference Besley and Coate1995; Ghatak & Guinnane, Reference Ghatak and Guinnane1999; Stiglitz, Reference Stiglitz1990), replacing material collateral with social collateral. As Armendáriz and Morduch (Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010, p. 13) write, ‘the classic Grameen contract takes advantage of clients’ close ties within their communities’. However, this shared responsibility for repaying a collective loan creates a cooperative dilemma. Each borrower is better off not repaying their share of the loan and letting other group members repay it. Yet if all borrowers do not repay their share, then the group will fail to repay the collective loan and will face penalties including being blocked from future loans. Therefore, in order to repay the collective loan, it is essential for group members to cooperate, by paying in full their own share and by helping other group members to pay their share.

Figure 1 sketches the stylised timeline of a typical loan cycle and Table 1 describes the decisions taken by group members at each step. These decisions all feed into the cooperative dilemma underlying JLL as there is conflict between the group goal (group's repayment) and the individual goal (maximise own income). For example, the decision of a borrower regarding how to spend the loan, whether to monitor others’ investments, how many group meetings to attend or whether to truthfully report the outcomes of one's own project, can all affect whether the loan is fully repaid at the end of the loan cycle.

Figure 1. The stylised timeline of a typical joint liability loan cycle from loan disbursement by the microfinance institution (MFI) to the decision of the MFI about loan renewal or exclusion from credit, which is conditional on borrowers’ repayment behaviour. At each stage framed by a rectangle, borrowers can be thought of as taking an action and this action can affect the group's repayment outcome (see Table 1).

Table 1. Description of typical stages of a microfinance loan cycle with joint liability lending (see Figure 1) and how group members’ decisions at these stages affect the cooperative dilemma.

Despite the cooperative dilemma at the heart of JLL, repayment rates of Grameen Bank and other MFIs employing the JLL model have been high, often above 95% (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Brau & Woller, Reference Brau and Woller2004; Cull & Morduch, Reference Cull and Morduch2018; Hossain, Reference Hossain1988). Yet there is considerable variation in repayment rates across time and space. For example, JLL credit defaults temporarily rose from around 2% to 90% in the 2010 Indian microfinance crisis (Haldar & Stiglitz, Reference Haldar and Stiglitz2016). There is also variation in the reported success of the JLL model relative to individual liability micro-lending. In some contexts, empirical studies report that JLL leads to better loan repayment than when individuals are solely liable for the loan (Carpena et al., Reference Carpena, Cole, Shapiro and Zia2013; Gomez & Santor, Reference Gomez and Santor2008; Khandker, Reference Khandker2012; Mahmud, Reference Mahmud2019), while in others there is no difference (Attanasio et al., Reference Attanasio, Augsburg, De Haas, Fitzsimons and Harmgart2015; Giné & Karlan, Reference Giné and Karlan2014). This variation in repayment rates and the variable success of the JLL model is difficult to explain.

We suggest that variation in repayment rates and therefore the success of JLL may be linked to whether individuals can solve the cooperative dilemma underlying it. If this is the case, then we expect that factors facilitating cooperation amongst group members should have a positive outcome on repayment efficacy. Here we propose and test whether these factors may be the same as those proposed to facilitate the evolution of cooperation in nature as identified in the biological sciences.

The notion that repayment under JLL is a public good, requiring cooperation and collective action, has been put forward by some social scientists (Anthony, Reference Anthony2005; Guttman, Reference Guttman2007; Sabin & Reed-Tsochas, Reference Sabin and Reed-Tsochas2018; van Bastelaer & Leathers, Reference van Bastelaer and Leathers2006), but it is not always treated explicitly as such in group-lending models. For example, the seminal economic model of group lending by Besley and Coate (Reference Besley and Coate1995) assumes that borrowers employ sanctions to oblige other group members to repay their shares, making repayment the self-interested choice. However, while sanctions are assumed to be caused by the ‘social connectedness’ of group members, how this social connectedness arises is not addressed. Similarly, peer punishment and ‘social capital’ – the ability to trust and cooperate with peers owing to some social structure, relations or norms (Coleman, Reference Coleman1988) – are widely cited reasons for the success of group lending (e.g. Hermes & Lensink, Reference Hermes and Lensink2007), but how and why certain social structures help to solve the cooperative dilemma inherent to JLL is unspecified. We propose that evolutionary theories of cooperation provide a tractable and measurable framework for understanding concepts like social capital and social connectedness, and may help to unify the currently diverse and disconnected findings in the literature on JLL.

3. Evolutionary theories of cooperation and predictions for microfinance loan repayment

3.1. The puzzle of cooperation and a general solution

In evolutionary biology, cooperation is defined as a behaviour that is beneficial to the recipient of the act, often (but not necessarily) at a cost to the actor (West et al., Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007a). The existence of costly cooperation presents a puzzle to evolutionary biologists. The problem arises because cooperators interact with selfish individuals (i.e. ‘defectors’) who benefit from the acts of cooperators but never bear the costs of cooperating themselves. Over the long term, selfish individuals should outcompete cooperators because selfish individuals accrue benefits while cooperators accumulate costs.

A general solution to this puzzle is to ensure that cooperators preferentially interact with other cooperators in the population (Fletcher & Doebeli, Reference Fletcher and Doebeli2009; Fletcher & Zwick, Reference Fletcher and Zwick2006; Queller, Reference Queller1985). This allows cooperators to share and accumulate the benefits of cooperation amongst themselves and prevents selfish individuals from free-riding on these benefits. Hence, the evolution of cooperation requires mechanisms of (positive) assortment that ensure that the average interaction group of cooperators contains more cooperators than the average interaction group of defectors (Fletcher & Doebeli, Reference Fletcher and Doebeli2009). Assortment prevents defectors from gaining the benefits of cooperation.

The following frequently used mathematical formalisation popularly known as ‘Hamilton's rule’ (Hamilton, Reference Hamilton1964a) specifies the conditions under which cooperative behaviour is favoured:

$$br \gt c$$

Cooperative behaviour is favoured when the benefit b of cooperation to the recipient, scaled by the degree of ‘relatedness’ r between the actor and the recipient, is greater than the cost c of cooperation to the actor. In Hamilton's original formulation (Hamilton, Reference Hamilton1964a), r was interpreted as the degree of genetic similarity between the actor and the recipient. However, r can be more broadly interpreted as the degree to which cooperators in the population interact preferentially with other cooperators (Fletcher & Doebeli, Reference Fletcher and Doebeli2009, Reference Fletcher and Doebeli2010; Fletcher & Zwick, Reference Fletcher and Zwick2006; Queller, Reference Queller1992), as it is the statistical association between like types (Hamilton, Reference Hamilton1975). Hence, r is a measure of assortment.

3.2. Assortment mechanisms and evolutionary hypotheses for loan repayment

Over the last half-century, several mechanisms of assortment have been proposed that support the evolution of cooperation (for reviews, see Lehmann & Keller, Reference Lehmann and Keller2006; Nowak, Reference Nowak2006; Sachs et al., Reference Sachs, Mueller, Wilcox and Bull2004; West et al., Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007b) and an extensive literature has explored their relevance to humans (e.g. Apicella & Silk, Reference Apicella and Silk2019; Hammerstein, Reference Hammerstein2003; N. Henrich & Henrich, Reference Henrich and Henrich2007; Powers et al., Reference Powers, van Schaik and Lehmann2019; Rand & Nowak, Reference Rand and Nowak2013). Here, we describe a subset that we consider important in the context of microfinance. For each assortment mechanism, we derive hypotheses for loan repayment, some of which we then test in Section 4. As argued in Section 2, the basis for our predictions is the assumption that higher repayment efficacy in JLL groups, i.e. lower likelihood of credit default or loan delinquency, constitutes a higher degree of cooperation among group members.

3.2.1. Common ancestry

Cooperation can be maintained when it is preferentially directed towards genetic relatives of the actor (Hamilton, Reference Hamilton1964a, Reference Hamiltonb). Here, the mechanism of assortment is genetic. The likelihood of two individuals sharing a gene that makes them behave cooperatively increases with increasing genetic relatedness (Grafen, Reference Grafen2007, Reference Grafen2009). For example, a gene for cooperation is more likely to be shared by identical twins than fraternal twins. Thus, common ancestry is a reliable indicator that the recipient of cooperation is also likely to be cooperative and pass on the benefits of received cooperation to future generations of kin. This process by which cooperation evolves owing to the actor and the recipient sharing ancestry is called ‘kin selection’ (Maynard Smith, Reference Maynard Smith1964). Interacting preferentially with kin is a heuristic that allows the assortment of cooperators and can lead to an accumulation of the benefits of cooperation across generations. The strength of kin-directed cooperation is therefore affected by the degree of genetic relatedness between the actor and recipient. For example, siblings, who on average share 50% of unique genetic variation, should be more likely to help one another than cousins, who share 12.5%.

Kin selection requires the availability of information about common ancestry which can be gained from cues and psychological short-cuts that identify kin (Bressan & Kramer, Reference Bressan and Kramer2015; Lacy & Sherman, Reference Lacy and Sherman1983). It leads to the evolution of emotions and motivations to care for kin, which are observed in human populations across the world (Ko et al., Reference Ko, Pick, Kwon, Barlev, Krems, Varnum and Kenrick2019). There is ample evidence that people bias help towards close kin for many different types of interaction such as food sharing (Gurven et al., Reference Gurven, Hill and Kaplan2002; Kaplan et al., Reference Kaplan, Hill, Cadeliña, Hayden, Hyndman, Preston and Yesner1985), cooperative hunting (Morgan, Reference Morgan1979), monetary giving (Bowles & Posel, Reference Bowles and Posel2005) and child care (Anderson et al., Reference Anderson, Kaplan, Lam and Lancaster1999).

Hypothesis for microfinance research

JLL groups comprising individuals who are more closely related via common ancestry (i.e. genetic kin) should have higher repayment efficacy than those comprising non-kin.

3.2.2. Prior interaction

Cooperation can be maintained when the actor's decision to cooperate or defect depends on the previous cooperative behaviours of the recipient. This is called reciprocity and can be based either on prior interactions with the same partner (direct reciprocity; Axelrod, Reference Axelrod1984; Axelrod & Hamilton, Reference Axelrod and Hamilton1981; Trivers, Reference Trivers1971) or on the basis of one's partner's reputation from her prior interactions with other partners (indirect reciprocity; Alexander, Reference Alexander1987; Leimar & Hammerstein, Reference Leimar and Hammerstein2001; Nowak & Sigmund, Reference Nowak and Sigmund2005; Panchanathan & Boyd, Reference Panchanathan and Boyd2003). Assortment arises because individuals direct cooperation to others who are known to have cooperated in the past. In this case, assortment increases with the number of repeated interactions or with more reliable information on the behaviour of others (Nowak, Reference Nowak2006). The idea that repeated interactions can facilitate outcomes (e.g. cooperation) which do not arise in one-shot encounters is well known to economists as the folk theorem (Fudenberg & Maskin, Reference Fudenberg and Maskin1986). Direct reciprocity requires cognitive mechanisms such as memory to identify suitable long-term partners. It leads to the evolution of emotional motivations such as trust, affinity and sympathy to maintain reciprocal relationships (Fessler & Haley, Reference Fessler and Haley2003; Seyfarth & Cheney, Reference Seyfarth and Cheney2012). Indirect reciprocity in humans is probably supported by our capacity for language to pass on information (Nowak & Sigmund, Reference Nowak and Sigmund2005), inclinations to spread gossip (N. Henrich & Henrich, Reference Henrich and Henrich2007), concern with reputation (Karlan and McConnell, Reference Karlan and McConnell2014; Milinski, Reference Milinski2016) and sympathy for people who do good to others (Bereczkei et al., Reference Bereczkei, Birkas and Kerekes2007). There is evidence from laboratory experiments and field studies that humans reciprocate directly (Dal Bó & Fréchette, Reference Dal Bó and Fréchette2018; Fischbacher et al., Reference Fischbacher, Gächter and Fehr2001; Gurven, Reference Gurven2006; Kasper & Borgerhoff Mulder, Reference Kasper and Borgerhoff Mulder2015) and indirectly (Diekmann et al., Reference Diekmann, Jann, Przepiorka and Wehrli2014; Seinen & Schram, Reference Seinen and Schram2006; Wedekind & Braithwaite, Reference Wedekind and Braithwaite2002).

Hypotheses for microfinance research

JLL groups with the opportunity for direct reciprocity between group members, such as when the group participates in repeated loan cycles (Che, Reference Che2002), should have higher repayment efficacy. Opportunities for mutual exchange outside the JLL group, such as when members have personal and business relations with each other (Anthony, Reference Anthony2005; de Quidt et al., Reference de Quidt, Fetzer and Ghatak2016), should be associated with higher repayment efficacy. JLL groups with the opportunity for indirect reciprocity, such as when members share mutual acquaintances within a larger social network (Postelnicu et al., Reference Postelnicu, Hermes and Servin2019), or engage in social activities outside the group, should have higher repayment efficacy as this may provide a means to acquire and spread reputational information.

3.2.3. Partner choice

Cooperation can be maintained when actors are able to select their interaction partners. Assortment occurs because individuals can choose to interact with known cooperators and avoid interacting with defectors from the outset (Bull & Rice, Reference Bull and Rice1991; Enquist & Leimar, Reference Enquist and Leimar1993; Gintis et al., Reference Gintis, Smith and Bowles2001; Hammerstein & Noë, Reference Hammerstein and Noë2016; Roberts, Reference Roberts1998). This is different to, but can work alongside, other mechanisms such as reciprocity (Section 3.2.2), in which individuals do not actively choose their interaction partners or ‘walk away’ from them, but can only choose whether or not to cooperate with an encountered partner (partner choice vs. partner control, see Schino & Aureli, Reference Schino and Aureli2017). Partner choice requires the ability to identify and choose cooperative partners using signals of their likelihood of being a cooperator. Signals of likely cooperation should be costly, and thereby ‘honest’, so that defectors cannot fool cooperators by faking such signals (Bowles & Hammerstein, Reference Bowles and Hammerstein2003). Honest signals might include an individual's past cooperative behaviour (Guido et al., Reference Guido, Robbett and Romaniuc2019; Sylwester & Roberts, Reference Sylwester and Roberts2010), costly cultural practices such as holding extravagant feasts (Barker et al., Reference Barker, Power, Heap, Puurtinen and Sosis2019), or facial or other physical characteristics (although evidence on humans’ capacity to detect cheaters by biological markers alone is mixed; Aamodt & Custer, Reference Aamodt and Custer2006; Fetchenhauer et al., Reference Fetchenhauer, Groothuis and Pradel2010).

Hypotheses for microfinance research

JLL groups which form via the selection of group members by other members, e.g. by being able to choose who is admitted to your group, should have higher repayment efficacy than groups where membership is not controlled by group members. Note that self-formation of groups is a traditional feature of the Grameen Bank, with economists suggesting that this allows peers to screen each other for the riskiness of their business project (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Ghatak & Guinnane, Reference Ghatak and Guinnane1999; Van Tassel, Reference Van Tassel1999). We expand this idea by suggesting that borrowers might screen for cooperativeness in general (as in biological market theory, see Hammerstein & Noë, Reference Hammerstein and Noë2016).

3.2.4. Similarity of tags

Cooperation can be maintained when it is directed only towards interaction partners that are similar to the actor in an arbitrary observable character or tag if that tag is a reliable indicator that the recipient of cooperation is also a cooperator (Antal et al., Reference Antal, Ohtsuki, Wakeley, Taylor and Nowak2009; Gardner & West, Reference Gardner and West2010; Hales, Reference Hales, Davidsson, Logan and Takadama2005; Hammond & Axelrod, Reference Hammond and Axelrod2006; Riolo et al., Reference Riolo, Cohen and Axelrod2001). In this case, interacting based on this tag leads to assortment. Tag-based cooperators of this type have sometimes been referred to as ‘greenbeards’, after a thought experiment in which green beards act as tags of cooperation (Dawkins, Reference Dawkins1976; Gardner & West, Reference Gardner and West2010). Assortment via tags is threatened when defectors can fake the cooperators’ tags and thus requires, and increases with, the reliability of tags as indicators of behaviour (Hales, Reference Hales, Davidsson, Logan and Takadama2005), for example by using signals that noncooperators cannot easily fake. Tag-based cooperation is different to partner choice (Section 3.2.3) as individuals cannot actively choose their interaction partners, but can only choose whether or not to cooperate with an encountered interaction partner. In humans, tag-based cooperation depends on a psychological inclination to cooperate preferentially with others who appear similar in certain ways (Fu et al., Reference Fu, Nowak, Christakis and Fowler2012). Such tags might include accents (Cohen & Haun, Reference Cohen and Haun2013), facial resemblance (DeBruine, Reference DeBruine2002), expressions of cultural and social identity like clothing, humour, sports or music preferences (Smaldino, Reference Smaldino2017) or other arbitrary markers of groups (Tajfel & Turner, Reference Tajfel and Turner1986).

Hypotheses for microfinance research

Repayment efficacy may be structured by observable biological or socio-cultural tags (e.g. accents, facial resemblance, clothing), after controlling for other differences between groups. Assuming that the tag is a known and reliable indicator of cooperation, a more specific prediction is that homogenous JLL groups whose members share this tag should have higher repayment efficacy than heterogenous groups whose members have different tags, after controlling for other differences between groups.

3.2.5. Social learning

Cooperation can be maintained when cooperative behaviour is transmitted between individuals via social learning mechanisms such as imitation and conformity (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985; J. Henrich & Boyd, Reference Henrich and Boyd2001; N. Henrich & Henrich, Reference Henrich and Henrich2007). Socially learned rules or norms of behaviour can make individuals in an interacting group more similar to each other (Apicella & Silk, Reference Apicella and Silk2019; Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson2009). Hence, the assortment of cooperators can be achieved via social learning. Tendencies to conform to others’ behaviour and adopt local institutions can generate some groups that are more cooperative and others that are less so (Chudek & Henrich, Reference Chudek and Henrich2011). Then, if there is competition between these groups and a more cooperative group stands to outcompete a less cooperative group, cooperation can emerge as the costs borne by the individuals of a more cooperative group are outweighed by the benefits they receive when their group wins and survives. This process has been called cultural group selection (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1985; J. Henrich, Reference Henrich2004; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini, Bell, Demps, Frost, Hillis and Zefferman2016; Waring et al., Reference Waring, Kline, Brooks, Goff, Gowdy, Jansen, Smaldino and Jacquet2015) and the degree of assortment increases with the tendency of individuals to socially learn and exhibit the behavioural rules of the group they are in, compared with other groups. Note that any type of assortment mechanism, including the ones mentioned in previous sections, can be conceptualised as resulting in group selection because assortment leads to ‘groups’ (e.g. kin groups, groups of reciprocators) in which individuals preferentially bestow benefits on each other (see Birch, Reference Birch2019; Wilson & Dugatkin, Reference Wilson and Dugatkin1997; Wilson & Sober, Reference Wilson and Sober1994). Cultural group selection depends on socially learned norms sustained by conformity or punishment. While there is evidence of variation in cooperation across human populations (Gächter et al., Reference Gächter, Herrmann and Thöni2010; J. Henrich et al., Reference Henrich, Boyd, Bowles, Camerer, Fehr, Gintis and Tracer2005; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini, Bell, Demps, Frost, Hillis and Zefferman2016), which is consistent with assortment via social learning of cooperation, the degree to which such variation is caused by the social learning of behavioural norms rather than other factors, such as en masse individual responses to shared ecological and demographic factors which can also create behavioural uniformity, is debated (Lamba & Mace, Reference Lamba and Mace2011).

Hypotheses for microfinance research

Repayment efficacy may be structured by socio-cultural group if there are socially learned rules of cooperation associated with these socio-cultural group boundaries. Repayment efficacy may be structured at any level at which behaviour may be socially transmitted, i.e. community, village, ethno-linguistic group, any other kind of interaction group. Specifically, JLL groups of the same socio-cultural group should have more similar repayment rates to groups from a different socio-cultural group, after controlling for other differences.

3.2.6. Ecology and demography

Cooperation can be maintained when ecological factors and demographic processes create and maintain behavioural similarity between individuals (Smaldino et al., Reference Smaldino, Schank and McElreath2013; Wilson, Reference Wilson1977). Assortment owing to ecology may arise because individuals’ environments vary with respect to the costs and benefits associated with cooperation. For example, the challenge of long-term survival in harsh ecologies may favour cooperation compared with groups living in less harsh ecologies (Smaldino et al., Reference Smaldino, Schank and McElreath2013) and moderate levels of ecological disturbance can aid cooperation relative to high or low levels of disturbance (Foster & Xavier, Reference Foster and Xavier2007). A substantial body of theory in evolutionary biology predicts that demographic characteristics of populations, such as their size and patterns of migration, are important drivers of cooperation and competition (Doebeli et al., Reference Doebeli, Blarer and Ackermann1997; Johnstone & Cant, Reference Johnstone and Cant2008; Platt & Bever, Reference Platt and Bever2009; West et al., Reference West, Pen and Griffin2002). Demography affects the stability of the various mechanisms of assortment described above, as well as the costs and benefits of cooperation. For example, high rates of migration in a population can destabilise cooperation by breaking down the assortment generated by common ancestry, prior interaction or partner choice. Similarly, cooperation via prior interaction can be destabilised in large populations as it may become harder to keep track of and remember past interactions and reputations (Boyd & Richerson, Reference Boyd and Richerson1988; Milinski et al., Reference Milinski, Semmann, Bakker and Krambeck2001). There is empirical evidence that demographic and ecological factors, such as household organisation, population size and age structure, geography and environmental productivity, affect cooperation across human populations (Blurton Jones, Reference Blurton Jones2016; Gurven et al., Reference Gurven, Hill and Kaplan2002; Lamba & Mace, Reference Lamba and Mace2011, Reference Lamba and Mace2013)

Hypotheses for microfinance research

Repayment efficacy may be structured by socio-cultural group if there are similarities in ecology and demography associated with these socio-cultural group boundaries. Repayment efficacy may be structured at any level at which ecology and demography are shared, i.e. community, village, ethno-linguistic group, any other kind of interaction group. Specifically, JLL groups of the same socio-cultural group (e.g. whose members were born or live in the same area) should have more similar repayment rates to groups from a different socio-cultural group, after controlling for other differences. Additionally, demographic factors such as population size and rates of migration might be associated with repayment efficacy. For example, repayment efficacy might be higher in smaller populations and populations with less migration (e.g. rural rather than urban populations).

3.3. Summary and clarifying comments

In the previous sections we have described several evolutionary mechanisms by which cooperators may preferentially assort (common ancestry, prior interaction, partner choice, similarity of tags, social learning, and ecology and demography), thus leading to the maintenance of cooperation. For each of these, we have specified hypotheses for how the mechanism may affect repayment efficacy in JLL-based microfinance loan groups. Before testing some of these hypotheses in the existing microfinance literature in Section 4, we offer some clarifications of these hypotheses, as well as of evolutionary approaches to human behaviour more generally, with a social science audience in mind.

First, it is important to keep in mind that these mechanisms may not be mutually exclusive (Sachs et al., Reference Sachs, Mueller, Wilcox and Bull2004), i.e. multiple mechanisms may operate simultaneously in the same loan group. For example, people may select loan group members (partner choice) partly based on their reputation (prior interaction).

Second, while some of these mechanisms rely on a genetic basis for cooperative behaviour (e.g. common ancestry, see Section 3.2.1), other mechanisms assume that behaviour is acquired and transmitted nongenetically (e.g. via social learning, see Section 3.2.5). Therefore, an evolutionary approach does not require that cooperative behaviour itself is entirely genetically determined, rather genetically evolved cognitive or psychological faculties such as memory or language may facilitate the ability to use these assortment mechanisms.

Third, we can therefore make a distinction between the assortment mechanism that is ultimately supporting the maintenance of cooperation (e.g. common ancestry) and the proximate physiological, developmental and psychological processes (e.g. kin recognition) by which that mechanism operates. This distinction between ultimate and proximate causes of behaviour (Tinbergen, Reference Tinbergen1963) is sometimes blurred in the social science literature, particularly relating to human cooperation (Alexander, Reference Alexander1987; West et al., Reference West, Griffin and Gardner2007a). In group lending, for example, proximate motivations and emotions like fear (Dube & Kamath, Reference Dube and Kamath2018), trust (van Bastelaer & Leathers, Reference van Bastelaer and Leathers2006) or a ‘preference’ for others’ payoffs (Carpenter & Williams, Reference Carpenter and Williams2014) do not distinguish between the ultimate assortment mechanisms at play. People may ‘trust’ both their kin and repeated interaction partners, but this does not explain why trust is directed towards these particular categories of people. Identifying the ultimate assortment mechanisms underlying human cooperation can allow us to make novel predictions about what characteristics of individuals and groups are likely to be associated with repayment efficacy.

Finally, evolutionary theory does not require that individuals are consciously aware of the ultimate evolutionary reason why they are performing a particular behaviour (Nettle et al., Reference Nettle, Gibson, Lawson and Sear2013). Indeed, people might more often cite proximate motivations and emotions such as fear, trust or love for why they may or may not cooperate with another person. Consequently, people's actual behaviour provides the appropriate data for testing our hypotheses rather than their self-reported motivations.

4. Empirical review: do predictors of loan repayment correspond to evolutionary mechanisms of cooperation?

In this section we attempt to test the first three assortment mechanisms presented in Section 3.2, common ancestry, prior interaction and partner choice by examining the empirical literature. At this stage, we do not explicitly test the other three mechanisms – similarity of tags, social learning, and ecology and demography. These mechanisms cannot be tested by collecting simple associations between predictors and repayment outcomes from separated contexts. Rather, they require the examination of patterns of relative variation in a multilevel dataset, for example with borrowers nested within loan groups, nested within MFIs, nested within socio-cultural groups, nested within regions, etc. (see, e.g. Lamba & Mace, Reference Lamba and Mace2011), to identify which levels best structure the variance in repayment efficacy (see Sections 3.2.4–3.2.6). Furthermore, these latter three mechanisms overlap in their predictions. For example, all three mechanisms predict that repayment efficacy may be structured by socio-cultural group boundaries or tags. Multilevel data are essential to distinguish between them. This analytical approach is beyond the scope of this initial review. Here, we simply assess whether the empirical MFI literature contains predictors that can be related to evolutionary assortment mechanisms and conduct a rough assessment of the evidence for only the first three (common ancestry, prior interaction and partner choice).

Economists and other social scientists have conducted multiple empirical studies exploring the factors linked to the repayment efficacy of microfinance groups. Their aim is typically to assess what mitigates the incentive problems inherent in microfinance, such as the temptation to dishonestly misuse the loan (‘moral hazard’) or to evade the repayment obligation that is difficult to enforce (Hermes & Lensink, Reference Hermes and Lensink2007). These studies compare multiple loan groups, usually from the same MFI and area, to examine whether certain characteristics of loan groups or borrowers are associated with higher or lower repayment efficacy. Our first step was to review the MFI literature to identify factors that had been tested by economists and other social scientists for their association with repayment efficacy of JLL groups and that could plausibly be linked to our evolutionary mechanisms specified in Section 3.2, especially common ancestry, prior interaction and partner choice. Since these studies were not guided by an evolutionary framework, they do not consistently and precisely measure the evolutionary factors that we predict to be associated with cooperation. For example, some studies measure kinship within the group as number of family members within the loan group, while others measure the percentage of group members related to each other. Consequently, we grouped factors from the literature into categories that themselves fell under the first three assortment mechanisms. For example, several authors measured associations between some form of geographical proximity between loan group members and repayment efficacy. We therefore created a category ‘geographical proximity’ to include these associations, which is likely to reflect the assortment mechanism of prior interaction.

We conduct a qualitative ‘vote count’ of findings within each category based on statistical significance (Koricheva et al., Reference Koricheva, Gurevitch and Mengersen2013). We count the number of associations that were in line with the evolutionary hypothesis (‘positive’), not in line (‘negative’) and that showed no statistical significance (‘nonsignificant’). We acknowledge that the ‘vote-counting’ methodology has clear weaknesses: it does not properly account for the size and uncertainty of effects, relies on results from error-prone statistical null hypothesis testing and weighs equally studies with different sample sizes, methods and quality (Koricheva et al., Reference Koricheva, Gurevitch and Mengersen2013). Further, despite our systematic approach, we cannot claim that this review is exhaustive or unbiased, since the collection of literature and effects involved multiple steps that were exploratory. Nevertheless, it provides a first systematic overview of the MFI literature within an evolutionary framework. A more rigorous quantitative meta-analysis would be the next step, but is challenging given the heterogeneity of the microfinance literature (Duvendack et al., Reference Duvendack, Palmer-Jones, Copestake, Hooper, Loke and Rao2011). Therefore, here we first assess the feasibility of pursuing this research agenda.

4.1. Review methodology

4.1.1. Literature search

We searched Google Scholar for various combinations of the terms: ‘microfinance’, ‘microcredit’, ‘group lending’, ‘joint liability’, ‘repayment’, ‘default’, ‘delinquency’, ‘arrears’, ‘cooperation’, ‘social capital’, ‘factors’, ‘determinants’, ‘predictors’. We first screened for studies in the peer-reviewed and grey literature (dissertations, working papers, preprints) that (a) analysed factors associated with a measure of repayment efficacy (e.g. timeliness of repayment, proportion of loan repaid at due date, full loan repaid yes/no, occurrence of repayment problems yes/no) in groups that take out loans and have some degree of joint liability, (b) were quantitative and (c) reported methods and results sufficiently. We further screened the resulting papers to exclude studies that (a) reported aggregate data at the level of an entire country or MFI rather than at the level of individual borrowers or loan groups, (b) used lab or lab-in-the-field experiments (Harrison & List, Reference Harrison and List2004) on MFIs instead of data from real MFIs and (c) did not report results for a predictor that links to the evolutionary hypotheses we set out to examine (Section 3.2). Thus, we built a database of predictors examined in the MFI literature that link to the evolutionary hypotheses we wish to test (Section 3.2). Building on Lamba (Reference Lamba, Gibson and Lawson2014), we focus on a set of predictors which is by no means an exhaustive list of all predictors occurring in the literature. Since no other previous work has been guided by similar hypotheses, we invite readers to examine our choices in the Supplementary Material 1 (SM1) and build upon them. We also scanned the bibliographies of all included work to find additional relevant studies. Based on this, predictors from a set of 41 studies were included in this review, with most of them published in economics and development studies journals (see SM1 for a full overview).

4.1.2. Extraction of effects of predictors on repayment efficacy from reviewed literature

For each predictor variable included in our database we qualitatively recorded whether their association with repayment efficacy was statistically positive, negative or nonsignificant. We then recoded the predictors used in the original studies such that a positive association is in line with the evolutionary hypothesis, i.e. supports the hypothesis of a positive relationship between the evolutionary predictor and repayment efficacy, and negative associations are contrary to the evolutionary prediction, i.e. in the opposite direction. For example, we predict a positive relationship between geographical proximity and repayment efficacy (see Section 3.2.2). If a study reported a statistically significant positive association between ‘geographical distance between group members’ and repayment efficacy, we recoded the predictor as ‘geographical proximity’, and consequently recoded its relationship with repayment efficacy as negative. Therefore, since in this case ‘geographical proximity’ has a negative association with repayment efficacy, it is recorded as not in line with our evolutionary hypothesis. Note that some studies measured repayment efficacy inversely (e.g. credit default or repayment delay, see SM1); however we never recoded this in SM1, only the predictors.

The microfinance literature includes both characteristics of borrowers and characteristics of loan groups as predictors of repayment efficacy. We have specified in our database in SM1 the level at which the predictor was specified by referring to borrower or loan group as appropriate in the description of the predictor.

We did not include predictor variables measuring psychological states such as trust, anger, a willingness to exert pressure on others or self-reported motives for repayment (e.g. Dube & Kamath, Reference Dube and Kamath2018; Griffin & Husted, Reference Griffin and Husted2015), because these do not directly capture assortment mechanisms for the evolution of cooperation. Rather, these represent proximate psychological motivations (see Section 3.3) which were not the focus of this study.

When multiple analyses were reported for the same predictors in one study (e.g. various types of models and/or varying sets of covariates were reported), we only extracted one association per predictor per study. We selected only the analysis explicitly favoured by the original authors, except if there was a regression model with even more predictors included simultaneously, i.e. a ‘full model’. In that case, we selected the association reported in the larger model. In rare cases, when the analysis favoured by the original authors was not judged appropriate for the purpose of this review, the most suitable analysis was chosen by the first author (SG). For example, Griffin and Husted (Reference Griffin and Husted2015) aggregated different questionnaire items into one latent variable, but the raw correlation between the questionnaire item of interest with repayment efficacy was seen as more suitable. When multiple measures for repayment efficacy were reported, we always selected whichever was most conservative in classifying repayment as low. For example, when both repayment problems within the loan group, i.e. individual borrowers not paying their shares (‘internal delinquency’), and repayment problems between the loan group and the MFI, i.e. the loan group not repaying its collective loan (‘external delinquency’), were reported, we used the latter. We invite readers to assess our choices of extracted variables, models and effects reported in SM1. We report associations as positive, negative or nonsignificant in accordance with the original authors’ own most permissive significance cut-offs (p < 0.1 in the majority of studies; SM1). In all studies, only monotonic relationships between predictors and repayment efficacy were analysed, except for two studies (Kolstad et al., Reference Kolstad, Pires and Wiig2017; Sabin & Reed-Tsochas, Reference Sabin and Reed-Tsochas2018), which reported an inverted U-shaped relationship between a predictor and repayment efficacy. Thus, in the results, ‘Inverted U’ is reported as an extra category.

4.1.3. Categorisation of predictors

After extracting predictors from the empirical microfinance literature, we grouped together predictors that measured the same underlying concept. This was necessary because different authors measured the same concept in different ways. For example, the predictors ‘Number of family members in group’ (Carpenter & Williams, Reference Carpenter and Williams2014) and ‘Proportion of group members who have a close relative in the group’ (Ahlin & Townsend, Reference Ahlin and Townsend2007) from two different studies are both classified as ‘Family members in group’. Each predictor was only included in one category. This gave rise to 13 categories of predictors which are displayed in Figure 2. SM1 provides the original definition of all underlying predictor and outcome variables included in each category.

Figure 2. Number and qualitative directions of associations between predictor categories and repayment efficacy of JLL borrowers reported in the literature. Predictors are grouped into 13 categories based on the concept they are measuring. Coloured boxes further group these 13 categories into the evolutionary assortment mechanisms (see Section 4.1.3 for details). Associations are reported qualitatively as negative (orange), nonsignificant (grey), inverted U-shaped (blue) or positive (green) as per the original study (see Section 4.1.2 for details) with percentages of each type of association shown. Note that some bars do not add up exactly to 100% owing to rounding. The figure is based on a total of 142 associations from 41 empirical studies spanning 32 countries. See SM1 for details and references for every association extracted from the literature and SM2 for a table with the data underlying this figure. Within the group of categories labelled ‘Prior interaction’, the first six categories relate to direct reciprocity, and the last three to indirect reciprocity, with two categories relating to both direct or indirect reciprocity, specifically ‘Geographic proximity of group members’ and ‘Participation in community and other associations’. ‘Geographic proximity of group members’ may also relate to the ‘Other/multiple mechanisms’ grouping.

As shown in Figure 2, we link 10 of these 13 categories to one of the three assortment mechanisms (common ancestry, prior interaction, partner choice) that we test, and group the final three categories as ‘Other/multiple mechanisms’ because these categories relate to and overlap across the three assortment mechanisms (similarity of tags, social learning, ecology and demography) that we do not explicitly test. We group predictors into conceptually cohesive categories and then link these categories to assortment mechanisms, rather than directly assigning predictors to mechanisms, to capture the multiple ways in which the assortment mechanisms may work.

4.2. Results

In total, 142 associations from 41 studies covering 32 countries were included and classified into 13 broader categories, shown in Figure 2. We find 47 (33.1%) positive associations of the predictor and repayment, meaning that the evolutionary hypothesis is supported in these cases. Two associations (1.4%) are initially positive for low values of the predictors (spatial proximity of group members’ residences; household income similarity of group members), but then turn negative (inverted U-shaped, fit via a quadratic function). Thirty associations (21.1%) are negative. There are 63 (44.4%) nonsignificant associations. Thus, just under half of the associations are nonsignificant, about one-third are positive and one-fifth are negative.

The three assortment mechanisms that we test (common ancestry, prior interaction, partner choice) contain varying proportions of negative, nonsignificant and positive associations (Figure 2 and Table SM2). For common ancestry, 50% of associations are negative, 38% are nonsignificant and 12% are positive. For prior interaction, 19% of associations are negative, 45% are nonsignificant, 1% (one finding) are inverted U shaped and 35% are positive. For partner choice, 13% of associations are negative, 44% are nonsignificant and 44% are positive.

Each assortment mechanism comprises multiple categories of predictors that group together variables measuring the same concept across studies (Figure 2 and Table SM2). These categories of predictors also contain varying proportions of negative, nonsignificant and positive associations (Figure 2). For example, 10% of associations between ‘prior acquaintance of group members’ and repayment are negative, 40% are nonsignificant and 50% are positive. Meanwhile, 37% of associations between ‘tenure and continuity of group composition’ and repayment are negative, 47% are nonsignificant and 16% are positive. Proportions of negative, nonsignificant and positive associations for each of the 13 categories separately are reported in Figure 2 and SM2.

For the 30 studies that reported loan group size means or ranges, we calculated a mean group size of 9.83 borrowers, median group size of 9.15 borrowers and range of 2.6–35 borrowers (where ranges were reported we used the mid-point of the range for our calculations). The assessed predictor variables, outcome variables, types of analysis and other study characteristics are presented in SM1.

5. Discussion

5.1. Summary of findings

In this paper, we assess whether the empirical literature on repayment efficacy among microcredit loan groups contains predictors that can be related to evolutionary assortment mechanisms that maintain cooperation: common ancestry, prior interaction, partner choice, similarity of tags, social learning, and ecology and demography. We find several predictors that can be related to these mechanisms, the majority of which relate to prior interaction. We conduct a rough assessment of the evidence for three of these (common ancestry, prior interaction, partner choice). Overall, the majority of associations are statistically nonsignificant, about one-third are positive (in line with our evolutionary hypotheses), about one-fifth are negative (not in line with our evolutionary hypotheses), and two associations take an inverted-U shape.

For the three mechanisms that we explicitly test, we find different levels of support. For common ancestry, 88% of studies show either negative (50%) or no associations (38%) between kin and repayment efficacy, leaving only 12% showing positive association (one finding), meaning that this evolutionary mechanism of assortment finds little support. For prior interaction, 64% of associations between a measure of acquaintanceship or interaction frequency between loan group members and repayment efficacy are either negative (19%) or nonsignificant (45%), with 35% positive, meaning we find greater support for this mechanism. However, prior interaction contains seven categories of predictors (see Figure 2), and there is variation in the level of support for each category. A majority of associations are positive for three categories of predictors (prior acquaintance of group members, 50%; frequency of group meetings, 60%; and shared extra-group social ties, 100% (one study)). On the other hand, a majority of associations are negative or nonsignificant for four categories (personal and business relations between group members, 74%; tenure and continuity of group composition, 84%; geographic proximity of group members, 53%; and participation in community and other associations, 55%), although for the latter two categories at least one-third of the associations are positive and these outnumber the negative associations. Consequently, the seven categories combined show mixed support for the mechanism of prior interaction. For partner choice, 57% of associations between a measure of whether loan group members chose any of their group members and repayment efficacy are either negative (13%) or nonsignificant (44%), with 44% positive, meaning we find the most support for this mechanism. This mechanism comprises two categories of predictors and a majority of associations are positive for one category of predictors (self-formation of group, 67%) with no negative associations at all. Some 70% of associations are negative (20%) or nonsignificant (50%) for the other category (rejection and invitation of members), although 30% are positive and outnumber the negative associations. Consequently, both categories together show some support for this assortment mechanism. In summary, of the three assortment mechanisms that we explicitly examine, we find little support for common ancestry, and more support for prior interaction and partner choice.

For the three mechanisms that we do not explicitly test (similarity of tags, social learning, ecology and demography), we nonetheless find predictors in the MFI literature to which they may be related, and which we grouped into three categories (socio-cultural homogeneity of group, socio-economic homogeneity of group and rurality and limited mobility). We find broad support for two of these categories (socio-cultural homogeneity of group, and rurality and limited mobility), with a majority of associations positive (67% and 50% respectively) and the number of positive associations equal to or greater than a half of all associations. For the category socio-economic homogeneity of group, we find a large number of associations (26), indicating the popularity of these predictors in the economic literature, but also the fact that this category includes many types of predictors. There is limited support for socio-economic homogeneity, with a majority of associations either negative (23%) or nonsignificant (58%), and more negative than positive (15%) associations. However, as discussed in Section 4, it is unclear how to link these categories of predictors to our evolutionary mechanisms given that all three mechanisms make predictions that overlap across these categories. In any case, these predictor–outcome associations cannot be used to test these mechanisms and multilevel data are required. Furthermore, these categories lump together many different kinds of homogeneity, and in many cases this homogeneity is measured in the original study using a composite index that combines several characteristics of borrowers. For example, similarity of ethnic markers, religion or caste are included in the category socio-cultural homogeneity of group and similarity of occupation, gender, age, income and education are included in the category socio-economic homogeneity of group. Therefore, these associations are difficult to interpret.

5.2. The negative effect of common ancestry

The finding that the majority of associations between kin and repayment efficacy are negative (i.e. not in line with our evolutionary hypothesis) is surprising given that many evolutionary studies in humans (Kurzban et al., Reference Kurzban, Burton-Chellew and West2015) and other species (Strassmann et al., Reference Strassmann, Page, Robinson and Seeley2011) have shown that help is preferentially directed towards kin. It is possible that the evolutionary theory of kin selection fails to explain repayment behaviour in the context of microfinance. Alternatively, there are at least three potential reasons for this unexpected finding which are in fact consistent with the theory.

First, economists have suggested that enforcement of loan repayment may be difficult among relatives or that relatives may collude against the MFI (Ahlin & Townsend, Reference Ahlin and Townsend2007; Hermes & Lensink, Reference Hermes and Lensink2007; Sharma and Zeller, Reference Sharma and Zeller1997). This may nevertheless be consistent with kin selection if group members who are relatives do not want to impose costs on their kin by punishing them for nonrepayment or are more lenient in giving them more time to repay their loans, and if they are willing to bear the penalties of nonrepayment imposed by the lender. In fact, some MFIs like Akhuwat in Pakistan have entirely banned family members from joining the same loan group (Mahmud, Reference Mahmud2019).

Second, if the loan group is embedded in a wider social network such that individuals have kin outside the loan group as well as inside, then the relationships between kin outside the loan group may influence the relationships between kin inside the loan group. For example, if one has lots of close relatives within one's village but one forms a loan group with more distant relatives, then if one's close kin in the village need help, one may help them at the expense of being able to repay one's share of the loan on time. In this case, although one is defaulting on kin within the loan group, it is to help closer kin outside the loan group, consistent with kin selection. For example, Cieslik et al. (Reference Cieslik, Hudon and Verwimp2019) report how borrowers in Burundi prioritise benefitting their family and friends over compliance with MFI rules by spending loans in unruly ways (e.g. consumption spending) that negatively affect repayment but may increase the status of their family (e.g. by spending on social events) or deepen close social bonds (e.g. by spending on gifts).

Third, if the density of kin in the wider social network is high, then upon forming a loan group with some of these kin, one may prioritise one's own earnings over the earnings of one's kin because one is also in economic competition with those kin. For example, if a borrower lives in a small village and forms a loan group with her sister, and they both own shops which compete for the same business, then the borrower may invest in her own business at the expense of repaying her share of the loan. This phenomenon, where cooperation between kin is undermined by competition between them, has been described by evolutionary biologists as kin competition (Taylor, Reference Taylor1992; West et al., Reference West, Pen and Griffin2002). Interestingly, one of the studies in our dataset may provide potential evidence for this: when splitting up their sample, Ahlin and Townsend (Reference Ahlin and Townsend2007) find a negative effect of kinship on loan repayment only in the more rural region of Thailand, where people might reside, and hence compete, more in extended families.

To summarise, two out of three reasons why kin has a negative effect on repayment may actually be in line with kin selection, while the third is consistent with another theory from evolutionary biology, kin competition. Thus, MFI loan groups demonstrate that kin selection need not always result in a positive association between kin and cooperation within an interaction group, for example when the wider social context is taken into account or when enforcement facilitates cooperation.

The observation that kinship can generate collusion (i.e. cooperation) within the loan group against the MFI suggests that other factors which increase within-group cohesion may similarly reduce repayment efficacy. For example, a decrease in repayment was observed in a microcredit programme in Sierra Leone when groups were ‘too cohesive’, measured by their geographical proximity (Sabin & Reed-Tsochas, Reference Sabin and Reed-Tsochas2018). When penalties by the lender are too small, cooperation for repayment at the loan-group level may be less relevant than cooperation at other levels, such as the household, neighbourhood, community or dyad. Frameworks of ‘linked games’ (Spagnolo, Reference Spagnolo1999) and multilevel selection (J. Henrich, Reference Henrich2004; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini, Bell, Demps, Frost, Hillis and Zefferman2016; Waring et al., Reference Waring, Kline, Brooks, Goff, Gowdy, Jansen, Smaldino and Jacquet2015) which address interconnected and nested social dilemmas can potentially help to understand these phenomena.

5.3. Limitations

The reviewed studies are diverse in the country/regions where they were conducted, in the methodology used, in the measurement of variables and in the level of empirical investigation (individual borrowers versus loan groups). Some authors interviewed multiple group members, others just one. Sometimes the repayment outcome was a more direct measure from administrative records (e.g. percentage of loan value not repaid at a certain date), while other studies measured more indirect outcomes via self-report (e.g. whether group members reported experiencing repayment difficulties). The same concepts were measured in different ways across studies and different sets of covariates were included in the statistical models across studies. Sample sizes and sizes of loan groups varied widely (SM1). We expect some false positives, owing to the multiple analyses run and variables tested within the same study, and false negatives, owing to low statistical power in many studies, in addition to potential publication bias. A quantitative meta-analysis with more rigorous inclusion criteria is an important next step.

Most of the associations in our database are cross-sectional and correlational, casting doubt on the causal relationship between predictor and repayment efficacy. For example, borrower groups formed via self-selection will probably include members that have stronger reciprocal ties than groups that were formed exogenously. Mahmud (Reference Mahmud2019) found that the more time people had to form their groups in one Pakistani MFI, the more the groups were composed of people who knew each other previously. This confounds prior interaction and partner choice which we have presented as separate mechanisms in Section 3.2. Selection bias may limit findings in cases where loans are only offered to, or taken up by, particular kinds of individuals (e.g. women). Reversed causality may occur, for example when repayment outcomes affect the social ties between borrowers, or when individuals attend group meetings more regularly because they have repayment difficulties, rather than vice versa (discussed by van Bastelaer & Leathers, Reference van Bastelaer and Leathers2006). Encouragingly, the few studies that attempt to explicitly test causality using quasi-experimental approaches (listed in SM1) find effects that are in line with our hypotheses: repeated interactions in group meetings (Dalla Pellegrina et al., Reference Dalla Pellegrina, De Michele, Di Maio, Landoni and Parravicini2017) and geographical proximity (Karlan, Reference Karlan2007), both led to higher repayment efficacy. In the future, natural experiments, longitudinal data and lab-in-the-field experiments could provide more robust tests of our evolutionary hypotheses.

Some positives associations in our review might plausibly be explained by factors other than assortment. As outlined in the introduction (Section 3.1), the evolution of cooperation also depends on the relative costs and benefits. For example, longer tenure of a group might increase assortment by facilitating repeated interactions among members (Section 3.2.2), but it may also improve the borrowers’ finances, thereby reducing the need for a microloan (Paxton et al., Reference Paxton, Graham and Thraen2000) or cause borrowers to exhaust productive business opportunities in which they could invest their loan (Guttman, Reference Guttman2007). This reduces the individual benefits of disciplined repayment and loan renewal. In terms of Hamilton's rule (Section 3.1), in this case though r may increase, b may simultaneously decrease. This could explain why this category of predictors (‘tenure and continuity of group composition’, Figure 2) has fewer positive associations with repayment than other proxies for prior interaction.

5.4. Implications for evolutionary biology and economics

We end by noting some general implications of our study. First, our unexpected finding that kin in the loan group are negatively associated with repayment efficacy highlights the need for evolutionary biologists and evolutionary human scientists to go beyond simplistic applications of evolutionary theory that make general claims that cooperation should always be preferentially directed towards kin, and test more nuanced predictions that arise from kin selection theory. Conversely, this also offers novel avenues of investigation for economists and social scientists studying microfinance. For example, the direction of the effect of kin on repayment efficacy may depend on the degree of kinship not only within the loan group, but also outside the group in the wider population. Typically, only the former is measured in microfinance studies.

Second, it is important to think about the overall structure of the cooperative dilemma (‘game’) that joint liability borrowers face as cooperative dilemmas come in different forms (Archetti & Scheuring, Reference Archetti and Scheuring2011, Reference Archetti and Scheuring2012). Once this is more clearly defined, predictions for different levels of assortment on the evolution of cooperation in this particular dilemma can be derived more precisely. A plausible model of JLL is a threshold public goods game: if a group's credit is fully repaid (i.e. the threshold is reached), all group members are rewarded with a new, larger loan, but under a strict implementation of JLL the lender is indifferent to who repays. Such dilemmas have been theoretically examined in economics (e.g. Palfrey & Rosenthal, Reference Palfrey and Rosenthal1984) and have been studied under the name of the ‘volunteer's dilemma’ in sociology (Diekmann, Reference Diekmann1985) and biology (Archetti, Reference Archetti2009). Indeed, theoretical work suggests that it is easier to maintain cooperation in a threshold public goods game than in a linear public goods game, and that the role of assortment may be less crucial (Archetti, Reference Archetti2009; Archetti & Scheuring, Reference Archetti and Scheuring2011). This is generally consistent with the high repayment efficacy among group lending programmes globally.

Third, economists acknowledge the important role of different forms of ‘social capital’ for loan repayment in the microfinance literature (Armendáriz & Morduch, Reference Armendáriz and Morduch2010; Cassar et al., Reference Cassar, Crowley and Wydick2007; Hermes & Lensink, Reference Hermes and Lensink2007). Coleman (Reference Coleman1988) defines social capital as social structure which facilitates particular actions of actors within that structure. In his definition, Coleman specifically highlights the roles of mutual obligation, expectations, trustworthiness, social norms, social sanctions and the transmission of information. In the context of JLL, social capital thus defined appears to comprise mechanisms that facilitate cooperators to selectively interact with each other. We propose that these are the assortment mechanisms described in Section 3.2, leading to the maintenance of cooperation. Therefore r, i.e. the degree of assortment in Hamilton's equation (Section 3.1), can be interpreted as a general measure of the effects of social capital. However, whereas the evolutionary biology literature distinguishes between ultimate causes of behaviour and the proximate motivations and preferences that support them (Section 3.3), the term social capital as used and measured by economists does not make this distinction. By distinguishing the two, an evolutionary approach allows us to identify the ultimate reasons why a behaviour or relationship occurs. For example, it allows us to explain why trust is directed at certain individuals or why certain peer networks are more or less conducive to successful repayment. This unpacking of social capital may lead to new insights and novel predictions in economic research. The concept of social capital emphasises not just the relations between actors but also the social structure in which they are embedded. This may serve as a reminder to the evolutionary sciences that measurements of r might benefit from taking account of not only the relatedness or degree of assortment of individuals within an interaction group but also the relative degrees of assortment within and between groups (see discussion Section 5.2).

In conclusion, we hope to have demonstrated the feasibility of using microfinance as a real-world test case for theories of the evolution of cooperation, and conversely that evolutionary theory may provide a unifying framework for organising existing findings on microfinance and generating new predictions regarding loan repayment under joint liability.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2020.64

Acknowledgements

Early stages of this work benefited from comments by Joanna Bryson and Nichola Raihani and from discussions with Bruce Kogut. We thank Robert Lensink for helpful discussions on microfinance and Bram Kuijper for advice on evolutionary models of cooperation. The work profited from exchange with participants at the Economics & Finance seminar at the University of Portsmouth, the CAGE & IAS Summer School 2018 at the University of Warwick and the Financial Inclusion Summer School 2018 at the University of Groningen. We thank two anonymous reviewers and the Editor for helpful comments. The first version of this manuscript, pre-printed at https://osf.io/tmpqj/, contained a mathematical analysis of a threshold public goods game. However, we decided to remove this model after reviewers pointed out potential problems and we were unable to fully resolve their concerns.

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

Author contributions

SG, AM and SL designed the study. SG and SL reviewed the literature. SG collated studies, extracted data and conducted the analysis. AM and SL error checked a subsample of extracted data. SG, AM and SL co-wrote the paper.

Financial support

This work is funded by a Royal Society fellowship (UF150036) and grant (RG160537) to SL.

Data availability

R code and results from the literature review to reproduce Figure 2 and Table SM2 are available at: https://github.com/stefgehrig/bankingoncooperation.

References

Aamodt, M. G., & Custer, H. (2006). Who can best catch a liar?: A meta-analysis of individual differences in detecting deception. The Forensic Examiner, 15(1), 611.Google Scholar
Ahlin, C., & Townsend, R. M. (2007). Using repayment data to test across models of joint liability lending. The Economic Journal, 117(517), F11F51. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02014.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, R. D. (1987). The biology of moral systems. Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Anderson, K. G., Kaplan, H., Lam, D., & Lancaster, J. (1999). Paternal care by genetic fathers and stepfathers II: Reports by Xhosa high school students. Evolution and Human Behavior, 20(6), 433451. https://doi.org/10.1016/S1090-5138(99)00022-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antal, T., Ohtsuki, H., Wakeley, J., Taylor, P. D., & Nowak, M. A. (2009). Evolution of cooperation by phenotypic similarity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 106(21), 85978600. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0902528106CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anthony, D. (2005). Cooperation in microcredit borrowing groups: Identity, sanctions, and reciprocity in the production of collective goods. American Sociological Review, 70(3), 496515. https://doi.org/10.1177/000312240507000307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apicella, C. L., & Silk, J. B. (2019). The evolution of human cooperation. Current Biology, 29(11), R447R450. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2019.03.036CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Archetti, M. (2009). Cooperation as a volunteer's dilemma and the strategy of conflict in public goods games. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 22(11), 21922200. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1420-9101.2009.01835.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Archetti, M., & Scheuring, I. (2011). Coexistence of cooperation and defection in public goods games. Evolution, 65(4), 11401148. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1558-5646.2010.01185.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Archetti, M., & Scheuring, I. (2012). Review: Game theory of public goods in one-shot social dilemmas without assortment. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 299, 920. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2011.06.018CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Armendáriz, B., & Morduch, J. (2010). The economics of microfinance (2nd ed.). MIT Press.Google Scholar
Attanasio, O., Augsburg, B., De Haas, R., Fitzsimons, E., & Harmgart, H. (2015). The impacts of microfinance: Evidence from joint-liability lending in Mongolia. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(1), 90122. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.20130489Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 211(4489), 13901396. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.7466396CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Banerjee, S. B., & Jackson, L. (2017). Microfinance and the business of poverty reduction: Critical perspectives from rural Bangladesh. Human Relations, 70(1), 6391. https://doi.org/10.1177/0018726716640865CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A., Karlan, D., & Zinman, J. (2015). Six randomized evaluations of microcredit: Introduction and further steps. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(1), 121. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.20140287Google Scholar
Barker, J. L., Power, E. A., Heap, S., Puurtinen, M., & Sosis, R. (2019). Content, cost, and context: A framework for understanding human signaling systems. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 28(2), 8699. https://doi.org/10.1002/evan.21768CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bereczkei, T., Birkas, B., & Kerekes, Z. (2007). Public charity offer as a proximate factor of evolved reputation-building strategy: An experimental analysis of a real-life situation. Evolution and Human Behavior, 28(4), 277284. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2007.04.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1995). Group lending, repayment incentives and social collateral. Journal of Development Economics, 46(1), 118. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-3878(94)00045-ECrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birch, J. (2019). Are kin and group selection rivals or friends? Current Biology, 29(11), R433R438. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2019.01.065CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blurton Jones, N. (2016). Demography and evolutionary ecology of Hadza hunter–gatherers. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S., & Hammerstein, P. (2003). Does market theory apply to biology? Santa Fe Institute Working Paper.Google Scholar
Bowles, S., & Posel, D. (2005). Genetic relatedness predicts South African migrant workers’ remittances to their families. Nature, 434(7031), 380383. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature03420CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1988). The evolution of reciprocity in sizable groups. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 132(3), 337356.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (2009). Culture and the evolution of human cooperation. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 364(1533), 32813288. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2009.0134CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brau, J., & Woller, G. (2004). Microfinance: A comprehensive review of the existing literature. The Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance, 9(1), 128.Google Scholar
Bressan, P., & Kramer, P. (2015). Human kin detection. Wiley Interdisciplinary Reviews: Cognitive Science, 6(3), 299311. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcs.1347Google ScholarPubMed
Bull, J. J., & Rice, W. R. (1991). Distinguishing mechanisms for the evolution of co-operation. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 149(1), 6374. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-5193(05)80072-4CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Carpena, F., Cole, S., Shapiro, J., & Zia, B. (2013). Liability structure in small-scale finance: Evidence from a natural experiment. The World Bank Economic Review, 27(3), 437469. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhs031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, J., & Williams, T. (2014). Peer monitoring and microcredit: Field experimental evidence from Paraguay. Oxford Development Studies, 42(1), 111135. https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2014.887061CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassar, A., Crowley, L., & Wydick, B. (2007). The effect of social capital on group loan repayment: Evidence from field experiments. The Economic Journal, 117(517), F85F106. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02016.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Che, Y.-K. (2002). Joint liability and peer monitoring under group lending. Contributions in Theoretical Economics, 2(1). https://doi.org/10.2202/1534-5971.1016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chudek, M., & Henrich, J. (2011). Culture–gene coevolution, norm-psychology and the emergence of human prosociality. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 15(5), 218226. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2011.03.003CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cieslik, K., Hudon, M., & Verwimp, P. (2019). Unruly entrepreneurs – Investigating value creation by microfinance clients in rural Burundi. Oxford Development Studies, 0(0), 118. https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2019.1597034Google Scholar
Cohen, E., & Haun, D. (2013). The development of tag-based cooperation via a socially acquired trait. Evolution and Human Behavior, 34(3), 230235. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2013.02.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 94, S95S120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cull, R., & Morduch, J. (2018). Microfinance and economic development. Handbook of finance and development. https://www.elgaronline.com/view/edcoll/9781785360503/9781785360503.00030.xmlCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahal, M., & Fiala, N. (2020). What do we know about the impact of microfinance? The problems of statistical power and precision. World Development, 128, 104773. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2019.104773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, P., & Fréchette, G. R. (2018). On the determinants of cooperation in infinitely repeated games: A survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 56(1), 60114. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.20160980CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalla Pellegrina, L., De Michele, A., Di Maio, G., Landoni, P., & Parravicini, S. (2017). Group meeting frequency and borrowers’ repayment performance in microfinance: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in South Africa. University of Milan Bicocca Department of Economics, Management and Statistics Working Paper No. 374. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3080201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawkins, R. (1976). The selfish gene. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
DeBruine, L. M. (2002). Facial resemblance enhances trust. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 269(1498), 13071312. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2002.2034CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
de Quidt, J., Fetzer, T., & Ghatak, M. (2016). Group lending without joint liability. Journal of Development Economics, 121, 217236. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2014.11.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A. (1985). Volunteer's dilemma. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 29(4), 605610. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002785029004003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diekmann, A., Jann, B., Przepiorka, W., & Wehrli, S. (2014). Reputation formation and the evolution of cooperation in anonymous online markets. American Sociological Review, 79(1), 6585. https://doi.org/10.1177/0003122413512316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doebeli, M., Blarer, A., & Ackermann, M. (1997). Population dynamics, demographic stochasticity, and the evolution of cooperation. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 94(10), 51675171. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.94.10.5167CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dube, A., & Kamath, R. (2018). Microfinance group processes and crises: Responses to economic and psychological threats. The Journal of Development Studies, 113.Google Scholar
Duvendack, M., Palmer-Jones, R., Copestake, J. G., Hooper, L., Loke, Y., & Rao, N. (2011). What is the evidence of the impact of microfinance on the well-being of poor people? EPPI-Centre, Social Science Research Unit, Institute of Education, University of London.Google Scholar
Enquist, M., & Leimar, O. (1993). The evolution of cooperation in mobile organisms. Animal Behaviour, 45(4), 747757. https://doi.org/10.1006/anbe.1993.1089CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fessler, D. M. T., & Haley, K. J. (2003). The strategy of affect: Emotions in human cooperation. In Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation (pp. 736). MIT Press.Google Scholar
Fetchenhauer, D., Groothuis, T., & Pradel, J. (2010). Not only states but traits – Humans can identify permanent altruistic dispositions in 20 s. Evolution and Human Behavior, 31(2), 8086. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2009.06.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economics Letters, 71(3), 397404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fletcher, J. A., & Doebeli, M. (2009). A simple and general explanation for the evolution of altruism. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 276(1654), 1319. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2008.0829CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fletcher, J. A., & Doebeli, M. (2010). Assortment is a more fundamental explanation for the evolution of altruism than inclusive fitness or multilevel selection: Reply to Bijma and Aanen. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 277(1682), 677678. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2009.1722CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fletcher, J. A., & Zwick, M. (2006). Unifying the theories of inclusive fitness and reciprocal altruism. The American Naturalist, 168(2), 252262. https://doi.org/10.1086/506529CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Foster, K. R., & Xavier, J. B. (2007). Cooperation: Bridging ecology and sociobiology. Current Biology: CB, 17(9), R319-321. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2007.03.005CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fu, F., Nowak, M. A., Christakis, N. A., & Fowler, J. H. (2012). The evolution of homophily. Scientific Reports, 2, 845. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep00845CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fudenberg, D., & Maskin, E. (1986). The folk theorem in repeated games with discounting or with incomplete information. Econometrica, 54(3), 533554. https://doi.org/10.2307/1911307CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, S., Herrmann, B., & Thöni, C. (2010). Culture and cooperation. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 365(1553), 26512661. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2010.0135CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gardner, A., & West, S. A. (2010). Greenbeards. Evolution, 64(1), 2538. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1558-5646.2009.00842.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ghatak, M., & Guinnane, T. W. (1999). The economics of lending with joint liability: Theory and practice. Journal of Development Economics, 60(1), 195228. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(99)00041-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giné, X., & Karlan, D. (2014). Group versus individual liability: Short and long term evidence from Philippine microcredit lending groups. Journal of Development Economics, 107, 6583. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.11.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, H., Smith, E. A., & Bowles, S. (2001). Costly signaling and cooperation. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 213(1), 103119. https://doi.org/10.1006/jtbi.2001.2406CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gomez, R., & Santor, E. (2008). Does the microfinance lending model actually work. Whitehead Journal of Diplomacy and International Relations, 9, 37.Google Scholar
Grafen, A. (2007). Detecting kin selection at work using inclusive fitness. Proceedings. Biological Sciences, 274(1610), 713719. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2006.0140Google ScholarPubMed
Grafen, A. (2009). Formalizing Darwinism and inclusive fitness theory. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 364(1533), 31353141. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2009.0056CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Griffin, D., & Husted, B. W. (2015). Social sanctions or social relations? Microfinance in Mexico. Journal of Business Research, 68(12), 25792587. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.06.023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guido, A., Robbett, A., & Romaniuc, R. (2019). Group formation and cooperation in social dilemmas: A survey and meta-analytic evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 159, 192209. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2019.02.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurven, M. (2006). The evolution of contingent cooperation. Current Anthropology, 47(1), 185192. https://doi.org/10.1086/499552CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurven, M., Hill, K., & Kaplan, H. (2002). From forest to reservation: Transitions in food-sharing behavior among the Ache of Paraguay. Journal of Anthropological Research, 58(1), 93120. https://doi.org/10.1086/jar.58.1.3631070CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guttman, J. M. (2007). Repayment performance in microcredit programs: Theory and evidence. Networks Financial Institute Working Paper, 2007-WP-11. https://www.indstate.edu/business/sites/business.indstate.edu/files/Docs/2007-WP-11_Guttman.pdfCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haldar, A., & Stiglitz, J. E. (2016). Group lending, joint liability, and social capital: Insights From the Indian microfinance crisis. Politics & Society, 44(4), 459497. https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329216674001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hales, D. (2005). Change your tags fast! – A necessary condition for cooperation? In Davidsson, P., Logan, B., and Takadama, K. (Eds.), Multi-agent and multi-agent-based simulation (pp. 8998). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1964a). The genetical evolution of social behaviour. I. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 7(1), 116. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-5193(64)90038-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1964b). The genetical evolution of social behaviour. II. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 7(1), 1752. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-5193(64)90039-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. (1975). Innate social aptitudes of man: An approach from evolutionary genetics. Biosocial Anthropology, 53, 133155.Google Scholar
Hammerstein, P. (2003). Genetic and cultural evolution of cooperation. MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammerstein, P., & Noë, R. (2016). Biological trade and markets. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1687), 20150101. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0101CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hammond, R. A., & Axelrod, R. (2006). The evolution of ethnocentrism. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(6), 926936. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022002706293470CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(4), 10091055.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J. (2004). Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 53(1), 335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Boyd, R. (2001). Why people punish defectors: Weak conformist transmission can stabilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative dilemmas. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 208(1), 7989.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., … Tracer, D. (2005). ‘Economic man’ in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. The Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28(6), 795815; discussion 815-855. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X05000142CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, N., & Henrich, J. (2007). Why humans cooperate: A cultural and evolutionary explanation. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hermes, N., & Lensink, R. (2007). The empirics of microfinance: What do we know? The Economic Journal, 117(517), F1F10. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02013.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hossain, M. (1988). Credit for alleviation of rural poverty: The Grameen Bank in Bangladesh. International Food Policy Research Institute. https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:fpr:resrep:65Google Scholar
Hulme, D. (2000). Is microdebt good for poor people? A note on the dark side of microfinance. Small Enterprise Development, 11(1), 2628. https://doi.org/10.3362/0957-1329.2000.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnstone, R. A., & Cant, M. A. (2008). Sex differences in dispersal and the evolution of helping and harming. The American Naturalist, 172(3), 318330. https://doi.org/10.1086/589899CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kaplan, H., Hill, K., Cadeliña, R. V., Hayden, B., Hyndman, D. C., Preston, R. J., … Yesner, D. R. (1985). Food sharing among ache foragers: Tests of explanatory hypotheses. [And Comments and Reply.] Current Anthropology, 26(2), 223246. https://doi.org/10.1086/203251CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlan, D. (2007). Social connections and group banking. The Economic Journal, 117(517), F52F84. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0297.2007.02015.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlan, D., & McConnell, M. A. (2014). Hey look at me: The effect of giving circles on giving. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 106, 402412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kasper, C., & Borgerhoff Mulder, M. (2015). Who helps and why?: Cooperative networks in Mpimbwe. Current Anthropology, 56(5), 701732. https://doi.org/10.1086/683024CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khandker, S. R. (2012). Grameen Bank lending: Does group liability matter? The World Bank. https://doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-6204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ko, A., Pick, C. M., Kwon, J. Y., Barlev, M., Krems, J. A., Varnum, M. E. W., … Kenrick, D. T. (2019). Family matters: Rethinking the psychology of human social motivation. Perspectives on Psychological Science. https://kar.kent.ac.uk/75338/Google ScholarPubMed
Kolstad, I., Pires, A. J. G., & Wiig, A. (2017). Within-group heterogeneity and group dynamics: Analyzing exit of microcredit groups in Angola. Oxford Development Studies, 45(3), 338351. https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2016.1243237CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koricheva, J., Gurevitch, J., & Mengersen, K. (2013). Handbook of meta-analysis in ecology and evolution. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kurzban, R., Burton-Chellew, M. N., & West, S. A. (2015). The evolution of altruism in humans. Annual Review of Psychology, 66(1), 575599. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-010814-015355CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lacy, R. C., & Sherman, P. W. (1983). Kin recognition by phenotype matching. The American Naturalist, 121(4), 489512. https://doi.org/10.1086/284078CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamba, S. (2014). A comparison of the economic literature on microfinance and the evolutionary literature on cooperation. In Gibson, M. A. and Lawson, D. W. (Eds.), Applied evolutionary anthropology: Darwinian approaches to contemporary world issues (pp. 3957). Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4939-0280-4_3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamba, S., & Mace, R. (2011). Demography and ecology drive variation in cooperation across human populations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(35), 1442614430. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1105186108CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lamba, S., & Mace, R. (2013). The evolution of fairness: Explaining variation in bargaining behaviour. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 280(1750), 20122028. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2012.2028Google ScholarPubMed
Lehmann, L., & Keller, L. (2006). The evolution of cooperation and altruism – A general framework and a classification of models. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 19(5), 13651376. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1420-9101.2006.01119.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leimar, O., & Hammerstein, P. (2001). Evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 268(1468), 745753. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2000.1573CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mahmud, M. (2019). Repaying microcredit loans: A natural experiment on liability structure. The Journal of Development Studies, 0(0), 116. https://doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2019.1632432Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, J. (1964). Group selection and kin selection. Nature, 201(4924), 11451147. https://doi.org/10.1038/2011145a0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meager, R. (2019). Understanding the average impact of microcredit expansions: A Bayesian hierarchical analysis of seven randomized experiments. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 11(1), 5791. https://doi.org/10.1257/app.20170299Google Scholar
Microcredit Summit Campaign. (2015). Mapping pathways out of poverty. The State of the Microcredit Summit Campaign Report.Google Scholar
Milinski, M. (2016). Reputation, a universal currency for human social interactions. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 371(1687), 20150100.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Bakker, T. C. M., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2001). Cooperation through indirect reciprocity: Image scoring or standing strategy? Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 268(1484), 24952501. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2001.1809Google ScholarPubMed
Morgan, C. J. (1979). Eskimo hunting groups, social kinship, and the possibility of kin selection in humans. Ethology and Sociobiology, 1(1), 8386. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(79)90008-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nettle, D., Gibson, M. A., Lawson, D. W., & Sear, R. (2013). Human behavioral ecology: Current research and future prospects. Behavioral Ecology, 24(5), 10311040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, M. A. (2006). Five rules for the evolution of cooperation. Science, 314(5805), 15601563. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1133755CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437(7063), 12911298. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature04131CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Palfrey, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1984). Participation and the provision of discrete public goods: A strategic analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 24(2), 171193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panchanathan, K., & Boyd, R. (2003). A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 224(1), 115126. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-5193(03)00154-1CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Paxton, J., Graham, D., & Thraen, C. (2000). Modeling group loan repayment behavior: New insights from Burkina Faso. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48(3), 639655. https://doi.org/10.1086/452613CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platt, T. G., & Bever, J. D. (2009). Kin competition and the evolution of cooperation. Trends in Ecology & Evolution, 24(7), 370377. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tree.2009.02.009CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Postelnicu, L., Hermes, N., & Servin, R. (2019). External social ties and loan repayment of group lending members: A case study of Pro Mujer Mexico. The Journal of Development Studies, 55(8), 17841798. https://doi.org/10.1080/00220388.2018.1464148CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powers, S. T., van Schaik, C. P., & Lehmann, L. (2019). Cooperation in large-scale human societies – What, if anything, makes it unique, and how did it evolve? OSF Preprints. https://doi.org/10.31219/osf.io/v47apCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Queller, D. C. (1985). Kinship, reciprocity and synergism in the evolution of social behaviour. Nature, 318(6044), 366367. https://doi.org/10.1038/318366a0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Queller, D. C. (1992). A general model for kin selection. Evolution, 46(2), 376380. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1558-5646.1992.tb02045.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rand, D. G., & Nowak, M. A. (2013). Human cooperation. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 17(8), 413425. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tics.2013.06.003CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Richerson, P., Baldini, R., Bell, A. V., Demps, K., Frost, K., Hillis, V., … Zefferman, M. (2016). Cultural group selection plays an essential role in explaining human cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. The Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 39, e30. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0140525X1400106XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riolo, R. L., Cohen, M. D., & Axelrod, R. (2001). Evolution of cooperation without reciprocity. Nature, 414(6862), 441443. https://doi.org/10.1038/35106555CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Roberts, G. (1998). Competitive altruism: From reciprocity to the handicap principle. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, 265(1394), 427431. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.1998.0312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sabin, N., & Reed-Tsochas, F. (2018). Able but unwilling to enforce: Cooperative dilemmas in group lending (SSRN Scholarly Paper ID 3275526). Social Science Research Network. https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=3275526Google Scholar
Sachs, J. L., Mueller, U. G., Wilcox, T. P., & Bull, J. J. (2004). The evolution of cooperation. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 79(2), 135160. https://doi.org/10.1086/383541CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schino, G., & Aureli, F. (2017). Reciprocity in group-living animals: Partner control versus partner choice. Biological Reviews, 92(2), 665672. https://doi.org/10.1111/brv.12248CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seinen, I., & Schram, A. (2006). Social status and group norms: Indirect reciprocity in a repeated helping experiment. European Economic Review, 50(3), 581602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seyfarth, R. M., & Cheney, D. L. (2012). The evolutionary origins of friendship. Annual Review of Psychology, 63, 153177. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-psych-120710-100337CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sharma, M., & Zeller, M. (1997). Repayment performance in group-based credit programs in Bangladesh: An empirical analysis. World Development, 25(10), 17311742. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(97)00063-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smaldino, P. E. (2017). Social identity and cooperation in cultural evolution. Behavioural Processes, 161, 108116. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.beproc.2017.11.015CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smaldino, P. E., Schank, J. C., & McElreath, R. (2013). Increased costs of cooperation help cooperators in the long run. The American Naturalist, 181(4), 451463. https://doi.org/10.1086/669615CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Spagnolo, G. (1999). Social relations and cooperation in organizations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38(1), 125. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(98)00119-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1990). Peer monitoring and credit markets. The World Bank Economic Review, 4(3), 351366. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/4.3.351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strassmann, J. E., Page, R. E., Robinson, G. E., & Seeley, T. D. (2011). Kin selection and eusociality. Nature, 471(7339), E5E6. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature09833CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sylwester, K., & Roberts, G. (2010). Cooperators benefit through reputation-based partner choice in economic games. Biology Letters, 6(5), 659662. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsbl.2010.0209CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. C. (1986). The social identity theory of intergroup behavior. Psychology of Intergroup Relations, 5, 724.Google Scholar
Taylor, P. D. (1992). Altruism in viscous populations – An inclusive fitness model. Evolutionary Ecology, 6(4), 352356. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF02270971CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinbergen, N. (1963). On aims and methods of Ethology. Zeitschrift Für Tierpsychologie, 20(4), 410433. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1439-0310.1963.tb01161.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. The Quarterly Review of Biology, 46(1), 3557. https://doi.org/10.1086/406755CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Bastelaer, T., & Leathers, H. (2006). Trust in lending: Social capital and joint liability seed loans in Southern Zambia. World Development, 34(10), 17881807.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Tassel, E. (1999). Group lending under asymmetric information. Journal of Development Economics, 60(1), 325. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3878(99)00034-6CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waring, T. M., Kline, M. A., Brooks, J., Goff, S., Gowdy, J., Jansen, M., Smaldino, P., & Jacquet, J. (2015). A multilevel evolutionary framework for sustainability analysis. Ecology and Science, 20(2). https://doi.org/DOI:10.5751/ES-07634-200234Google Scholar
Wedekind, C., & Braithwaite, V. A. (2002). The long-term benefits of human generosity in indirect reciprocity. Current Biology, 12(12), 10121015. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0960-9822(02)00890-4CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
West, S. A., Griffin, A. S., & Gardner, A. (2007a). Social semantics: Altruism, cooperation, mutualism, strong reciprocity and group selection. Journal of Evolutionary Biology, 20(2), 415432. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1420-9101.2006.01258.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, S. A., Griffin, A. S., & Gardner, A. (2007b). Evolutionary explanations for cooperation. Current Biology, 17(16), R661R672. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2007.06.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
West, S. A., Pen, I., & Griffin, A. S. (2002). Cooperation and competition between relatives. Science (New York, NY), 296(5565), 7275. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1065507CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wilson, D. S. (1977). Structured demes and the evolution of group-advantageous traits. The American Naturalist, 111(977), 157185. JSTOR.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, D. S., & Dugatkin, L. A. (1997). Group selection and assortative interactions. The American Naturalist, 149(2), 336351. https://doi.org/10.1086/285993CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, D. S., & Sober, E. (1994). Reintroducing group selection to the human behavioral sciences. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 17(4), 585607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The stylised timeline of a typical joint liability loan cycle from loan disbursement by the microfinance institution (MFI) to the decision of the MFI about loan renewal or exclusion from credit, which is conditional on borrowers’ repayment behaviour. At each stage framed by a rectangle, borrowers can be thought of as taking an action and this action can affect the group's repayment outcome (see Table 1).

Figure 1

Table 1. Description of typical stages of a microfinance loan cycle with joint liability lending (see Figure 1) and how group members’ decisions at these stages affect the cooperative dilemma.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Number and qualitative directions of associations between predictor categories and repayment efficacy of JLL borrowers reported in the literature. Predictors are grouped into 13 categories based on the concept they are measuring. Coloured boxes further group these 13 categories into the evolutionary assortment mechanisms (see Section 4.1.3 for details). Associations are reported qualitatively as negative (orange), nonsignificant (grey), inverted U-shaped (blue) or positive (green) as per the original study (see Section 4.1.2 for details) with percentages of each type of association shown. Note that some bars do not add up exactly to 100% owing to rounding. The figure is based on a total of 142 associations from 41 empirical studies spanning 32 countries. See SM1 for details and references for every association extracted from the literature and SM2 for a table with the data underlying this figure. Within the group of categories labelled ‘Prior interaction’, the first six categories relate to direct reciprocity, and the last three to indirect reciprocity, with two categories relating to both direct or indirect reciprocity, specifically ‘Geographic proximity of group members’ and ‘Participation in community and other associations’. ‘Geographic proximity of group members’ may also relate to the ‘Other/multiple mechanisms’ grouping.

Supplementary material: PDF

Gehrig et al. supplementary material

Gehrig et al. supplementary material

Download Gehrig et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 564.4 KB