Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-10T05:03:21.079Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Degrowth: a path to transformative solutions for socio-ecological sustainability

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 March 2024

Mine Islar*
Affiliation:
Lund University Center for Sustainability Studies (LUCSUS), Biskospgatan 5, Lund, Sweden
Max Koch
Affiliation:
Department of Social Work, Lund University, Allhelgona kyrkogata 8, Lund, Sweden
Riya Raphael
Affiliation:
Department of Social Work, Lund University, Allhelgona kyrkogata 8, Lund, Sweden
Alexander Paulsson
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Management, Lund University, Tycho Brahes väg 1, 223 63 Lund, Sweden
*
Corresponding author: Mine Islar; Email: mine.islar@lucsus.lu.se

Abstract

Non-technical summary

Engaging with economic questions is crucial for sustainability science to maintain its transformative potential. By recognizing the impact of continuous economic growth on environmental problems, the concept of degrowth proposes a practical approach to achieving sustainability. It urges experts in sustainability to think carefully about the impacts of economic growth, echoing recent scientific findings that question the need for endless growth. Therefore, this article highlights the potential of degrowth as a transformative approach that can expand capacities necessary for socio-ecological sustainability.

Technical summary

This article highlights the potential of degrowth as a transformative approach that can expand capacities necessary for socio-ecological sustainability. By addressing economic growth as a fundamental driver of unsustainability, degrowth offers a concrete pathway toward achieving sustainable outcomes. It calls for sustainability scientists to explicitly consider the role of economic growth, aligning with recent scientific assessments that support a critical stance on growth. Although degrowth and sustainability share common goals such as respecting biocapacity and equitable distribution of ecological budgets, degrowth approaches differ by placing emphasis on national and local solutions and exploring aspects such as technology, time, work, commodity, and property. Engaging with economic questions is crucial for sustainability science to maintain its transformative potential. Growth-critical perspectives such as degrowth and post-growth have the potential to propel sustainability discourses into new, more impactful realms of development.

Social media summary

Engaging with economic questions is crucial for sustainability science to maintain its transformative potential. Degrowth proposes a practical approach for achieving sustainability.

Type
Intelligence Briefing
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

The degrowth scholarship argues for a multi-scalar transformation beyond the growth-oriented economic paradigm to achieve socio-ecological sustainability. Since its emergence in the early 2000s, degrowth has conceived the broad values of sustainability and justice as inseparable, requiring integrated strategies (Barlow et al., Reference Barlow, Regen, Cadiou, Chertkovskaya, Hollweg, Plank, Schulken and Wolf2022). Recent studies show that a growth-oriented economy does not lead to increasing levels of sustainable and equitable development because there is ‘diminishing social returns with higher resource use’ (O'Neill et al., Reference O’Neill, Fanning, Lamb and Steinberger2018). This implies that in a growth-oriented economy, welfare or well-being ceases to increase after a certain level of growth. Instead, it just continues to further exceed planetary boundaries having direct implications on sustainability. In the light of recent research, the concept of degrowth is increasingly recognized as an alternative to our current system and defined as a proposal for a radical voluntary reorganization of society that leads to a drastic reduction in the use of energy and resources (Schmelzer et al., Reference Schmelzer, Vetter and Vansintjan2022).

Often in sustainability science, discussion of consumption and production relationships is limited to the context of sustainable development goals (SDGs) where different solutions from circular economy to green growth are grouped under one umbrella such as ‘sustainable consumption and production’ (Kates et al., Reference Kates, Clark, Corell, Hall, Jaeger, Lowe, McCarthy, Schellnhuber, Bolin, Dickson, Faucheux, Gallopin, Grübler, Huntley, Jäger, Jodha, Kasperson, Mabogunje, Matson and Svedin2001). However, adopting a critical approach to growth as a solution aligns with recent scientific assessments that advocate for the necessity to question our current economic systems. For instance, the terms ‘degrowth’ and ‘post-growth’ are mentioned several times in the AR6 IPCC report. In the adaptation report, it is described as ‘a solution for achieving environmental sustainability and socio-economic progress’ and as a ‘deliberate response to concerns about ecological limits to growth and the compatibility between growth-oriented development and sustainability’ (IPCC, 2022a, 2022b, WGII, Ch. 18, p. 80). The mitigation report mentions ‘GDP non-growth/degrowth or post-growth’ as approaches allowing climate stabilization below 2°C (IPCC, 2022a, chapter III, p. 86). In addition to that, Values assessment of the Intergovernmental Panel for Biodiversity and Ecosystem services (IPBES, 2022) also identifies degrowth as one of the suggested pathways to achieve just and sustainable future defining it as a strategy that reduce the material throughput of society, protecting human well-being through equitable distribution of material wealth rather than economic growth. Within the same report, the environmental values associated with degrowth are presented as being based on the principles of strong sustainability where biodiversity, nature's contributions to people, and core ecological processes are seen as irreplaceable by technology and built infrastructure. Based on these assessments, current models of societal progress that prioritize economic growth at the expense of biodiversity and ecological life support systems are incompatible with sustainability.

According to Clark and Harley's (Reference Clark and Harley2020) comprehensive review on sustainability science, there are six capacities necessary to support development pathways toward sustainability. These are capacities to (a) measure sustainable development, (b) promote equity, (c) adapt to shocks and surprises, (d) transform the system into more sustainable development pathways, (e) link knowledge with action, and (f) devise governance arrangements that allow people to work together in exercising the other capacities. In the light of these recent scientific recognition of degrowth as a solution to unsustainability, in this paper, we aim to show how degrowth contributes to debates on sustainability and sustainable development by offering radical solutions to emancipate social systems from their dependency on growth. We expand our analysis by putting degrowth into conversation with Clark and Harley's review on capacities and explain how degrowth solutions can deepen capacities necessary to inform socio-ecological sustainability.

1. Degrowth and capacity to measure sustainable development

Clark and Harley's review on sustainability science identifies measuring well-being as one of the ways to expand the capacity to measure sustainable development. We argue that degrowth can contribute here by historicizing and unpacking the taken for granted relationship between sustainable development and well-being. The critiques of development that arose in the latter part of the 20th century served as the foundation for the concept of degrowth. In other words, degrowth emerged as a response to the strong association between the notion of sustainable development and economic growth. The Brundtland report (1987) advocated for ‘a new era of economic growth – growth that is forceful and at the time socially and environmentally sustainable’ (p. 7). It further emphasized the need for revitalizing global economic growth to prevent economic, social, and environmental crises, asserting that ‘more rapid economic growth in both industrial and developing countries’ was crucial (ibid., p. 72). Similarly, SDGs also engage with economic growth. For instance, SDG 8 aims to promote sustained, inclusive, sustainable economic growth, full and productive employment and decent work for all. Its first target aims to sustain per capita economic growth in accordance with national circumstances and, in particular, at least 7% gross domestic product (GDP) growth per annum in the least developed countries. In the SDG framework, this growth strategy is made sustainable by a single target (SDG 8.4): ‘endeavor to decouple economic growth from environmental degradation’.

Much has been learned on the relation between GDP and environmental pressures since the emergence of the empirical literature on decoupling in the 1990s (for reviews, see, Haberl et al., Reference Haberl, ., Wiedenhofer, Virag, Kalt, Plank, Brockway, Fishman, Hauskost, Krausmann, Leon-Gruchalski, Mayer, Pichler, Schaffartzik, Sousa, Streeck and Creutzig2020; Hickel and Kallis, Reference Hickel and Kallis2020; Parrique, Reference Parrique2019; Vadén et al., Reference Vadén, Lähde, Majava, Järvensivu, Toivanen, Hakala and Eronen2020). The mitigation report of the IPCC AR6 provides one of the most recent syntheses of this body of research. In the report, decoupling is described as ‘insufficient’ (Hubacek et al., Reference Hubacek, Chen, Feng, Wiedmann and Shan2021), ‘not sufficient’ (IPCC AR6 WGIII, Ch. 2, p. 39), with rates that ‘fall a long way short’ (Le Quéré et al., Reference Le Quéré, Korsbakken, Wilson, Tosun, Andrew, Andres, Candell, Jordan, Peters and van Vuuren2019), which makes green growth a ‘misleading’ (Ward et al., Reference Ward, Sutton, Werner, Costanza, Mohr and Simmons2016), ‘misguided’ (Hickel & Kallis, Reference Hickel and Kallis2020) strategy which ‘rests partly on faith’ (Vadén et al., Reference Vadén, Lähde, Majava, Järvensivu, Toivanen, Hakala and Eronen2020).

To make economic growth truly sustainable, we would need to (1) absolutely decouple production and consumption (relative decoupling is not enough) (2) from all environmental pressures (not only carbon) (3) wherever these happen (taking into account imported impacts) (4) at a pace that is sufficiently fast to avoid ecological collapse, taking into account science-based targets (Anderson et al., Reference Anderson, Broderick and Stoddard2020) in line with equity (Robiou du Pont et al., Reference Robiou du Pont, Louise Jeffery, Gütschow, Rogelj, Christoff and Meinshausen2017) (5) by keeping that decoupling over time (as to avoid recoupling). Such narratives of green growth have never been achieved and there is yet no convincing evidence showing that it could.

This is perhaps the most important contribution the degrowth literature had toward debates around sustainable development and its assumptions on well-being: the pursuit of economic growth in advanced capitalist countries are not compatible with the respect of global planetary boundaries. The need to produce and consume less is a consequence of the failure to decouple GDP from environmental pressures. If a specific country is overshooting its fair share of planetary boundaries, and if economic activities are still unavoidably correlated with ecological footprints, then sustainability necessarily requires a reduction of production and consumption. Although elements of social justice, well-being, and democracy are still actively debated among a variety of perspective, the need for a reduction of production and consumption for a social and ecological well-being has been stable since the emergence of the term in 2002 (for a history, see, Parrique, Reference Parrique2019).

2. Degrowth and capacity to promote equity

For a just and equitable transition toward sustainability, it is vital to challenge and transform the unequal power dynamics which have persisted along capitalist, geo-political, colonial, gendered, and racialized lines (Dengler et al., Reference Dengler, Lang, Seebacher, Barlow, Regen, Cadiou, Chertkovskaya, Hollweg, Plank, Schulken and Wolf2022). For several decades, scholars who work on inequality have challenged the growth model for its belief that steady levels of increasing GDP would tackle inequality through the ‘trickle-down of wealth’ from the richest to the poorest (cf. Breman, Reference Breman1996). Instead, one of the consequences has been an ongoing cycle of highly unsustainable extraction of natural resources and labor to maintain the growth paradigm (Chertkovskaya & Paulsson, Reference Chertkovskaya and Paulsson2021). Exploitative logics of extraction and persistent inequality have been key components in the development of the Global North (cf. Amin, Reference Amin1976; Grosfoguel, Reference Grosfoguel2000; Mies, Reference Mies2007). With widespread outsourcing of industrial production in the 1980s, the Global North largely relies on cheap labor from the Global South (cf. Dengler & Seebacher, Reference Dengler and Seebacher2019; Mies, Reference Mies2007; Prentice and De Neve, Reference Prentice and De Neve2017). For example, Hickel et al. (Reference Hickel, Dorninger, Wieland and Swandi2022a, p. 10) calculate that ‘the drain amounted to $10.8 trillion in 2015, and $242 trillion over the period from 1990 to 2015…’ from the Global South to the North.

Colonial histories not only frame the contemporary relations of production and extraction, but the impact of climate change is also asymmetrical. High-income countries, such as Europe and the USA, are responsible for consistently overshooting several planetary boundaries (Fanning et al., Reference Fanning, O'Neill, Hickel and Roux2022; Hickel et al., Reference Hickel, O'Neill, Fanning and Zoomkawala2022b). However, the middle- and low-income countries of the Global South are more vulnerable to numerous effects of climate change (Chen et al., Reference Chen, Noble, Hellmann, Coffee, Murillo and Chawla2015). Thus, universalized strategies of green growth continue within the legacy of neo-colonial means of prescriptive economic planning. Within degrowth scholarship, there is a recognition that these colonial modes of unequal exchange need to be addressed. However, it is important to critically explore what this implies. For example, a common argument proposed is that the Global North needs to ‘degrow’ to enable the Global South to ‘grow’ to gain higher standards of living (D'Alisa et al., Reference D'Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015). Although these suggestions are well-intended and it is crucial to address discussions on redistribution and reparations, it is also pertinent to examine how degrowth in the Global North economies would inadvertently impact the Global South, especially when the global value and supply chains are complexly entangled (Matković, Reference Matković2018). Yet, a degrowth lens becomes valuable to explore the multi-dimensionality of sustainable transitions, since it puts socio-economic and ecological justice at the core of the discussions of sustainability, instead of focusing on ‘greening’ growth or the markets. Degrowth offers alternatives on how to radically reduce inequality (e.g. wealth and income caps). Proponents have adopted the notion of ‘eco-social’ policies to reduce structures of inequality simultaneously with respecting planetary limits. To integrate both overarching goals, the literature (see Koch, Reference Koch2022a, for an overview) suggests orienting public policies toward the upper (or planetary) and lower (or sufficiency) boundaries of the ‘safe and just operating space’ as defined by Rockström et al. (Reference Rockström, Steffen, Noone, Persson, Chapin, Lambin, Lenton, Scheffer, Folke, Schellnhuber, Nykvist, de Wit, Hughes, van der Leeuw, Rodhe, Sörlin, Snyder, Costanza, Svedin and Foley2009) and Raworth (Reference Raworth2017). In relation to meeting basic needs or the ‘social floor’ of this space, proponents argue for the introduction of a universal and unconditional basic income, the expansion/introduction of universal basic services (UBSs), a voucher system, or a combination of the three (Bohnenberger, Reference Bohnenberger2023). Concerning the upper boundary of the safe and just operating space, degrowthers build on relevant philosophical approaches that defend ‘limitarianism’ in an ecologically constrained world (Robeyns, Reference Robeyns2019). More concrete economic proposals suggest the (re-)introduction of wealth taxation and/or the definition of maximum incomes as some quantitative proportion from minimum incomes (Buch-Hansen & Koch, Reference Buch-Hansen and Koch2019; François et al., Reference François, Mertens de Wilmars and Maréchal2023; Pizzigatti, Reference Pizzigatti2018).

Degrowth scholarship has also engaged with feminist theories on care and social reproduction to examine the gendering of labor within growth-driven economies under capitalism (Barlow et al., Reference Barlow, Regen, Cadiou, Chertkovskaya, Hollweg, Plank, Schulken and Wolf2022; Chertkovskaya et al., Reference Chertkovskaya, Paulsson and Barca2019; D'Alisa et al., Reference D'Alisa, Demaria and Kallis2015). Feminist conceptualizations of social reproduction offer analytical possibilities to acknowledge various scales of care – from everyday domestic work which is vital to maintain life – to structures of care provision through public welfare (Bhattacharya, Reference Bhattacharya2017; Dengler et al., Reference Dengler, Lang, Seebacher, Barlow, Regen, Cadiou, Chertkovskaya, Hollweg, Plank, Schulken and Wolf2022; Koch & Buch-Hansen, Reference Koch and Buch-Hansen2020). There is, however, a further need to examine the intersections of gendered and racialized organization of the labor market. For example, in the current economic paradigm, the commodification of care work has resulted in the segregation, gendering, and racializing of the labor force (Fraser, Reference Fraser2013; Melamed, Reference Melamed2015; Mies, Reference Mies2007; Parreñas, Reference Parreñas2015). The transformation of industrial production is inevitable due to climate change, and care work is unlikely to decline and may even increase, as we observed during COVID-19. Thus, any vision of integrating the ecological and social aspects of an economy needs to reassess how paid and unpaid care work can be reorganized and how structures of care provision can be built for equitable forms of sustainability (Gomez-Baggethun, Reference Gomez-Baggethun2022). By locating ecological and equitable provisions of care at the center of sustainable transition, degrowth scholarship offers a valuable space to critically engage with discussions on care to create more dignified spaces of work and life-making possibilities (Chertkovskaya & Paulsson, Reference Chertkovskaya and Paulsson2021).

3. Degrowth and capacity to promote transformations and governance

Much research on sustainability calls for a large-scale transformation to overcome path dependence. Indeed, the ability to destabilize existing regimes and overcome incumbency is a fundamental component of the capacity for transformation (Clark & Harley, Reference Clark and Harley2020). This should thus be at the cutting edge of transformation research for sustainability. But the research on the governance of sustainability and the financing of transitions, tend to merely describe the difficulties with transformation and put a disproportionate large focus on the costs of a transition. Our argument, however, is that degrowth can offer a way out of path dependency and allow transformational change. It is therefore crucial to explore how governance and welfare financing may be decoupled from economic growth.

The degrowth literature has begun to address horizontal and vertical governance issues and specifically the role of the state (D'Alisa & Kallis, Reference D'Alisa and Kallis2020; Koch Reference Koch2020, Reference Koch2022b). Although the modern state, including the welfare state, has co-evolved with the provision of economic growth, the emerging consensus is that it can nevertheless play an important role within degrowth transformations. In contrast to ecological modernization and ‘environmental state’ approaches (e.g. Meadowcroft in Gough et al., Reference Gough, Meadowcroft, Dryzek, Gerhards, Lengfeld, Markandya and Ortiz2008) that all aim to gradually optimize ecological performances within wider ‘green growth’ strategies, degrowth notions of the state presuppose a break with what Hausknost (Reference Hausknost2020) calls the ‘glass ceiling’ of transformations, namely the policy priority of economic growth. If the growth provision were replaced by a sustainability provision, governments could build governance networks at various scales (European, national, local) and with various private, semi-private, and non-profit actors to ensure the respect of ecological limits in production and consumption patterns (Khan et al., Reference Khan, Emilsson, Fritz, Koch, Hildingsson and Johansson2023). In such multi-level and multi-scalar frameworks, higher level frameworks will be required to set ecological and social targets and to facilitate the sharing (re-)distribution of resources to reduce regional and social inequalities. Such redistribution mechanisms will be necessary at the global level, not least considering the enormous amount of climate debt owed by the Global North to the South (Hickel, Reference Hickel2021).

In existing welfare states economic growth is one of the necessary conditions for the maintenance of high employment levels and thus the government's fiscal base. Lower levels of growth threaten to undermine this base precisely when the welfare state's social functions to counteract economic downturns that may accompany social and ecological transformations are required the most (Bailey, Reference Bailey2015). To achieve ecological sustainability without undermining critical amounts of well-being it is necessary to make welfare systems independent of economic growth (Corlet Walker et al., Reference Corlet Walker, Druckman and Jackson2021; Hirvilammi et al., Reference Hirvilammi, Häikiö, Johansson, Koch and Perkiö2023; Koch, Reference Koch2022a). This relates to both the supply and demand aspects of welfare provision (Büchs, Reference Büchs2021). Reconsidering the supply aspects of welfare requires the transfer of funding sources to those that are less affected by economic fluctuations, such as taxes on property, land, wealth, and inheritance or necessitate the imposition of taxes on consumption practices with high-carbon emissions. Degrowth scholars have also suggested the introduction of caps on wealth and income (Buch-Hansen & Koch, Reference Buch-Hansen and Koch2019).

The demand for welfare could be reduced in an alternative political-economy context that would feature a more even distribution of work, resources and opportunities, greater economic security and improved community and family capacity for social support, care, and social participation (Chertkovskaya et al., Reference Chertkovskaya, Paulsson and Barca2019). Büchs (Reference Büchs2021) adds to this that a corresponding health policy could help prevent disease and maximize everyone's chances to lead healthy and fulfilled lives instead of generating productivity and profits for the health care sector. In general, any shift toward a post-growth economy would need to be accompanied by ‘decommodified’ social policies (Dukelow & Murphy, Reference Dukelow and Murphy2022) that contribute toward a reconfiguration of existing links between work, cash, and services including new kinds of ‘sustainable welfare benefits’ such as universal basic income, UBSs, vouchers, and/or participation income (Bohnenberger, Reference Bohnenberger2020; Coote & Percy, Reference Coote and Percy2020; McGann & Murphy, Reference McGann and Murphy2023).

Another aspect that degrowth can offer concrete insights into debates on transformations and governance is in the context of financing of public services without economic growth. Since degrowth entails both a slow-down in production and consumption, this can impact taxes and subsequently any government's capacity to implement needed reforms. Government revenue in most cases is derived from two primary streams: tax on income and tax on consumption. If fewer people work, there is less taxable income. If consumption slows-down, tax revenue does too. So, what would happen to these two revenue streams if society embarked on a degrowth trajectory? Well, if the total number of hours worked is lowered, for example through a work-time reduction reform, as has been proposed (e.g. Kallis, Reference Kallis2013), the tax base will decrease accordingly. However, should salaries be kept at the same levels as before the work-time reduction reform, this would imply a substantial salary-increase in real terms. Additionally, if the unemployed or the involuntary part-time workers are allowed to share the existing jobs, for example through a substantive job-sharing program, as has been proposed in degrowth scholarship (Alcott, Reference Alcott2013; Scarrow, Reference Scarrow2018), then the total number of hours worked may very well increase. This would most likely lead to a growing tax base, although it depends on the number of unemployed, the share of involuntary part-time workers, and their levels of income.

Moving over to consumption, VAT and sales tax will probably decrease if consumption slows down. For example, widespread voluntary simplicity (Alexander, Reference Alexander2011) and re-use of products, combined with reforms to prevent planned obsolescence (see, e.g., Fitzpatrick et al., Reference Fitzpatrick, Parrique and Cosme2022), the removal of advertising from public spaces (Lloveras et al., Reference Lloveras, Marshall, Vandeventer and Pansera2022) and the introduction of a maximum income cap (Buch-Hansen & Koch, Reference Buch-Hansen and Koch2019), would most likely slow-down consumption and thus also reduce government revenue. Shifting the tax base from consumption to wealth will most likely then be necessary. A billionaire tax has been proposed both by wealthy people themselves (Neate, Reference Neate2022) and by parties in many countries (Whitehouse, 2022). Scaling up inheritance tax could be another reform to cover the loss in revenue coming from a slow-down of consumption. Besides simply making up for the loss of revenue, taxing the wealthiest could also imply the greatest impact in terms of reducing environmental harm. After all, it is the wealthiest households that emit the largest share of carbon dioxide emission (Chancel, Reference Chancel2022).

How would government spending change under a degrowth trajectory? People will still need help and care. People should also continue to benefit from guaranteed pensions. Consequently, health care funding and pension savings are essential. Yet, there are likely other care-related expenses that would be affected. For example, many of the so-called welfare diseases, which are generally linked to affluence, would probably diminish over time. This includes, for example, heart disease, stroke, Alzheimer's, diabetes, kidney diseases, and breast cancer. The list could be much longer. But the main point is clear: rather than being associated with costly reforms and a lowering of the tax base, degrowth itself could mitigate some of the escalating costs found in the core areas of today's health care systems (Borowy & Aillon, Reference Borowy and Aillon2017). Arguably, degrowth would be self-financed over a longer period of time, around 10–20 years, as it would be built on a combination of reduced spending and increased revenue. Indeed, by shifting costs around and shifting the tax base, if only temporarily, revenues and expenses would be matched over time. Although we here only have sketched how the financing of public services without economic growth could be approached, more studies are needed to explore the fiscal details around tax reforms in full, and how such shifts in revenues and spendings could balance out.

4. Conclusion

In conclusion, this article highlights the potential of degrowth as a transformative approach that can expand capacities necessary for socio-ecological sustainability. By addressing economic growth as a fundamental driver of unsustainability, degrowth offers a concrete pathway toward achieving sustainable outcomes. It calls for sustainability scientists to explicitly consider the role of economic growth, aligning with recent scientific assessments that support a critical stance on growth.

Although degrowth and sustainability share common goals such as respecting biocapacity and equitable distribution of ecological budgets, degrowth approaches differ by placing emphasis on national and local solutions and exploring aspects such as technology, time, work, commodity, and property. Engaging with economic questions is crucial for sustainability science to maintain its transformative potential. Growth-critical perspectives such as degrowth and post-growth have the potential to propel sustainability discourses into new, more impactful realms of development.

For instance, in the context of equality and well-being, degrowth proposes a downsizing of production and consumption in Western extractive economies to free up ecological space for the Global South with a careful consideration to how such changes in the North will impact industries and labor in the South. Drawing upon critical feminist conceptualizations, degrowth highlights the importance of recognizing various scales of social reproduction and the need to reorganize and transform work and governance to create sustainable and equitable futures.

By integrating degrowth into sustainability science, we can enrich the discourse and explore alternative pathways that can move beyond mere technocratic approaches. Embracing degrowth as a transformative approach holds the potential to reshape our understanding of sustainability and foster more inclusive, equitable, and ecologically balanced societies.

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge the support of Lund University's Research Programme for Excellence, focusing on Agenda 2030 and Sustainable Development. We thank Timothy Parrique, Jennifer Hinton, and Johanna Alkan Olsson who contributed to the discussion for the initial ideas of the paper.

Author contributions

Mine Islar designed conceptualization and framing of the article. All authors lead to different sections of the article and contributed equally to writing.

Funding statement

The project is funded by Lund University's Research Programme for Excellence, focusing on Agenda 2030 and Sustainable Development.

Competing interests

None.

References

Alcott, B. (2013). Should degrowth embrace the job guarantee? Journal of Cleaner Production, 38, 5660. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2011.06.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alexander, S. (2011). The voluntary simplicity movement: Reimagining the good life beyond consumer culture. International Journal of Environmental, Cultural, Economic, and Social Sustainability, 7(3), 133150.Google Scholar
Amin, S. (1976). Unequal development: An essay on the social formations of peripheral capitalism (Brian Pearce, Trans.). Sussex: The Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, K., Broderick, J. F., & Stoddard, I. (2020). A factor of two: how the mitigation plans of ‘climate progressive’ nations fall far short of Paris-compliant pathways. Climate Policy, 20(10), 12901304. https://doi.org/10.1080/14693062.2020.1728209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, D. (2015). The environmental paradox of the welfare state: The dynamics of sustainability. New Political Economy, 20(6), 793811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barlow, N., Regen, L., Cadiou, N., Chertkovskaya, E., Hollweg, M., Plank, C., Schulken, M., & Wolf, V. (eds.) (2022). Degrowth & strategy: How to bring about socio-ecological transformation. Mayfly. https://mayflybooks.org/degrowth-strategy/Google Scholar
Bhattacharya, T. (ed.). (2017). Social reproduction theory: Remapping class, recentering oppression. Pluto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnenberger, K. (2020). Money, vouchers, public infrastructures? A framework for sustainable welfare benefits. Sustainability, 12(2), 596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnenberger, K. (2023). Peaks and gaps in eco-social policy and sustainable welfare: A systematic literature map of the research landscape. European Journal of Social Security, 25(4), 328346. https://doi.org/10.1177/13882627231214546CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borowy, I., & Aillon, J.-L. (2017). Sustainable health and degrowth: Health, health care and society beyond the growth paradigm. Social Theory & Health, 15(3), 346368. https://doi.org/10.1057/s41285-017-0032-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Breman, J. (1996). Footloose labour: Working in India's informal economy. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buch-Hansen, H., & Koch, M. (2019). Degrowth through income and wealth caps? Ecological Economics, 160, 264271. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2019.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Büchs, M. (2021). Sustainable welfare: How do universal basic income and universal basic services compare? Ecological Economics, 189, 107152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chancel, L. (2022) Global carbon inequality over 1990–2019. Nature Sustainability, 5, 931938. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-022-00955-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, C., Noble, I., Hellmann, J., Coffee, J., Murillo, M., & Chawla, N. (2015) University of Notre Dame Global Adaptation Index: Country index technical report. ND-GAIN: Notre Dame Global Adaptation Index. https://gain.nd.edu/assets/254377/nd_gain_technical_document_2015.pdfGoogle Scholar
Chertkovskaya, E., & Paulsson, A. (2021). Countering corporate violence: Degrowth, ecosocialism and organising beyond the destructive forces of capitalism. Organization, 28(3), 405425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chertkovskaya, E., Paulsson, A., & Barca, S. (eds.). (2019) Towards a political economy of degrowth. Rowman & Littlefield.Google Scholar
Clark, W., & Harley, A. (2020). Sustainability science: Toward a synthesis. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 45(1), 331386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coote, A., & Percy, A. (2020). The case for universal basic services. Polity.Google Scholar
Corlet Walker, C., Druckman, A., & Jackson, T. (2021). Welfare systems without growth: A review of the challenges and next steps in the field. Ecological Economics, 186, 107066.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
D'Alisa, G., Demaria, F., & Kallis, G. (eds). (2015). Degrowth: A vocabulary for a New Era. Routledge.Google Scholar
D'Alisa, G., & Kallis, G. (2020). Degrowth and the state. Ecological Economics, 169, 106486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dengler, C., Lang, M., & Seebacher, L. (2022). Care: An overview of strategies for social-ecological transformation in the field of care. In Barlow, N., Regen, L., Cadiou, N., Chertkovskaya, E., Hollweg, M., Plank, C., Schulken, M., & Wolf, V. (Eds.), Degrowth & strategy: How to bring about socio-ecological transformation (pp. 311321). Mayfly. https://mayflybooks.org/degrowth-strategy/Google Scholar
Dengler, C., & Seebacher, L. (2019). What about the Global South? Towards a feminist decolonial degrowth approach. Ecological Economics, 157(2019), 246252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dukelow, F., & Murphy, M. (2022). Building the future from the present: Imagining post-growth, post-productivist ecosocial policy. Journal of Social Policy, 51(3), 504518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fanning, A., O'Neill, D., Hickel, J., & Roux, N. (2022). The social shortfall and ecological overshoot of nations. Nature Sustainability, 5, 2636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fitzpatrick, N., Parrique, T., & Cosme, I. (2022). Exploring degrowth policy proposals: A systematic mapping with thematic synthesis. Journal of Cleaner Production, 365, 119. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2022.132764CrossRefGoogle Scholar
François, M., Mertens de Wilmars, S., & Maréchal, K. (2023). Unlocking the potential of income and wealth caps in post-growth transformation: A framework for improving policy design. Ecological Economics, 208, 107788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraser, N. (2013). Fortunes of feminism: From state-managed capitalism to neoliberal crisis. Verso.Google Scholar
Gomez-Baggethun, E. (2022). Rethinking work for a just and sustainable future. Ecological Economics, 200, 107506. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2022.107506CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gough, I., Meadowcroft, J., Dryzek, J., Gerhards, J., Lengfeld, H., Markandya, A., & Ortiz, R. (2008). JESP Symposium: Climate change and social policy. Journal of European Social Policy, 18(4), 2544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grosfoguel, R. (2000). Developmentalism, modernity and dependency theory in Latin America. Nepantla: Views from South 1(1), 347374. http://www.umass.edu/legal/Benavides/Fall2005/397U/Readings%20Legal%20397U/5%20Ramon%20Grosfoguel.pdfGoogle Scholar
Haberl, H., , Wiedenhofer, D., Virag, D., Kalt, G., Plank, B., Brockway, P., Fishman, T., Hauskost, D., Krausmann, F., Leon-Gruchalski, B., Mayer, A., Pichler, M., Schaffartzik, A., Sousa, T., Streeck, J., & Creutzig, F. (2020). A systematic review of the evidence on decoupling of GDP, resource use and GHG emissions, part II: Synthesizing the insights. Environmental Research Letters, 15(6), 065003. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/ab842aCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausknost, D. (2020). The environmental state and the glass ceiling of transformation. Environmental Politics, 29(1), 1737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hickel, J. (2021) The anti-colonial politics of degrowth. Political Geography, 88, 13. https://eprints.lse.ac.uk/110918/1/1_s2.0_S0962629821000640_main.pdfCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hickel, J., Dorninger, C., Wieland, H., & Swandi, I. (2022 a). Imperialist appropriation in the world economy: Drain from the global South through unequal exchange, 1990–2015. Global Environmental Change, 73(2022), 113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2022.102467CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hickel, J., & Kallis, G. (2020). Is green growth possible? New Political Economy, 25, 469486. https://doi.org/10.1080/13563467.2019.1598964CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hickel, J., O'Neill, D., Fanning, A., & Zoomkawala, H. (2022 b). National responsibility for ecological breakdown: A fair shares assessment of resource use, 1970–2017. The Lancet Planetary Health, 6(4), e342e349. https://doi.org/10.1016/S2542-5196(22)00044-4CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hirvilammi, T., Häikiö, L., Johansson, H., Koch, M., & Perkiö, J. (2023). Social policy in a climate emergency context: Towards an ecosocial research agenda. Journal of Social Policy, 52(1), 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubacek, K., Chen, X., Feng, K., Wiedmann, T., & Shan, Y. (2021). Evidence of decoupling consumption-based CO2 emissions from economic growth. Advances in Applied Energy, 4, 100074. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.adapen.2021.100074CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IPBES. (2022). Summary for policymakers of the methodological assessment report on the diverse values and valuation of nature of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services [U. Pascual, P. Balvanera, M. Christie, B. Baptiste, D. González-Jiménez, C. B. Anderson, S. Athayde, D. N. Barton, R. Chaplin-Kramer, S. Jacobs, E. Kelemen, R. Kumar, E. Lazos, A. Martin, T. H. Mwampamba, B. Nakangu, P. O'Farrell, C. M. Raymond, S. M. Subramanian, M. Termansen, M. Van Noordwijk, & A. Vatn (eds.).] IPBES Secretariat, Bonn, Germany. https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.6522392CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IPCC. (2022a). Summary for Policymakers [P. R. Shukla, J. Skea, A. Reisinger, R. Slade, R. Fradera, M. Pathak, A. Al Khourdajie, M. Belkacemi, R. van Diemen, A. Hasija, G. Lisboa, S. Luz, J. Malley, D. McCollum, S. Some, & P. Vyas (eds.)]. In Climate Change 2022: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [P. R. Shukla, J. Skea, R. Slade, A. Al Khourdajie, R. van Diemen, D. McCollum, M. Pathak, S. Some, P. Vyas, R. Fradera, M. Belkacemi, A. Hasija, G. Lisboa, S. Luz, & J. Malley (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009157926.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IPCC. (2022b). Summary for Policymakers [H.-O. Pörtner, D. C. Roberts, E. S. Poloczanska, K. Mintenbeck, M. Tignor, A. Alegría, M. Craig, S. Langsdorf, S. Löschke, V. Möller, & A. Okem (eds.)]. In Climate Change 2022: Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [H.-O. Pörtner, D. C. Roberts, M. Tignor, E. S. Poloczanska, K. Mintenbeck, A. Alegría, M. Craig, S. Langsdorf, S. Löschke, V. Möller, A. Okem, & B. Rama (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, pp. 333, https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009325844.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kallis, G. (2013). Societal metabolism, working hours and degrowth: A comment on Sorman and Giampietro. Journal of Cleaner Production, 38(2013), 9498.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kates, R. W., Clark, W. C., Corell, R., Hall, J. M., Jaeger, C. C., Lowe, I., McCarthy, J. J., Schellnhuber, H. J., Bolin, B., Dickson, N. M., Faucheux, S., Gallopin, G. C., Grübler, A., Huntley, B., Jäger, J., Jodha, N. S., Kasperson, R. E., Mabogunje, A., Matson, P., … Svedin, U. (2001). Sustainability science. Science, 292(5517), 641642. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1059386CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Khan, J., Emilsson, K., Fritz, M., Koch, M., Hildingsson, R., & Johansson, H. (2023). Ecological ceiling and social floor: Public support for eco-social policies in Sweden. Sustainability Science, 18, 15191532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, M. (2020). The state in the transformation to a sustainable postgrowth economy. Environmental Politics, 29(1), 115133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, M. (2022 a). Social policy without growth: Moving towards sustainable welfare states. Social Policy and Society, 21(3), 447459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, M. (2022 b). State-civil society relations in Gramsci, Poulantzas and Bourdieu: Strategic implications for the degrowth movement. Ecological Economics, 193, 107275.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koch, M., & Buch-Hansen, H. (2020). In search of a political economy of the postgrowth era. Globalizations, 18(7), 110.Google Scholar
Le Quéré, C., Korsbakken, J., Wilson, C., Tosun, J., Andrew, R., Andres, R., Candell, J., Jordan, A., Peters, G., & van Vuuren, D. (2019). Drivers of declining CO2 emissions in 18 developed economies. Nature Climate Change, 9(3), 213217. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41558-019-0419-7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lloveras, J., Marshall, A. P., Vandeventer, J. S., & Pansera, M. (2022). Sustainability marketing beyond sustainable development: Towards a degrowth agenda. Journal of Marketing Management, 38(17–18), 20552077. https://doi.org/10.1080/0267257X.2022.2084443CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matković, A. (2018). ‘No magic bullets’: The Lawn-Smith debate, or why degrowth cannot be understood without a value-theory of imperialism. Journal for the Critique of Science, Imagination & New Anthropology, 46(273), 8198.Google Scholar
McGann, M., & Murphy, M. (2023). Income support in an eco-social state: The case for participation income. Social Policy and Society, 22(1), 1630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melamed, J. (2015). Racial capitalism. Critical Ethnic Studies, 1(1), 7685.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mies, M. (2007). Patriarchy and accumulation on a world scale – Revisited [Keynote lecture at the green economics institute, reading, 29 October 2005]. International Journal of Green Economics, 1(3/4), 268275. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJGE.2007.013059CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neate, R. (2022). Millionaires call on governments worldwide to ‘tax us now’. Guardian. https://www.theguardian.com/business/2022/jan/19/millionaires-call-on-governments-worldwide-to-tax-us-nowGoogle Scholar
O’Neill, D. W., Fanning, A. L., Lamb, W. F., & Steinberger, J. K. (2018). A good life for all within planetary boundaries. Nature Sustainability, 1(2), 8895. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-018-0021-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parreñas, R. S. (2015). Servants of globalization: Migration and domestic work. Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parrique, T. (2019) The political economy of degrowth. Economics and finance (doctoral dissertation). Université Clermont Auvergne, Clermont-Ferrand, France, and Stockholm Resilience Centre (SRC), Stockholm University. https://theses.hal.science/tel-02499463/documentGoogle Scholar
Pizzigatti, S. (2018). The case for a maximum wage. Polity.Google Scholar
Prentice, R., & De Neve, G. (eds). (2017). Unmaking the global sweatshop: Health and safety of the world's garment workers. University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raworth, K. (2017). Doughnut economics: Seven ways to think like a 21st century economist. Chelsea Green Publishing.Google Scholar
Robeyns, I. (2019). What, if anything, is wrong with extreme wealth? Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 20(3), 251266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robiou du Pont, Y., Louise Jeffery, M., Gütschow, J., Rogelj, J., Christoff, P., & Meinshausen, M. (2017). Equitable mitigation to achieve the Paris agreement goals. Nature Climate Change, 7(1), 3843.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockström, J., Steffen, W., Noone, K., Persson, Å., Chapin, F. S., Lambin, E. F., Lenton, T. M., Scheffer, M., Folke, C., Schellnhuber, H. J., Nykvist, B., de Wit, C. A., Hughes, T., van der Leeuw, S., Rodhe, H., Sörlin, S., Snyder, P. K., Costanza, R., Svedin, U., … Foley, J. A. (2009). A safe operating space for humanity. Nature, 461(7263), 472475. https://doi.org/10.1038/461472aCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Scarrow, R. (2018). Work and degrowth. Nature Sustainability, 1, 159. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41893-018-0057-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmelzer, M., Vetter, A., & Vansintjan, A. (2022). The future is degrowth: A guide to a world beyond capitalism. Verso. Retrieved January 3, 2024, from https://www.researchgate.net/publication/362762776_The_Future_Is_Degrowth_A_Guide_to_a_World_beyond_Capitalism.Google Scholar
Vadén, T., Lähde, V., Majava, A., Järvensivu, P., Toivanen, T., Hakala, E., & Eronen, J. (2020). Decoupling for ecological sustainability: A categorisation and review of research literature. Environmental Science & Policy, 112, 236244.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ward, J., Sutton, P., Werner, A., Costanza, R., Mohr, S., & Simmons, C. (2016). Is decoupling GDP growth from environmental impact possible? PLoS ONE, 11(10), e0164733. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0164733CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Whitehouse (2022). President's budget rewards work, not wealth with new billionaire minimum income tax. Press release. 28 March 2022; https://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/briefing-room/2022/03/28/presidents-budget-rewards-work-not-wealth-with-new-billionaire-minimum-income-tax/Google Scholar